Skip to main content
Log in

Europe Goes ‘Countercyclical’: A Legal Assessment of the New Countercyclical Dimension of the CRR/CRD IV Package

  • Article
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

One of the most innovative features of Basel III was the introduction of a new ‘countercyclical’ regulatory dimension for banks. In 2013, this dimension was operationalised in the European prudential framework included in the CRR/CRD IV package. Although the uniform implementation of these rules has been welcomed by the European legislator as creating a level playing field for banks and investment firms, this legal analysis reveals the existence of serious competitive disadvantages for small local and regional banks. While the largest entities are incentivised to exploit the arbitrage opportunities hidden in the CRR/CRD IV countercyclical provisions, such opportunities are not available to smaller entities. Thus, the unintended result of the new prudential framework seems to be not only a re-sizing of the banking balance sheets, but also a re-composition of the banking structures. In this paper, one of the building blocks of the Legal Theory of Finance, i.e., the construction of finance as a legal by-product is taken as a point of departure to show how the adoption of the new countercyclical rules paves the way for a new consolidation wave in the banking industry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See for the still ongoing debate on the causes of the 2007–2008 financial crisis, inter alia, Friedman (2010), Blanchard (2009), Blundell-Wignall et al. (2008), Claessens et al. (2013), Lin and Treichel (2012).

  2. See, for example, Cornelis (2015), Heremans and Bosquet (2011), Driesen (2014), Crawford (2011), Posner (2009).

  3. See Minsky (1986a, b, 1992a, b). For an overview of the theory, see also King (2013).

  4. See Pistor (2013).

  5. The IKE is a financial market theory developed in Frydman and Goldberg (2007). The contribution of the authors to the economic debate lies in the idea that markets do not achieve equilibrium outcomes, as asserted by the ECMH. Instead, the existence of imperfect knowledge as an inherent feature of financial markets leads to extreme asset price swings that eventually generate instability.

  6. The MVF may be considered as an extension of Minsky’s Financial Instability Hypothesis to contemporary financial markets and has been developed in Mehrling (2011). More importantly, according to the MVF, liquidity is strongly intertwined with imperfect knowledge and a critical determinant of asset price swings. For a discussion of the MVF and its regulatory suggestions, see Pistor (2012), at pp. 28–36.

  7. Pistor (2012), at p. 3.

  8. Pistor (2013), at pp. 317, 318; Sinapi (2011), at pp. 10, 11.

  9. Pistor (2013), at p. 318.

  10. Claessens and Kodres (2014), at p. 15.

  11. Pistor (2013), at p. 321.

  12. Pistor (2012), at p. 4.

  13. Pistor (2013), at p. 317.

  14. Pistor (2012), at p. 53.

  15. See McDonnell (2014), at p. 124.

  16. Idem.

  17. Idem.

  18. Borio et al. (2001), at p. 1.

  19. This feature of the financial cycle is usually referred as ‘financial accelerator’. For a better insight, see Bernanke et al. (1996, 1999).

  20. Borio et al. (2001), para. 2.3. See also Dierick (2004), at p. 51.

  21. A deeper perspective on the risk pricing issues arising from Basel II is given in Kashyap and Stein (2004).

  22. See infra, para. 2.3.

  23. Directive 2013/36/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013 on access to the activity of credit institutions and the prudential supervision of credit institutions and investment firms, OJ L 176, 27.6.2013, pp. 338–436.

  24. Regulation (EU) No. 575/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013 on prudential requirements for credit institutions and investment firms, OJ L 176, 27 June 2013, pp. 1–337.

  25. For example, in Germany, the CRD IV has been transposed into the national framework by way of the CRD IV Implementation Act (CRD-IV-Umsetzungsgesetz): see Bundesgesetzblatt Teil I Nr. 53 of 03 September 2013. In Italy, the EU package has been implemented through the Circular of Bank of Italy No. 285 of 17 December 2013.

