Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Conscription and the developing countries

  • Research article
  • Published:
International Journal of Economic Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many countries, mostly ones with developing economies, still have conscription. This study explains why, based on the costs of different recruitment systems. A conscription system can be costly to set up, and misallocates labor compared to all-volunteer recruitment, but entails a smaller wage bill. In a developing country with a highly distorting tax system, the burden of taxes needed to finance the higher wage bill of an all-volunteer military can be larger than the burdens that are unique to a conscription system. The highly burdensome taxes that the government of a developing country with a large informal sector must rely upon mean that its variable cost of staffing a government labor force or army by an all-volunteer system is greater than that of a developed country that can levy less distorting taxes. The minimum force size for which conscription has lower cost than voluntary recruitment is higher, the greater the tax distortion. Furthermore, to economize on training cost, a country with a more distorting tax system is more likely to have a lottery, with longer service obligation than if it did not have a lottery. The upshot is that a country with a distorting tax system is more likely to have conscription, and if it does have conscription, is more likely to have a lottery system, with longer service obligation than if it did not have a lottery and drafted an entire age cohort. If our reasoning is correct, countries with less efficient tax systems, wishing to recruit larger fractions of their labor forces, would be more likely to have conscription with longer service obligations. We show that such patterns are indeed present in the data—a cross section of 104 countries observed around 2012. In this way, we explain why many developing countries continue to impose conscription even as the developed countries are abandoning it.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. [Imbens and van der Klauuw [13]] find that former draftees in the Netherlands have 5% lower salaries than their birth cohorts, on average. Bingley [4] find that high-ability former draftees faced a 7% earning penalty in Denmark. Grenet et al. [10] and [Bauer et al. [2]] find no effect of military conscription on wages—in Britain and in Germany. [Card and Cardoso [5]] find a positive effect of conscription on the wage of the low-educated in Portugal. Galiani et al. [8], and Hjalmarsson and Lindquist [12] find that those having been conscripted were more likely to later commit crimes—in Argentina and in Sweden, which further indicates how conscription preempts the formation of human capital. However, there is apparently no relationship between conscription and crime in Denmark [Albæk[1]].

  2. Mulligan and Shleifer [17] also include conscription with “exemption” and with “replacement” in their analysis. Conscription with exemption means that students, parents, workers in designated industries, and such, are exempted from service. And conscription with replacement means that a draftee may pay another person to serve in his or her place, or may pay a monetary tax in lieu of service. Conscription with replacement can be found in the American Civil War (1861–1865), in which 81% of draftees made a monetary payment as a commutation fee or to hire a substitute (Mulligan [18]). Lack of data prevents us from extending our cross-country empirical analysis to take into account which countries have conscription systems with exemption or replacement.

  3. From: Institute for Economics and Peace, Global Peace Index, 2016, p. 99:

    “Assessment of the intensity of contentiousness of neighbors, ranked from 1–5 (peaceful to very aggressive) by the EIU’s Country Analysis team. Country analysts are asked to assess this indicator on an annual basis, for the period March to March.

    Scoring Criteria: basis, for the period March to March.

    Scoring Criteria:

    1 = Peaceful: None of the neighbors has attacked the country since 1950.

    2 = Low: The relationship with neighbors is generally good, but aggressiveness is manifest in politicians’ speeches or in protectionist measures.

    3 = Moderate: There are serious tensions and consequent economic and diplomatic restrictions from other countries.

    4 = Aggressive: Open conflicts with violence and protests.

    5 = Very aggressive: Frequent invasions by neighboring countries.

  4. The raw observations on relationships with neighboring countries are taken from the website of the Institute for Economics and Peace which uses it as a component of its “Global Peace Index,” at this link: http://www.visionofhumanity.org/#/page/indexes/global-peace-index. After accessing this link, click on “specify indicator”, and select “neighboring countries relations,” from the drop-down menu. Then click on “global rankings” .

References

  1. Albæk, K., Leth-Petersen, S., Le Maire, D., & Tranæs, T. (2013). Does peacetime military service affect crime?. IZA Discussion Paper No. 7528.

  2. Bauer, T. K., Bender, S., Paloyo, A. R., & Schmidt, C. M. (2012). Evaluating the labour-market effects of compulsory military service. European Economic Review, 56(4), 814–829.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Besley, Timothy, & Persson, Torsten. (2014). Why do developing countries tax so little? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(4), 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bingley, P., Lundborg, P., & Lyk-Jensen, S. Vincent. (2014). Opportunity cost and the incidence of a draft lottery. IZA Discussion Paper No. 8057.

  5. Card, D., & Cardoso, A. R. (2012). Can compulsory military service raise civilian wages? Evidence from the Peacetime draft in Portugal. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4(4), 57–93.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Central Intelligence Agency. (annual). The CIA Factbook. Virginia.

