Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-10T14:12:30.495Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Japanese foreign economic policy: the domestic bases for international behavior

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

By many criteria, Japan is weak internationally. As a consequence one would expect its foreign economic policy to have been marked by limited choice, weakness, and constant vacillation in the face of external pressures. The domestic political structures of the country, however, have for most of the period since World War II permitted wide choice, strength, and consistency. A corporatist coalition of finance, major industry, trading companies, and the upper levels of the national bureaucracy, coupled with the consistent rule of the conservative Liberal Democratic Party, the systematic exclusion of organized labor from formal policy-making channels, and the lack of social overhead spending, has permitted the Japanese state to function as official doorman determining what, and under what conditions, capital, technology, and manufactured products enter and leave Japan. The strengths acquired from such past policies make it likely that the Japanese state will remain capable of dealing with the increasing domestic and international threats to its capacity to make relatively autonomous choices about Japan's international economic behavior.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 This is surely an oversimplification of many diverse works; however, among the works which have moved generally in this direction are: Haas, Ernst B., Beyond the Nation-State (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1964)Google Scholar; Deutsch, Karl W., Nerves of Government (New York: Free Press, 1966)Google Scholar; The Analysis of International Relations (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1968)Google ScholarPubMed; Kindleberger, Charles, ed., The International Corporation (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Vernon, Raymond, Sovereignty at Bay (New York: Basic Books, 1971)Google Scholar; Morse, Edward L., Foreign Policy and Interdependence in Gaullist France (Princeton: Princeton University Press, (1973)Google Scholar; The Politics of Interdependence,” International Organization Vol. 23, (Spring 1969): 311–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cooper, Richard N., The Economics of Interdependence (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968)Google Scholar; Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S. Jr, Transnational Relations and World Politics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Richard Rosecrance and Arthur Stein, Interdependence in World Politics(forthcoming). The Keohane and Nye book includes a particularly useful bibliography on the subject of transnational relations, and the journal International Organization has published a number of significant articles on the problem.

2 See in particular Katzenstein, Peter J., “International Relations and Domestic Structures: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States,” International Organization Vol. 30, No. 1 (Winter 1976): l45CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Huntington, Samuel P., “Transnational Organizations in World Politics,” World Politics Vol. 25 (04 1973): 333–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

4 Ibid., p. 364.

5 The classic statement of this possibility comes from Lowi, Theodore J., “American Business, Public Policy, Case Studies and Political Theory,” World Politics Vol. 16 (07 1964): 677715CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See Zimmerman, William, “Issue Area and Foreign Policy Process: A Research Note in Search of a General Theory,” American Political Science Review Vol. 67 (12 1973): 1204–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar for an application to foreign policy problems. An application to Japanese politics can be found in Pempel, T.J., “Patterns of Policymaking: Higher Education,” in Pempel, T.J., ed., Polkymaking in Contemporary Japan (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1977)Google Scholar. Haruhiro Fukui has done a great deal of work on the problem in the area of Japanese foreign policy. See particularly his “Studies in Policymaking: A Review of the Literature,” and “Tanaka Goes to Peking: A Case Study in Foreign Policymaking,” in ibid.

6 Hisao, Kanamori, “Sekai Keizai no naka no Ninon,” in Gendai no Nihon Keizai, Ichirō, Okuma and Eitarō, Tsujimura, eds., (Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shimbunsha, 1975), p. 125Google Scholar.

7 Ibid., p. 132.

8 One of the earliest and more significant articles to make this point was Saburō, Ōkita, “Shigen Yunyūkoku Nihon o Jikaku seyo,” Chūō Kōron 963 (12 1967)Google Scholar. For a more recent version of his thinking, see Ōkita, , “Natural Resource Dependency and Japanese Foreign Policy,” Foreign Affairs Vol. 52 (07 1974): 714–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 See Hisao, Kanamori, Seminā: Nihon Keizai no Jōshiki (Tokyo: Nihon Hyōronsha, 1976), pp. 1618Google Scholar; Shintarō, Hayashi and Fukutarō, Watanabe, Kokusai Keizai Kyōshitsu (Tokyo: Yūhikaku, 1973), p. 55Google Scholar.