  26. See BCBS (2011). For further insights on the Basel III framework, see Chorafas (2011). For a historical perspective on the Basel III implementation process, see Lyngen (2012).

  27. On the effects of the global financial crisis, see Ötker-Robe and Podpiera (2013), Ollivaud and Turner (2014), Gros and Alcidi (2010). For an interesting survey on how the financial crisis affected the fiscal positions of countries, see Tagkalakis (2013).

  28. See Gorton and Metrick (2012), para. 1. See also Gorton (2010), Solomon (2012).

  29. See, for example, Aksoy and Basso (2015), at p. 2.

  30. Chan (2011), at p. 1. For a critical assessment, see Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2012).

  31. Berrospide (2013), para. 3.1. For an overview of the stages of the financial crisis, see BIS (2009).

  32. For an empirical survey on the magnitude of banks’ loss-absorbing capacity and capital erosion during the financial crisis, see Strah et al. (2013). See also Rosengren (2013).

  33. BCBS (2011), para. 35. See also BCBS (2013), para. 2.

  34. Berrospide (2013), para. 1. For more details, see Gale and Yorulmazer (2011), Acharya and Merrouche (2013).

  35. Acharya and Merrouche (2013), para. 5. See also Heider et al.(2009), para. 1.

  36. On the issue, see Gorton and Metrick (2010), para. 4.

  37. For an empirical assessment, see Cornett et al. (2011). According to the authors, during the financial crisis, the poor management of liquidity risk was one of the main reasons for the decline in credit supply.

  38. BCBS (2011), paras. 8–10 and 11–15.

  39. On the issue, see BCBS (2011), para. 8. See also Musch et al. (2008), at pp. 107, 108.

  40. BCBS (2011), para. 11.

  41. See, in general, BCBS (2011), at p. 3. On the issue, see also D’Hulster (2009).

  42. BCBS (2011), paras. 40, 41. For technical insights on the LCR, see BCBS (2013).

  43. Idem, para. 42. For a technical survey on the final structure of the NSFR, see BCBS (2014b).

  44. BCBS (2011), para. 43.

  45. On the differences between microprudential and macroprudential regulatory framework, inter alia, see Schwarcz (2015). See also Kashyap et al. (2010), Borio (2003).

  46. Gordy and Howells (2006), at p. 395. See also Andersen (2011).

  47. Blundell-Wignall and Atkinson (2010), at p. 5.

  48. Idem, at pp. 5, 6.

  49. Idem, at p. 6.

  50. CGFS (2010), at p. 10.

  51. In particular, see the recommendations in FSF and BCBS (2009), at pp. 1–6.

  52. BCBS (2011), para. 18.

  53. Minsky (1986b), at p. 3. More generally, see also Delli Gatti et al. (1994), para. III, stating that to contain the eruption of a financial crisis, capitalist economies developed a set of institutions and authorities that can be considered as ‘circuit breakers’. For a deeper analysis of the role that institutions play in Minsky’s theory, see Sinapi (2011).

  54. See Caruana (2010), at pp. 3, 4.

  55. IMF (2012), at pp. 76 and 82.

  56. For the resulting aspect of risk sensitivity of Basel II, see BCBS (2011), paras. 20–22. See also FSF and BCBS (2009), at p. 2.

  57. BCBS (2011), paras. 20 and 33.

  58. See BCBS (2011), para. 97.

  59. Ibid, paras. 151–167. For a better understanding of the main features of the Basel III leverage ratio, see also BCBS (2014a).

  60. For a better understanding of how the leverage ratio behaves over the cycle, see Brei and Gambacorta (2014).

  61. BCBS (2011), para. 16.

  62. For an assessment of the impact of this forward-looking provisioning, see Cummings and Durrani (2014).

  63. See BCBS (2011), paras. 26–28 and 122–135.

  64. BCBS (2011), paras. 124–126.

  65. FSB, BIS and IMF (2011), at p. 5. See also Krishnamurti and Lee (2014), at pp. 33, 34. For a better understanding of the rationale and dynamics of macroprudential regulation, inter alia, see Hanson et al. (2011), Borio (2003, 2009), Borio and Shim (2007), Nier (2011), Gohari and Woody (2015). For a literature review, see Galati and Moessner (2011).

  66. More specifically, Basel III has designed the countercyclical capital buffer as an extension of the capital conservation buffer. Banks thus have to set up this integrated buffer above the regulatory minimum Tier 1 capital requirement, enlarging the size of its range. For the technical details, see BCBS (2011), Annex I.

  67. See, for example, the Recommendation of the ESRB of 18 June 2014 on guidance for setting countercyclical buffer rates (ESRB/2014/1), Recital (1). For a literature review on the mechanisms of shock transmission, see De Bandt and Hartmann (2000), at pp. 18–36.

  68. This opinion is shared by Repullo and Saurina (2011), at p. 4. Following the Basel III Accord, specific rules on the countercyclical capital buffers have been operationalised in the US and EU. In the US, the discipline is laid down in 12 CFR § 324.11—Capital conservation buffer and countercyclical capital buffer amount. In the EU, Art. 130 of Directive 2013/36/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2012 (Capital Requirement Directive IV, or CRD IV) establishes the European framework for the countercyclical capital buffer.

  69. This flexibility has been recognised in the European framework (CRR/CRD IV), where national authorities have great discretion in the calibration and application of the buffers. On the issue, see Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), at p. 63.

  70. For a definition of time-varying instruments, see Lim et al. (2011), at p. 5. For a survey on the efficiency of time-varying policy, see Sharma (2013).

  71. Repullo and Saurina (2011), at p. 3.

  72. Caruana and Cohen (2014), at p. 18. See also Jiménez et al. (2012), showing that countercyclical capital buffers have positive effects in terms of credit availability in bad times; for the optimality of having time-varying capital requirements to tolerate a greater probability of default when economy-wide bank capital is scarce relative to lending opportunities, cf. Kashyap and Stein (2004).

  73. BCBS (2011), paras. 146, 147.

  74. Idem, paras. 139–145.

  75. For further technical details of the operationalisation of the countercyclical capital buffers, see also Detken et al. (2014).

  76. Repullo and Saurina (2011), at p. 8.

  77. See BCBS (2010a), Annex 2. For a critical assessment of the credit-to-GDP gap in calibrating this buffer, see Repullo and Saurina (2011). See also Drehmann and Tsatsaronis (2014).

  78. Inter alia, see CRD IV, Recital (79), and CRR, Recital (90).

  79. See Recitals (9) and (10) CRR.

  80. Elizalde (2007), at p. 1.

  81. See Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), at pp. 56, 57. See also Recital (11) CRR.

  82. According to Recital (12) CRR, ‘shaping prudential requirements in the form of a regulation would ensure that those requirements will be directly applicable. This would ensure uniform conditions by preventing diverging national requirements as a result of the transposition of a directive. This Regulation would entail that all institutions follow the same rules in all the Union, which would also boost confidence in the stability of institutions, especially in times of stress. A regulation would also reduce regulatory complexity and firms’ compliance costs, especially for institutions operating on a cross-border basis, and contribute to eliminating competitive distortions’.

  83. For an overview of the characteristics of contingent convertible bonds, see Avdjiev et al. (2013). For a legal analysis of CoCos, see Biljanovska (2016).

  84. See, in particular, Art. 63 CRR.

  85. For an empirical assessment of the procyclical behaviour of credit institutions arising from the approaches for the calculation of risk weights as established in Basel II and III (i.e., Standardised Approach and IRB Approach), see Heid (2007).

  86. Art. 166(8) and (9) CRR.

  87. For a brief comparison of the CRR and the CRD III framework regarding the Standardised Approach, see Allen & Overy (2014a).

