Skip to main content
Log in

The Coleman–Shapley index: being decisive within the coalition of the interested

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Coleman power of a collectivity to act (CPCA) is a popular statistic that reflects the ability of a committee to pass a proposal. Applying the Shapley value to that measure, we derive a new power index—the Coleman–Shapley index (CSI)—indicating each voter’s contribution to the CPCA. The CSI is characterized by four axioms: anonymity, the null voter property, the transfer property, and a property stipulating that the sum of the voters’ power equals the CPCA. Similar to the Shapley–Shubik index (SSI) and the Penrose–Banzhaf index (PBI), our new index reflects the expectation of being a pivotal voter. Here, the coalitional formation model underlying the CPCA and the PBI is combined with the ordering approach underlying the SSI. In contrast to the SSI, voters are ordered not according to their agreement with a potential bill, but according to their vested interest in it. Among the most interested voters, power is then measured in a way similar to the PBI. Although we advocate the CSI over the PBI so as to capture a voter’s influence on whether a proposal passes, our index gives new meaning to the PBI. The CSI is a decomposer of the PBI, splitting the PBI into a voter’s power as such and the voter’s impact on the power of the other voters by threatening to block any proposal. We apply our index to the EU Council and the UN Security Council.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We do without the assumption \(N\in {\mathcal {W}}\) frequently made in the literature. This extends the domain of our axioms. However, our results would also hold true if the axioms were restricted to the smaller domain.

  2. Working on a fixed set \(N,\) we omit it in the following and, e.g., write \({\text {CPCA}}\left( {\mathcal {W}}\right)\) instead of \({\text {CPCA}}\left( N, {\mathcal {W}}\right)\).

  3. Mann and Shapley (1964), Felsenthal and Machover (1996), Kurz and Napel (2018) and Bernardi and Freixas (2018) generalize this definition/interpretation of the Shapley–Shubik index by considering more or less general probability distributions on roll call votes, which consist of a rank ordering of the voters and information on their voting behavior, yea or nay.

  4. Equation (3) is not only satisfied by the CSI. Yet, CSI is the only index that itself is decomposable. Indeed, decomposability (i.e., requiring that there exists an index that decomposes) and 2CPCA-Efficiency are characteristic of the CSI.

  5. Note that although 2Efficiency requires invariance of the merging voters’ power, it is silent about the other players’ power, such that the proportions of power might change.

  6. We use the EU population sizes on 01.01.2017 rounded up to the nearest ten (http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat). Detailed numbers can be found in online supplementary materials.

References

  • Amaral, J., & Tsay, A. A. (2009). How to win “spend” and influence partners: Lessons in behavioral operations from the outsourcing game. Production and Operations Management, 18(6), 621–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, J. F. (1965). Weighted voting does not work: A mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Review, 19, 317–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, N., Paeglis, I., & Rahnamaei, M. (2016). Multiple blockholders, power, and firm value. Journal of Banking & Finance, 66, 66–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bena, J., & Xu, T. (2017). Competition and ownership structure of closely held firms. Review of Financial Studies, 30(5), 1583–1626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardi, G., & Freixas, J. (2018). The Shapley value analyzed under the Felsenthal and Machover bargaining model. Public Choice, 176(3–4), 557–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertini, C., Freixas, J., Gambarelli, G., & Stach, I. (2013). Comparing power indices. International Game Theory Review, 15(2), 1340004–1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casajus, A. (2012). Amalgamating players, symmetry, and the Banzhaf value. International Journal of Game Theory, 41(3), 497–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casajus, A. (2014). Collusion, quarrel, and the Banzhaf value. International Journal of Game Theory, 43(1), 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casajus, A., & Huettner, F. (2018). Decomposition of solutions and the Shapley value. Games and Economic Behavior, 108, 37–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1971). Control of collectivities and the power of a collectivity to act. In B. Lieberman (Ed.), Social choice. New York: Gordon and Breach.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubey, P., & Shapley, L. S. (1979). Mathematical properties of the Banzhaf power index. Mathematics of Operations Research, 4, 99–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einy, E. (1987). Semivalues of simple games. Mathematics of Operations Research, 26, 185–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einy, E., & Haimanko, O. (2011). Characterization of the Shapley–Shubik power index without the efficiency axiom. Games and Economic Behavior, 73(2), 615–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D., & Machover, M. (1996). Alternative forms of the Shapley value and the Shapley–Shubik index. Public Choice, 87(3–4), 315–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S., & Machover, M. (1998). The measurement of voting power: Theory and practice, problems and paradoxes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S., & Machover, M. (2001). The treaty of Nice and qualified majority voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 18, 431–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S., & Machover, M. (2004). A priori voting power: What is it all about? Political Studies Review, 2(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G., & Schmid, F. A. (2000). Universal banking and the performance of German firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 29–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haimanko, O. (2018). The axiom of equivalence to individual power and the Banzhaf index. Games and Economic Behavior, 108, 391–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibarzabal, N., & Laruelle, A. (2018). Ghost seats in parliaments. European Journal of Operational Research, 264(1), 354–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karos, D., & Peters, H. (2015). Indirect control and power in mutual control structures. Games and Economic Behavior, 92, 150–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köke, J., & Renneboog, L. (2005). Do corporate control and product market competition lead to stronger productivity growth? Evidence from market-oriented and blockholder-based governance regimes. Journal of Law and Economics, 48(2), 475–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S. (2016). Computing the power distribution in the IMF. Technical report, arXiv:1603.01443