  7. Economist magazine. (2011). Conscription a farewell to arms: Military service lingers in countries that are poor or small, but elsewhere it is on the way out, September 10, 2011.

  8. Galiani, Sebastian, Rossi, Martín A., & Schargrodsky, Ernesto. (2011). Conscription and crime: Evidence from the Argentine draft lottery. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3(2), 119–136.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Gordon, Roger, & Li, Wei. (2009). Tax structures in developing countries: Many puzzles and a possible explanation. Journal of Public Economics, 93((7–8)), pp. 855–866, Aug.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Grenet, J., Hart, R., & Roberts, E. (2011). Above and beyond the call: Long-term real earnings effects of British male military conscription in the post-war years. Labour Economics, 18(2), 194–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Hall, Joshua C. (2011). The Worldwide decline in conscription: A victory for Economics? October 3, 2011. Library of Economics and Liberty. Retrieved July 15, 2016 from the World Wide Web: http://www.econlib.org/library/Columns/y2011/Hallconscription.html.

  12. Hjalmarsson, R., & Lindquist, Matthew J. (2016). The causal effect of military conscription on crime and the labour market, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 11110.

  13. Imbens, Guido, & van der Klauuw, Wilbert. (1995). Evaluating the cost of conscription in the Netherlands. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 13(2), 207–215.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Institute for Economics and Peace (website). Global Peace Index. http://www.visionofhumanity.org/#page/indexes/global-peace-index/. Accessed 12 Dec 2015.

  15. International Institute for Strategic Studies (annual). The Military Balance. London, various issues.

  16. La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer, Andrei, & Vishny, Robert. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 15(1), 222–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Mulligan, Casey, & Shleifer, Andrei. (2005). Conscription as regulation. American Law and Economics Review, 7(1), 85–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Mulligan, C. (2015). In-kind taxes, behavior, and comparative advantage, NBER Working Paper 21586.

  19. Park, C-Y. & Mercado, R. Jr. (2015). Financial inclusion, poverty, and income inequality in developing Asia, ADB working paper series no. 426/2015, Asian Development Bank, Singapore Economic Review (forthcoming). http://hdl.handle.net/11540/2272. Accessed 12 Dec 2015.

  20. Prichard, Wilson, Cobham, Alex C., & Goodall, Andrew. (2014). The ICTD Government Revenue Dataset (September 1, 2014). ICTD Working Paper 19.

  21. Ross, Thomas. (1994). Raising an army: A positive theory of military recruitment. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 109–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Siems, Mathias M. (2007). Legal origins: Reconciling law and finance and comparative law. McGill Law Journal, 52(1), 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Slemrod, Joel. (1990). Optimal taxation and optimal tax systems. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(1), 157–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Sweden to reintroduce conscription amid rising Baltic tensions, The Guardian, March 2, 2017.

  25. Tarabar, Danko, & Hall, Joshua, C. (2016). Explaining the worldwide decline in the length of mandatory military service, 1970–2010. Public Choice, 168(1), 55–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Toronto, N. (2005). Military Recruitment Data Set, version 2005.1. Available from the author at nathan.toronto@us.army.mil.

  27. War Resisters’ International (website). World survey of conscription and conscientious objection to military service. http://www.wri-irg.org/co/rtba/.

  28. World Bank (website). World Development Indicators. http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-development-indicators.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David Flath.

Appendix A.1. Data sources

Appendix A.1. Data sources

There are several sources from which one can construct panel data on conscription systems for about 150 countries, from 2008 to 2013. These are CIA (CIA Factbook) [6], IISS (The Military Balance) [15], War Resisters’ International website (WRI) [27], and Toronto [26]. However, only CIA Factbook and Military Balance have updated editions annually, while the other two do not reflect the change in policy of countries in the more recent years. That is a reason why Military Balance and CIA Factbook have been used, while WRI and Toronto [26] are references to consult for past patterns. For cross-section analysis we extract the most recent observations from Military Balance and CIA Factbook and use that to code a dummy variable equal to one if a country is using a conscription system to actively recruit and 0 if it is using an all-volunteer system.

Turning to independent variables, information for government revenue relative to GDP, and percentage of total tax revenue derived from different kinds of taxes, are collected from Prichard [20]. Their dataset was compiled from many sources, including IMF (World Economic Outlook, Government Finance Statistics, and Country reports), OECD, and CEPAL (Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe).

There are two variables for institutional factors. These are British legal origin, Socialist legal origin. La Porta et al. [16] have data for legal origins, but their data does not reflect the post-Cold-War change of East European countries, reverting to German and French legal origins as shown by Siems [22]. We incorporate the Siems changes into our variables.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vuong, N.D.T., Flath, D. Conscription and the developing countries. IJEPS 13, 119–146 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-018-0004-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-018-0004-5

Keywords

Navigation