  88. Idem, at p. 3.

  89. For further details on the standards for the competent authorities’ assessment of an application to use the IRB Approach, cf. Art. 144 CRR.

  90. EBA (2015), at p. 32.

  91. Behn et al. (2014), at p. 2.

  92. For details, see BCBS (2001).

  93. For an interesting empirical study on the procyclicality underlying the IRB Approach, see Goodhart and Segoviano (2004).

  94. The CRR/CRD IV package does not directly introduce any accounting provisioning, as rules on accounting standards fall outside of the scope of the prudential package. However, the IRB Approach, albeit not dynamic, is certainly forward-looking as it is a model based on expected losses. On the role of dynamic provisioning in the CRR, see Burroni et al. (2009), at pp. 7–10. As stated in Recital (13) CRR, ‘in areas not covered by this Regulation, such as dynamic provisioning…, competent authorities or Member States should be able to impose national rules, provided that they are not inconsistent with this Regulation’.

  95. See Allen & Overy (2014b), at p. 4.

  96. The CRR defines the PD as the probability of default of a counterparty over a one-year period.

  97. The LGD is the ratio of the loss on an exposure due to the default of a counterparty to the amount outstanding at default.

  98. Using the words of the CRR, we refer to the amount outstanding at default.

  99. See Art. 162 CRR.

  100. See, in particular, Recitals (90) and (91) CRR.

  101. Art. 429(2) and (3) CRR.

  102. Art. 429(5) CRR.

  103. Art. 429(6) CRR.

  104. Art. 429(9) and (10) CRR.

  105. Recital (80) CRD IV.

  106. Art. 129(2) CRD IV.

  107. Art. 136 CRD IV.

  108. Art. 135 CRD IV.

  109. Art. 130(2) CRD IV.

  110. Art. 141 CRD IV.

  111. For a deeper understanding of the SREP, see Guidelines for common procedures and methodologies for the supervisory review and evaluation process (SREP). EBA/GL/2014/13, 19 December 2014.

  112. About the possibility to use the Pillar 2 instruments to counter procyclicality, see, in particular ESRB (2014), at pp. 133–140.

  113. Minsky (1986a, b, 1992a, b), at p. 219.

  114. Ibid; see also Palley (2013), at pp. 135, 136.

  115. See, in particular, Cerutti et al. (2015).

  116. Gerding (2013), at p. 261.

  117. Idem.

  118. Pistor (2013), at p. 327.

  119. Kaplan (2013).

  120. For incentive effects of capital requirements on off-balance sheet regulatory arbitrage in the case of securitisation contributing to the subprime crisis, cf. Calomiris (2009), at pp. 65, 66.

  121. European Commission (2013), at p. 4.

  122. See Recitals (9) and (10) CRR.

  123. Masera (2014), at pp. 394, 395.

  124. See Behn et al. (2014), at p. 2.

  125. See BCBS (2010b).

  126. Previously, other empirical studies acknowledged the same results. See, for example, Repullo and Suarez (2004), Rime (2003), Hakenes and Schnabel (2006).

  127. See, again, European Commission (2013), at p. 4.

  128. For this broad scope of application, cf. BCBS (2014c) at p. 10.

  129. On the issue, see Berger and Udell (2002). See also Berger et al. (2005).

  130. See Angelkort and Stuwe (2011), at pp. 6, 7. On the relationship between small local banks and SMEs financing, see also European Association of Cooperative Banks, ‘SMEs and co-operative banks are an essential part of the “real economy” of the EU’, Annex to EACB-UEAPME open letter, 21 November 2014. Similarly, on the fundamental role of SMEs, see Recital (44) CRR.

  131. Art. 501(2) CRR.

  132. For the definition of SMEs, see Commission Recommendation 2003/361/EC concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises, OJ 2003 L 124/36, Art. 2, stating that the category of SMEs is made up of enterprises which employ fewer than 250 persons and which have an annual turnover not exceeding EUR 50 million, and/or an annual balance sheet total not exceeding EUR 43 million.

  133. See Art. 123 CRR.

  134. See Art. 122 CRR.

  135. Angelkort and Stuwe (2011), at pp. 12, 13.

  136. See, for example, Eurochambres, Basel III-CRR/CRD IV, Position, Brussels, January 2012.

  137. On the channels of adjustment of banks’ capital following a regulatory increase of capital requirements, see Cohen (2013), at pp. 26, 27. See also Cohen and Scatigna (2014).

  138. Cohen and Scatigna (2014), at p. 1.

  139. See on the issue, Fitch Ratings. Basel III: return and deleveraging pressures. Macro Credit Research, 17 May 2012, available at www.fitchratings.com.

  140. Idem.

  141. See Timmermans (2012), at pp. 24–29.

  142. For these costs arising in different exemplary scenarios, see Baker and Wurgler (2015), Härle et al. (2010), at p. 2.

  143. For issues of new shares by large banks as examples, see Shotter J, ‘Commerzbank to raise €1.4bn to boost capital’, Financial Times, 27 April 2015, available at http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/aa01ae20-ecf8-11e4-a81a-00144feab7de.html#axzz3eMln6NxH; Aloisi S, Sassard S, ‘Monte Paschi approves capital increase for up to 2.5 billion euros’, Reuters, 5 November 2014, available at http://reut.rs/1shgwXX.

  144. See Conference of State Bank Supervisors (2011), at p. 4.

  145. Idem.

  146. Angelkort and Stuwe (2011), at pp. 11, 12.

  147. Cohen and Scatigna (2014), at p. 26.

  148. Idem.

  149. Timmermans (2012), at p. 14.

  150. Laeven et al. (2014), at p. 10. See also Masera (2013), at p. 395.

  151. Idem.

  152. See BCBS (2011), para. 152.

  153. Inter alia, Schäfer D, ‘Deutsche Bank to cut balance sheet to comply with leverage rules’, Financial Times, 30 July 2013, available at http://on.ft.com/12AHgvk. See also Stevens L, ‘Deutsche Speeds Up Plan to Shrink Size’, Wall Street Journal, 22 July 2013, available at http://on.wsj.com/1zFA6BZ.

  154. See Shotter J, ‘Commerzbank warns of future challenges’, Financial Times, 12 February 2015, available at http://on.ft.com/1MhJDqB.

  155. For better insights into the deleveraging process after the implementation of Basel III, see O’Sullivan and Kinsella (2011).

  156. See Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2015/62 of 10 October 2014 amending Regulation (EU) No. 575/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council with regard to the leverage ratio, OJ L 11, 17 January 2015, pp. 37–43.

  157. According to Art. 429(8), institutions may determine the exposure value of cash receivables and cash payables of repurchase transactions, securities or commodities lending or borrowing transactions, long settlement transactions and margin lending transactions with the same counterparty on a net basis only if: (a) the transactions have the same explicit final settlement date; (b) the right to set off the amount owed to the counterparty with the amount owed by the counterparty is legally enforceable in the normal course of business or in the event of default, insolvency and bankruptcy; (c) the counterparties intend to settle net, settle simultaneously, or the transactions are subject to a settlement mechanism that results in the functional equivalent of net settlement.

  158. Art. 429(10) CRR.

  159. Art. 429(11) CRR.

  160. Art. 429(14) CRR.

  161. According to Sabine Lautenschläger, Deputy President of the Deutsche Bundesbank and President’s Alternate in the Governing Council of the ECB, this setting of the leverage ratio rules ‘punishes low-risk business models, and it favours high-risk businesses, encouraging banks to engage in more risk-taking’. See Sabine Lautenschläger, The leverage ratio: a simple and comparable measure? Speech held at the evening reception of the Deutsche Bundesbank/SAFE Conference ‘Supervising Banks in Complex Financial Systems’, Frankfurt, 21 October 2013. See also German Banking Industry Committee, Comments on the leverage ratio in follow-up to the lcr-lr-hearing of the EU Commission on 10 March 2014. In the words of this report (p. 5): ‘[B]anks which have specialised in less risky business areas such as construction finance, commercial real estate or housing loans or mortgage bond business will be significantly disadvantaged’.