  • Kurz, S., Maaser, N., & Napel, S. (2017). On the democratic weights of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 125(5), 1599–1634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S., Maaser, N., & Napel, S. (2018). Fair representation and a linear Shapley rule. Games and Economic Behavior, 108, 152–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S., & Napel, S. (2018). The roll call interpretation of the Shapley value. Economics Letters, 173, 108–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laruelle, A., & Valenciano, F. (2001). Shapley–Shubik and Banzhaf indices revisited. Mathematics of Operations Research, 26(1), 89–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (1988). The relationship between shareholding concentration and shareholder voting power in British companies: A study of the application of power indices for simple games. Management Science, 34(4), 509–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (2002a). Voting power in the governance of the international monetary fund. Annals of Operations Research, 109(1/4), 375–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (2002b). An empirical comparison of the performance of classical power indices. Political Studies, 50, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (2003). Computing power indices for large voting games. Management Science, 49(6), 831–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehrer, E. (1988). An axiomatization of the Banzhaf value. International Journal of Game Theory, 17(2), 89–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mann, I., & Shapley, L. (1964). Values of large games, IV: Evaluating the electoral college by Montecarlo techniques. Research Memorandum 2651, RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, CA.

  • Matsui, T., & Matsui, Y. (2000). A survey of algorithms for calculating power indices of weighted majority games. Journal of the Operations Research Society of Japan, 43(1), 71–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1972). Multilinear extensions of games. Management Science, 18(5, Part 2), 64–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1977). Values of games with a priori unions. In R. Henn & O. Moeschlin (Eds.), Essays in mathematical economics and game theory (pp. 76–88). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, L. (1946). The elementary statistics of majority voting. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 109(1), 53–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renneboog, L., & Trojanowski, G. (2011). Patterns in payout policy and payout channel choice. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(6), 1477–1490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S. (1953). A value for \(n\)-person games. In H. Kuhn & A. Tucker (Eds.), Contributions to the Theory of Games (Vol. 2, pp. 307–317). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S., & Shubik, M. (1954). A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. American Political Science Review, 48, 787–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiese, H. (2009). Applying cooperative game theory to power relations. Quality & Quantity, 43, 519–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the anonymous referees and the editors as well as to participants of several seminars, workshops, and conferences for helpful comments on our paper, particularly to Sergiu Hart and Annick Laruelle. Funded by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG, German Research Foundation)—388390901 and 288880950.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Frank Huettner.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 118 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Casajus, A., Huettner, F. The Coleman–Shapley index: being decisive within the coalition of the interested. Public Choice 181, 275–289 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00654-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00654-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation