Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter November 22, 2021

The Impact of Behavioral Economics on the Law: Introduction

  • Christoph Engel EMAIL logo
From the journal Review of Law & Economics

Abstract

Adopting the paradigms, findings and tools of behavioral economics has opened a promising avenue for legal research. This article sketches the broader framework within which the papers assembled in this special issue may be placed.

JEL Classification: D01; D90; D91; K00; C91

Corresponding author: Christoph Engel, Max Planck Institute for Research on Collection, Kurt-Schumacher-Straße 10, D 53113 Bonn, Germany, E-mail:

References

Amendola, K.L. and Wixted, J.T. (2015). Comparing the diagnostic accuracy of suspect identifications made by actual eyewitnesses from simultaneous and sequential lineups in a randomized field trial. J. Exp. Criminol. 11: 263–284. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11292-014-9219-2.Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, J.R. (2000). Learning and memory. An integrated approach. Wiley, New York.Search in Google Scholar

Bandura, A. (1977). Social learning theory. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs.Search in Google Scholar

Birmingham, R.L. (1970). Breach of contract, damage measures, and economic efficiency. Rutgers Law Rev. 24: 273–292.Search in Google Scholar

Bolton, G.E. and Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 90: 166–193. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.1.166.Search in Google Scholar

Box, G.E.P. (1976). Science and statistics. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 71: 791–799. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1976.10480949.Search in Google Scholar

Bracht, G.H. and Glass, G.V. (1968). The external validity of experiments. Am. Educ. Res. J. 5: 437–474. https://doi.org/10.3102/00028312005004437.Search in Google Scholar

Brown, D.E. (1991). Human universals. New York, McGraw-Hill.Search in Google Scholar

Camerer, C.F. and Ho, T.H. (1999). Experience-weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica 67: 827–874. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00054.Search in Google Scholar

Charness, G. and Martin, D. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica 74: 1579–1601. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.x.Search in Google Scholar

Chelius, J.R. (1976). Liability for industrial accidents. A comparison of negligence and strict liability systems. J. Leg. Stud. 5: 293–309. https://doi.org/10.1086/467554.Search in Google Scholar

Clatch, L. and Borgida, E. (2021). Behavioral economics in plea-bargain decision-making: beyond the shadow-of-trial model. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0069.Search in Google Scholar

Craswell, R. (1988). Contract remedies, renegotiation, and the theory of efficient breach. South. Calif. Law Rev. 61: 629–670.Search in Google Scholar

Davis, D.D. and Holt, C.A. (2021). Experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton.Search in Google Scholar

Desmet, P. and Engel, C. (2021). People are conditional rule followers. J. Econ. Psychol. 85: 102384. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2021.102384.Search in Google Scholar

Ederer, F. and Stremitzer, A. (2017). Promises and expectations. Game. Econ. Behav. 106: 161–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2017.09.012.Search in Google Scholar

Edlin, A.S. (1996). Cadillac contracts and up-front payments. Efficient investment under expectation damages. J. Law Econ. Organ. 12: 98–118. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.jleo.a023363.Search in Google Scholar

Eigen, Z.J. (2012). When and why individuals obey form-adhesive contracts. Experimental evidence of consent, compliance, promise and performance. J. Leg. Stud. 41: 67–93. https://doi.org/10.1086/664688.Search in Google Scholar

Eisenberg, T. and Engel, C. (2016). Unpacking negligence liability. Experimentally testing the governance effect. J. Empir. Leg. Stud. 13: 116–152. https://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12099.Search in Google Scholar

Ellickson, R.C. (1989). Bringing culture and human frailty to rational actors: a critique of classical law and economics. Chic. Kent. Law Rev. 65: 23–56.Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. (2005). Generating predictability. Institutional analysis and institutional design. Cambridge University Press, Cambrige.Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. (2007). The psychological case for obliging judges to write reasons. In: Engel, C. and Strack, F. (Eds.), The impact of court procedure on the psychology of judicial decision making. Nomos Publishers, Baden-Baden, pp. 71–109.Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. (2021). The proper scope of behavioral law and economics. In: Grundmann, S. and Hacker, P. (Eds.), Theories of choice. The social science and the law of decision making. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 19–36.Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. and Güth, W. (2018). Modeling a satisficing judge. Ration. Soc. 30: 220–246. https://doi.org/10.1177/1043463118767406.Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C., Hausladen, C., and Schubert, M. (2020). Charting the type space. The case of linear public good games. Max Planck Institute, Bonn.Search in Google Scholar

Englich, B. and Mussweiler, T. (2001). Sentencing under uncertainty: anchoring effects in the court room. J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. 31: 1535–1551.Search in Google Scholar

Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K.M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q. J. Econ. 114: 817–868. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355399556151.Search in Google Scholar

Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., and Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 71: 397–404. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1765(01)00394-9.Search in Google Scholar

Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P.M., and ABC Research Group (1999). Simple heuristics that make us smart. Oxford University Press, New York.Search in Google Scholar

Grgić-Hlača, N., Engel, C., and Gummadi, K.P. (2019). Human decision making with machine assistance. An experiment on bailing and jailing. In Proceedings of the ACM on Human-Computer Interaction, 3, CSCW, Article 178 (November 2019).Search in Google Scholar

Hart, O. and Moore, J. (2008). Contracts as reference points. Q. J. Econ. 123: 1–48. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.1.1.Search in Google Scholar

Hastie, R. (1993). Inside the juror. The psychology of juror decision making. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge England, New York, NY.Search in Google Scholar

Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (2000). Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Russell Sage Foundation.Search in Google Scholar

Kleine, M., Pascal, L., and Zhurakhovska, L. (2016). Fairness and persuasion. How stakeholder communication affects impartial decision making. Econ. Lett. 141: 173–176. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2016.02.019.Search in Google Scholar

Köszegi, B. and Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Q. J. Econ. 121: 1133–1165.Search in Google Scholar

Kripke, H. (1984). Law and economics. Measuring the economic efficiency of commercial law in a vacuum of fact. Univ. Penn. Law Rev. 133: 929–985.Search in Google Scholar

Levmore, S. (2021). The evolutionary force of behavioral economics in law. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0054.Search in Google Scholar

Miceli, T. and Segerson, K. (2021). The role of bias in economic models of law. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0043.Search in Google Scholar

Mussweiler, T. and Strack, F. (2000). Numeric judgements under uncertainty: the role of knowledge in anchoring. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 36: 495–518. https://doi.org/10.1006/jesp.1999.1414.Search in Google Scholar

Pennington, N. and Hastie, R. (1993). The story model for juror decision making. In: Hastie, R. (Ed.), Inside the juror. The psychology of juror decision making. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 192–221.Search in Google Scholar

Pi, D. (2021). The limitations of behavioral economics in tort law. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0076.Search in Google Scholar

Priest, G.L. and Klein, B. (1984). The selection of disputes for litigation. J. Leg. Stud. 13: 1–55. https://doi.org/10.1086/467732.Search in Google Scholar

Rizzo, M.J. (2021). The paternalistic turn in behavioral law and economics. A critique. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0056.Search in Google Scholar

Roe, B.E. and Just, D.R. (2009). Internal and external validity in economics research. Tradeoffs between experiments, field experiments, natural experiments, and field data. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 91: 1266–1271. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8276.2009.01295.x.Search in Google Scholar

Shavell, S. (1980). Strict liability versus negligence. J. Leg. Stud. 9: 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1086/467626.Search in Google Scholar

Steblay, N., Dysart, J., Solomon, F., and Lindsay, R.C.L. (2001). Eyewitness accuracy rates in sequential and simultaneous lineup presentations. A meta-analytic comparison. Law Hum. Behav. 25: 459–473. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1012888715007.Search in Google Scholar

Strack, F. and Mussweiler, T. (1997). Explaining the enigmatic anchoring effect. Mechanisms of selective accessibility. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 73: 437–446. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.73.3.437.Search in Google Scholar

Sunstein, C.R. (2013). Behavioral economics and paternalism. Yale Law J. 122: 1826–1899.Search in Google Scholar

Teichman, D. and Zamir, E. (2021). Behavioral economics and court decision-making. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0058.Search in Google Scholar

Thaler, R.H. and Sunstein, C.R. (2008). Nudge. Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, Yale.Search in Google Scholar

Treitel, G.H. (1988). Remedies for breach of contract: a comparative account. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Search in Google Scholar

Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgement under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185: 1124–1131. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.185.4157.1124.Search in Google Scholar

Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. J. Bus. 59: 5251–5278. https://doi.org/10.1086/296365.Search in Google Scholar

Tyler, T.R. (2006). Why people obey the law. Yale University Press, New Haven.Search in Google Scholar

Ulen, T.S. (1984). The efficiency of specific performance. Toward a unified theory of contract remedies. Mich. Law Rev. 83: 341–403. https://doi.org/10.2307/1288569.Search in Google Scholar

Ulen, T.S. (2021). Behavioral contract law. Rev. Law Econ. https://doi.org/10.1515/rle-2021-0067.Search in Google Scholar

Vanberg, C. (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica 76: 1467–1480.Search in Google Scholar

Wilson, J.Q. and Kelling, G.L. (1982). Police and neighborhood safety. Broken windows. Atl. Mon. 127: 29–38.Search in Google Scholar

Zamir, E. and Teichman, D. (2014). The oxford handbook of behavioral economics and the law. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Zamir, E. and Teichman, D. (2018). Behavioral law and economics. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2021-11-22

© 2021 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 26.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2021-0068/html
Scroll to top button