11 Norman, E.H., Japan's Emergence as a Modern State, Dower, John, ed., Origins of the Modern Japanese State: Selected Writings of E.H. Norman (New York: Pantheon, 1975)Google Scholar; Lockwood, William W., The Economic Development of Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1954)Google Scholar; Lockwood, , ed., The State and Economic Enterprise in Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yanaga, Chitoshi, Big Business in Japanese Politics (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968)Google Scholar; Pempel, T.J., “The Bureaucratization of Policymaking in Postwar Japan,” American Journal of Political Science Vol. 18 (11 1974): 647–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Harari, Ehud, “Japanese Politics of Advice in Comparative Perspective: A Framework for Analysis and a Case Study,” Public Policy Vol. 22 (Fall 1974): 537–77Google Scholar; Johnson, Chalmers, “The Reemployment of Retired Government Bureaucrats in Japanese Big Business,” Asian Survey Vol. 14 (11 1974): 953–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar, inter alia.

12 Thayer, Nathaniel B., How the Conservatives Rule Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969)Google Scholar; Fukui, Haruhiro, Party in Power (Canberra: Australian National University Press, 1970)Google Scholar.

13 Kiyoaki, Tsuji, Nihon Kanryōsei no Kenkyū (Tokyo: Tōkyō Daigaku Shuppan, 1969)Google Scholar; Yoshinori, Ide, “Sengo Kaikaku to Nihon Kanryōsei,” in Sengo Kaikaku, Vol. 3, Seiji Katei, Kenkyujo, Tokyo Daigaku Shakai Kagaku, ed. (Tokyo: Tōkyō Daigaku Shuppan, 1974), pp. 143–229Google Scholar.

14 Fukui, Party in Power; Thayer; Pempel, “Bureaucratization of Policymaking”; Johnson, Chalmers, “Japan: Who Governs? An Essay on Official Bureaucracy,” The Journal of Japanese Studies Vol. 2 (Autumn 1975): 128CrossRefGoogle Scholar, inter alia.

15 Pempel, “Bureaucratization of Policymaking,” takes up the reasons for some of the harmony.

16 Smith, Thomas C., Political Change and Industrial Development in Japan: Government Enterprise, 1868–1880 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1955)Google Scholar; Norman; Lockwood, Economic Development of Japan; Lockwood, ed., State and Economic Enterprise; Patrick, Hugh T., “The Phoenix Risen from the Ashes: Postwar Japan,” in Modern East Asia: Essays in Interpretation, Crowley, James B., ed., (New York: Haicourt, Brace and World, 1970): pp. 298335Google Scholar, inter alia.

17 Smith; Bieda, K., “Economic Planning in Japan,” Economic Record Vol. 45 (06 1969): 181205CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Yamamura, Kozo, Economic Policy in Postwar Japan (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1967)Google Scholar; Fukui, Haruhiro, “Economic Planning in Postwar Japan: A Case Study in Policy Making”, Asian Survey Vol. 12 (04 1972): 327–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Yanaga; Curtis, Gerald L., “Big Business and Political Influence,” in Modern Japanese Organization and Decision-Making, Vogel, Ezra, ed., (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), pp. 3370Google Scholar.

19 Kinenkai, Yano Tsuneta, ed., Nihon Kokusei Zue 1976 (Tokyo: Kokuseisha, 1976), p. 326Google Scholar, (hereafter Zue).

20 Takao, Shimura, Nihon Keizoi no Kōzō Hendō (Tokyo: Mineruba Shobō, 1973), pp. 4042Google Scholar. See also Boltho, Andrea, Japan: Economic Survey, 1953–1973 (London: Oxford University Press, 1975), p. 28Google Scholar; The Industrial Policy of Japan (Paris: OECD, 1972)Google ScholarPubMed, esp. Chapter 4.

21 Ibid., p. 70.

22 Zue, p. 324.

23 Yamamura, Kozo, “Structure is Behavior: An Appraisal of Japanese Economic Behavior, 1960 to 1972,” The Japanese Economy in International Perspective, Frank, Isaiah, ed., (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1975), p. 70Google Scholar. See also Shimura, pp. 29–39. Okuma and Tsujimura, Chapter 7.

24 One example of this can be found in technology usage and diffusion; see Masamu, Saito, “Diffusion Mechanisms of Technology and Industrial Transformation: Case of Small Scale Industries in Japan,” in Transfer of Technology for Small Industries (Paris: OECD, 1974)Google Scholar. 1974).

25 Gerald L. Curtis, in Vogel, p. 55.

26 On the trading companies elsewhere, see Bieda, K., The Structure and Operation of the Japanese Economy (New York: Wiley, 1970), p. 203Google Scholar. The only exceptions he notes are United Africa and Swiss Trading Corporations, both in South Africa, and Société Genéral in Belgium.

27 Ryūsuke, Kikuiri, ”Shōsha: Organizers of the World Economy,” Baldwin, Frank, trans., The Japan Interpreter Vol. 8 (Autumn 1973): 354Google Scholar. On Japanese trading companies see also Trading Houses in Japan,” The Oriental Economist Vol. 38 (01 1970): 3738Google Scholar; Emori, Morihisa, “The Japanese General Trading Company,” in Bergsten, C. Fred, ed., Toward a New World Trade Policy: The Maidenhead Papers (Boston: Lexington, 1975), pp. 127–35Google Scholar.

28 Henderson, Dan Fenno, Foreign Enterprise in Japan (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1973), p. 135Google Scholar. On the Bank and its role, see also Ackley, Gardner and Ishi, Hiromitsu, “Fiscal, Monetary and Related Policies,” in Asia's New Giant, Patrick, Hugh and Rosovsky, Henry, eds., (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1976), pp. 153247Google Scholar.

29 Boltho, p. 120.

30 Wallich, Henry C. and Wallich, Mable I., “Banking and Finance,” in Patrick and Rosovsky, pp. 293–98Google Scholar, deals with the formation of keiretsu.

31 Kazuo, Ōkōchi, Sengo Nihon no Rōdō Undō (Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten, 1955)Google Scholar; Kazuo, Ōkōchi and Hiroshi, Matsuo, Nihon Ródó KumiaiMonogatari: Shōwa (Tokyo: Chikuma Shobō, 1965)Google Scholar.

32 See the case study in Cole, Robert E., Japanese Blue Collar (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1971)Google Scholar. On unions more generally see also Cook, Alice, An Introduction to Japanese Trade Unionism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1966)Google Scholar; Okochi, K. et al. , Workers and Employers in Japan (Princeton and Tokyo: Princeton University Press and Tokyo University Press, 1974)Google Scholar. See also Yoshino, M.Y., Japan's Managerial System: Tradition and Innovation (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1968)Google Scholar.

33 This point is developed in Pernpel, T.J., “The Dilemma of Parliamentary Opposition in Japan,” Polity Vol. 8 (Fall 1975): 6379Google Scholar.

34 Lowi, Theodore J., The End of Liberalism (New York: Norton, 1969)Google Scholar.

35 K. Bieda, The Structure and Operation of the Japanese Economy.

36 See, inter alia, Gilpin, Robert, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation (New York: Basic Books, 1975)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gilpin, Robert, France in the Age of the Scientific State (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1968)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stephen Blank, “Britain: The Politics of Foreign Economic Policy, the Domestic Economy, and the Problem of Pluralistic Stagnation,” in this volume.

37 Kindleberger, Charles P., Power and Money (New York: Basic Books, 1970), p. 120CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38 On Japanese economic planning see, inter alia, Bieda, “Economic Policy in Japan”; Fukui, “Economic Planning in Postwar Japan”; Watanabe, Tsunehiko, “National Planning and Economic Growth in Japan,” in Quantitative Planning of Economic Policy, Hickman, Bert, ed., (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1965), pp. 233–51Google Scholar.

40 On MITI see Yūuichirō, Noguchi, Nihon no Keizai Nashonarizumu (Tokyo: Diyamondo-sha, 1976), esp. Chapter 1Google Scholar; Yasuharu, Honda, Ninon Neokanryō-ron (Tokyo: Kōdansha, 1974), Chapter 1Google Scholar; Daizō, Kusayanagi, Kanryō Ōkokuron (Tokyo: Bungei Shungū, 1975), pp. 251–77Google Scholar. See also the forthcoming essay by Chalmers Johnson on MITI in Scalapino, Robert, The Foreign Policy of Modern Japan (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, forthcoming)Google Scholar.

41 Hadley, Eleanor, Antitrust in Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970)Google Scholar. Also Kozo Yamamura, Economic Policy in Postwar Japan.

42 Kaplan, Eugene J., Japan: The Government-Business Relationship (Washington: US Government Printing Office, 1972), pp. 77158Google Scholar.

43 Iinkai, Kōsei Torihiki, Kósei Torihiki Iinkai Nenji Hókoku (Tokyo: Ókurashó Insatsu Kyoku, 1975), p. 177Google Scholar.

44 Zue, p. 414.

45 Ibid., p. 416.

46 Komiya, Ryutaro, “Japan and the World Economy,” in Bergsten, , Toward a New World Trade Policy, p. 191Google Scholar.

47 Drysdale, Peter, ed., Direct Foreign Investment in Asia and the Pacific (Sydney: Australian National University Press, 1972)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ozawa, Terutomo, Japan's Technological Challenge to the West, 1950–1974 (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1974), esp. Chapter 2Google Scholar; Peck, Merton J. and Tamura, Shūji, “Technology,” in Patrick, and Rosovsky, , pp. 525–85Google Scholar.

48 It was then, for example, that the ban was lifted on computers.

49 Trezise, Philip H. and Suzuki, Yukio, “Politics, Government, and Economic Growth in Japan,” in Patrick, and Rosovsky, , p. 798Google Scholar.

50 Texas Instrument's Annual Report; see also Business Week, January 27, 1968, p. 132.

51 Hall, G.R. and Johnson, R.E., “Transfers of United States Aerospace Technology to Japan,” in The Technology Factor in International Trade, Vernon, Raymond, ed., (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970), pp. 305–58Google Scholar, provides a detailed assessment of the role within this one area. See also Henderson, p. 229, which notes that 30 percent of Japanese industry operates on foreign technology.

52 Ibid., p. 87.

53 Hollerman, Leon, “Foreign Trade in Japan's Economic Transition,” in Frank, , p. 191Google Scholar; Fukuda, Haruko, Japan and World Trade: The Years Ahead (Westmead: Saxon House, 1973), pp. 7781Google Scholar; Hayashi and Watanabe, pp. 83–86.

54 Chōsakai, Rinji Gyōsei, Kyōkan Kyōgōhan Bōeki Kankei Kyoninka Jimu no uchi Kakuschōcho ni wataru mono ‘Kyōkan Kyōgō’ ni kan suri Kaizenan, Part I (06 1964)Google Scholar, passim.

55 See also Bunko, Nikkei, ed., Bōeki no Chishiki (Tokyo: Nihon Keizai Shimbunsha, 1973), p. 175Google Scholar, for earlier figures; pp. 165–77, for an analysis.

56 Seietsurō, Iida, “Nihon Keizai no Kikō to Kōdo Seichō no Shikumi,” in Shōwa no Sengoshi IV, Saburō, Ienaga et al. , eds., (Tokyo: Sekibunsha, 1976), pp. 2329Google Scholar.

57 Ibid, p. 30.

58 For an excellent discussion of this problem see Tsurumi, Yoshi, “Japan,” Daedalus, Special Issue: The Oil Crisis in Perspective Vol. 104 (Fall 1975): 113–27Google Scholar.

59 Henderson, passim.

60 Ibid., p. 17.

62 Allen, G.C., “Japan's Place in Trade Strategy,” in Trade Strategy and the Asia-Pacific Region, Colbert, Hugh, ed., (London: Allen and Unwin, 1970), p. 65Google Scholar. Okita, Yoichi, “Japan's Fiscal Incentives for Exports,” in , Frank, pp. 207–30Google Scholar.

63 Ibid. The cost of these incentives in terms of lost tax revenues is calculated by the Ministry of Finance annually and from 1962 through 1971 they came to well over $40 billion. Okita, , “Japan's Fiscal Incentives…,” p. 219Google Scholar; my calculations.

64 Yanaga, pp. 205 ff.; Halliday, Jon and McCormack, Gavan, Japanese Imperialism Today (Middlesex: Penguin, 1973), pp. 2023Google Scholar.

65 Kunihiko, Ogawa, Kuroi Keizai Kyōryoku (Tokyo: Shimpō Shinsho, 1974)Google Scholar, goes into some of the more sordid arrangements involving former prime ministers' benefits from various reparations, for example, based on records of the National Diet. Olson, Lawrence, Japan in Postwar Asia (New York: Praeger, 1968), also provides some insightful examples of the sameGoogle Scholar.

66 Jun, Nishikawa, Shigen Nashonarizumu (Tokyo: Diyamondo-sha, 1974), pp. 338Google Scholar; Ogawa, passim. In 1975, 37 percent of Japan's exports and 49 percent of its imports came from Asia, , Zue, p. 147Google Scholar. One-quarter of its direct overseas investments were in South Asia; see Sangyōshō Sangyō Seisakukyoku, Tsūshō, Wagakuni Kigyō no Kaigai Jigyō Katsudō (Tokyo: Ókurashō Insatsukyoku, 1975), p. 234Google Scholar.

67 Ozaki, Robert S., “Japan's Role in Asian Economic Development,” Asian Survey Vol. 7 (04 1967), p. 241CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

68 Hasegawa, Sukehiro, Japanese Foreign Aid: Policy and Practice (New York: Praeger, 1975), p. 25Google Scholar.

69 Ibid.; Hayashi and Watanabe, pp. 244–48; Gaimushō, , Kokusai Kyōryoku Handobukku (Tokyo: Kokusai Kyōryoku Kenkyūkai, 1975), pp. 624–32Google Scholar; Kaigai Keizai Kyōryoku Binran 1975–76 (Tokyo: Kaigai Keizai Kyóryoku Kikin Chósa Kaihatsubu, 1975), pp. 316–63Google Scholar; Seisakukyoku, Tsūshō Sangyōshō Tsūshō, Keizai Kyōryoku no Genjō to Mondaiten (Tokyo: Okurashō Insatsukyoku, 1975), inter aliaGoogle Scholar.

70 My thanks to Alan G. Rix for a number of conversations on his on-going research into this area and for several unpublished drafts of papers in which he amply demonstrates this point.

71 Consultants, Dodwell Marketing, Japanese Companies' Overseas Investments (Tokyo: Dodwell, 1974), p. 6Google Scholar; Yoshino, M.Y., “Japanese Foreign Direct Investment,” in , Frank, p. 251Google Scholar; Kaigai Keizai Kyóryoku Binran 1975–76, pp. 432–33.

72 Among the most noteworthy are Indonesia, South Korea, and the Philippines. Taiwan does not receive “aid,” yet it is the recipient of many generous commercial packages which would appear to be tied to the common conservative and anti-Communist orientations of the leaders of Taiwan and Japan.

73 It is perhaps interesting to note, for example, that a project now under discussion between the Ministry of Transport and the Indonesian government to provide navigation equipment in the Malacca Straits involves equipment that is produced only by Japan's Fujitsū.

74 My calculations from “Zuhyō ni miru Sengo Sanjúnenkan no Senshin Rokkakoku Keuizai no Suii,” Ekonomisuto 1 March 1976, p. 80.

75 Zue, pp. 96–98.

76 Sautter, Christian, Japan: Le Prix de la Puissance (Paris: Editions du Seuil, 1973)Google Scholar, translated into Japanese, as Japon: Sono Keizairyōku wa Honmono ka? (Tokyo: Sangyō Nōritsu Tanki Daigaku Shuppan, 1974), p. 60Google Scholar.

77 Keiichirō, Isoda, Nihon Bōeki no Mirai (Tokyo: Tōyō Keizai Shimpōsha, 1972), p. 92Google Scholar.

78 Zue, p. 117.

79 Tsūshō Sangyōshō, Tsūshō Hakusho 1975. See also Krause, Lawrence and Sekiguchi, Sueo, “Japan and the World Economy,” in Patrick, and Rosovsky, , p. 409, for a more technical assessment of the changing nature of Japanese exportsGoogle Scholar.

80 Gilpin, Robert, “The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations,” in Keohane, and Nye, , p. 53Google Scholar.

81 OECD, Statistiques de Recettes Publiques de Pays Membres de I'OECD 1965–72 (Paris: OECD, 1975), p. 24Google Scholar.

82 See Patrick and Rosovsky, pp. 36–37; Sethi, S. Prakash, Japanese Business and Social Conflict (Cambridge: Ballinger, 1975), p. 10Google Scholar; Seiichirō, Saitō, “Atarashii Kokumin Seikatsu no Kōzu,” in Sekai no naka no Nihon Keizai, Takuji, Shimano, ed., (Tokyo: Gakuyō Shobō, 1975), pp. 6263Google Scholar.

83 Jinushi, Shigeyoshi, “Social Security System in Transition,” Developing Economies Vol. 10 (12 1972): 501CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84 Ibid., pp. 501–12.

85 Ministry of Education, Educational Standards in Japan, 1970 (Tokyo: Ministry of Education, 1971), pp. 145–46Google Scholar; Pempel, T.J., “The Politics of Enrollment Expansion in Japanese Universities,” Journal of Asian Studies Vol. 33 (11 1973): 6786CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

86 Wilensky, Harold L., The Welfare State and Equality (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), pp. 3031Google Scholar.

87 Boltho, pp. 84–93; Blumenthal, T., Saving in Postwar Japan (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki, Personal Savings and Consumption in Postwar Japan (Tokyo: Kinokuniya, 1970), inter aliaGoogle Scholar.

88 Boltho, p. 181.

89 My calculations from Japan Statistical Index, various years.

90 Yoshio, Andō, Kindai Nihon Keizaishi Yóran (Tokyo: Tōkyō Daigaku Shuppan, 1975), pp. 1012, 180Google Scholar.

91 On the different measures, see inter alia, Bieda, , The Structure and Operation of the Japanese Economy, p. 41Google Scholar.

92 Cole, Robert E., “Japanese Workers, Unions and the Marxist Appeal,” The Japan Interpreter Vol. 6 (Summer 1970): 118–19Google Scholar.

93 See inter alia, Funahashi, Naomichi, “The Industrial Reward System: Rewards and Benefits,” in Okochi, et al. , eds., Workers and Employers in Japan, pp. 383–89Google Scholar.

94 Ekonomisuto,1 March 1976, p. 83.

95 Noguchi, Chapter 1.

96 Vishwanathan, Savitri, Normalization of Japanese-Soviet Relations, 1945–1970 (Tallahassee: Diplomatic Press, 1973), pp. 101 ffGoogle Scholar; Hunsbergei, Warren, Japan and the United States in World Trade (New York: Harper and Row, 1964), pp. 213–14Google Scholar.

97 Destler, I.M. et al. , “The Textile Wrangle: Conflict in Japanese-American Relations 1969–71” (1976, processed manuscript)Google Scholar.

98 Based on the US-Japan Trade Council, United States Exports to Japan and United States Imports from Japan (various dates).

99 Gilpin, , U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation, pp. 109–11Google Scholar; Langdon, F. C., Japan's Foreign Policy (Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1974)Google Scholar; Patterson, Gardner, Discrimination in International Trade: The Policy Issue, 1945–1965 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1966), pp. 272307, inter aliaCrossRefGoogle Scholar.

100 Halliday and McCormack, pp. 11–12.

101 Kiause and Sekiguchi, in Patrick and Rosovsky, p. 419.

102 Ozawa, pp. 74–75; The Japan Economic Journal, 10 October 1972.

103 Fukui, , Party in Power, p. 229Google Scholar.

104 Langdon, p. 178.

105 Haruhiio Fukui, “Tanaka Goes to Peking,” in Pempel, Policymaking in Contemporary Japan.

106 Halliday and McCormack, p. 232.

107 On Tyumen, see Curtis, Gerald L., “The Tyumen Oil Project and Japanese Foreign Policy,” paper presented at the Research Conference on Japanese Foreign Policy, Kauai, Hawaii, 14–18 01 1974Google Scholar; Hitchcock, David Jr., “Joint Development of Siberia: Decision-Making in Japanese Foreign Relations,” Asian Survey Vol. 11 (03 1971): 279300CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

108 Curtis, “The Tyumen Oil Project and Japanese Foreign Policy.”

109 It should be noted that most of these pressures which did conflict with Japanese domestic political thrusts had their own domestic motivations. Most notably, pressures against Japan to reduce exports came as a consequence of organized economic groups within the relevant states. Correspondingly, pressures for liberalization of capital movements and imports came from businesses most likely to take advantage of these changes. Nothing surprising should be found in this observation; it is simply a reaffirmation of the domestic sources of much of international behavior.

110 Zue, p. 201.

111 On voluntary restrictions, see Patterson, pp. 307–17; Lynch, John, Toward an Orderly Market: An Intensive Study of Japan's Voluntary Quota on Cotton Textile Exports (Tokyo: Sophia University, 1968)Google Scholar, passim; Bergsten, C. Fred, “On the Non-Equivalence of Import Quotas and Voluntary Export Restraints,” in Bergsten, , New World Trade Policy, pp. 239–71Google Scholar.

112 Consider only the major problems posed for the Japanese budget by government support for rice prices to meet the political demands of farmers. See Michael W. Donnelly, “Setting the Price of Rice: A Study in Political Decision-Making,” in Pempel, Policymaking in Contemporary Japan.

113 The comments of Joseph S. Nye, Jr., and Stephen D. Cohen at the Conference on Foreign Economic Policy of Advanced Industrial States were particularly helpful in developing this point. More generally, see Simmel, Georg, Conflict and the Web of Group-Affiliations (New York: Free Press, 1955)Google Scholar and Coser, Lewis, The Functions of Social Conflict (New York: Free Press, 1956), passimGoogle Scholar.

114 Zue, p. 102.

115 Margaret McKean, “Pollution and Policymaking,” in Pempel, Policymaking in Contemporary Japan.

116 See, as examples: Economic Planning Agency, Basic Economic and Social Plan: 1973–1977 (Tokyo: Government Printing Office, 1973)Google Scholar; Shingikai, Sangyō Kōzō, Sangyō Kōzō no ChōkiBijon (Tokyo: Tsúshó Sangyó Chósakai, 1975)Google Scholar.

117 The Economist, 4 December 1976, p. 104.

118 See especially Beigsten, C. Fred, “The Threat from the Third World,” “The Threat Is Real,” and “The Response to the Third World,” Foreign Policy Vols. 11, 14, 17 (Summer 1973Google Scholar; Spring 1974; Winter 1974–75).

119 See the sources cited in fn. 116 plus Japan External Trade Organization, Japan: Into the Multinationalization Era (Tokyo: Press International, 1973)Google ScholarPubMed, and Japan as an Export Market (Tokyo: JETRO, n.d., probably 1972)Google Scholar; Tsūshō Sangyōshō Sangyō Seisakukyoku, Wagakuni Kigyō no Kaigai Jigyō Katsudō; Tsūshō Sangyōshō Tsūshō Seisakukyoku, Keizai Kyōryoku no Genjō to Mondaiten, Chapter 2; Tsūshō Sangyōshō, Tsūshō Hakusho 1975, passim, but esp. Part I, Chapter 2 and Part II, Chapters 2 and 3, inter alia.

120 My thinking on this point has been helped considerably by discussions with Richard Rosecrance. A more optimistic perception of the role to be played by new international forces, particularly the multinational corporation, can be found in Diebold, John, “Multinational Corporations: Why Be Scared of Them?Foreign Policy Vol. 12 (Fall 1973): 7995CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

121 Shishido, Toshio, “The Framework of Decision-Making in Japanese Economic Policies,” in Perspectives on U.S.-Japan Economic Relations, Taylor, Allen, ed., (Cambridge: Ballinger, 1973), p. 205Google Scholar.

122 Ibid.

123 Japan Transport Economics Research Center, Illustrated Transport Economy of Japan, 1974 (Tokyo: Japan Transport Economics Research Center, 1974), pp. 4041Google Scholar.

124 Tsurumi, p. 124. On the oil shock and its domestic political consequences, see also Juster, Kenneth I., “Japanese Foreign Policy Making During the Oil Crisis,” (unpublished honors thesis, Department of Government, Harvard University, 03 1976)Google Scholar.

125 See inter alia Varon, Bension and Takeuchi, Kenji, “Developing Countries and Non-Fuel Minerals,” Foreign Affairs Vol. 52 (04 1974): 497510CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Moran, Theodore H., “New Deal or Raw Deal in Raw Materials,” Foreign Policy Vol. 5 (Winter 19711972): 119–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Krasnei, Stephen D., “Oil is the Exception,” Foreign Policy Vol. 14 (Spring 1974): 6884CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Weinstein, Franklin B., “Multinational Corporations and the Third World: The Case of Japan and Southeast Asia,” International Organization Vol. 30, No. 3 (Summer 1976): 373404CrossRefGoogle Scholar.