  162. Inter alia, Bershidsky L, ‘The incredible shrinking EU bank’, Bloomberg View, 2 April 2015, available at http://bv.ms/1anZTIp; Moshinsky B, ‘EU banks shrink assets by $1.1 trillion as capital ratios rise’, Bloomberg Business, 17 December 2013, available at http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-12-16/eu-banks-shrink-assets-by-1-1-trillion-as-capital-ratios-rise.

  163. For the decrease of lending volume following from an increase of CET 1, see the Macroeconomic Assessment Group (MAG) established by the BIS in 2010, which reported that an increase of 1 % in CET 1 in 4 years leads to a 1.4–1.5 % decrease of lending volume, with a following drop in the global real GDP of around 2 %. For details, see MAG (2010), at p. 5. See also Gavalas and Syriopoulos (2014).

  164. See Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2012), at p. 292. The authors found that before the crisis smaller European banks displayed a surprisingly stable level of asset growth and no hint of procyclical leverage.

  165. Borgioli et al. (2013), at pp. 17, 18.

  166. Idem.

  167. See KPMG (2013), at p. 2.

  168. See for examples in Germany and Italy, where a large fraction of the banking market consists of savings and cooperative banks: Henning H, ‘Consolidation wave likely for German banks’, Wall Street Journal, 4 April 2014, available at http://on.wsj.com/1safCT4; Sanderson R, ‘Merger season looms for Italy’s popolari’, Financial Times, 30 March 2015, available at http://on.ft.com/1FaYDT.

  169. On the issue, see Berger and Humphrey (1993).

  170. Bini Smaghi (2007). For a comparative evaluation of how small banks are currently reacting to the new provision of the Dodd-Frank Act in the US largely confirming these results, see Peirce et al. (2014).

  171. Idem.

  172. See Association of Sparda Banks e.V. (2013), at p. 5.

  173. See Bini Smaghi (2007).

  174. See Mersch (2015), according to whom ‘there are too many banks in Europe relative to the size of the market. This implies that there is significant scope to benefit from rationalisation, and without exacerbating the problem of “too big to fail”’.

  175. See Peirce et al. (2014), at pp. 49–52.

  176. As seen above (see supra nn. 167 and 168 and corresponding text), Germany and Italy can be taken as proxies of such a consolidation wave in Europe.

  177. For a critical evaluation of costs and benefits of banking mergers in the EU, see Hagendorff and Nieto (2015).

  178. Inter alia, European Association of Cooperative Banks, supra n. 130; Eurochambres, supra n. 136.

  179. Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), at p. 63.

  180. Masera (2013), at p. 396.

  181. Art. 501(2) CRR.

  182. See German Banking Industry Committee, Indicators for risk development of loans to small and medium-sized enterprises (SME), 2 March 2012, at p. 6. See also Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), at p. 63.

  183. Deutsche Bundesbank (2013), at p. 63.

  184. A further buffer with countercyclical effects is the systemic risk buffer laid down in Art. 137. However, since its rationale lies in preventing and mitigating long-term non-cyclical systemic or macroprudential risks not covered by the CRR, we do not consider it as a proper countercyclical tool. For this reason, this buffer is not treated in this paper.

  185. Art. 131(5) CRD IV.

  186. Art. 131(6) CRD IV.

  187. Art. 131(14) CRD IV.

  188. Indeed, this one-size approach has been contested by the Financial Policy Committee (FPC) established by the Financial Services Act 2012 as UK macroprudential authority. For details, cf. Tucker et al. (2013).

References

  • Acharya V, Merrouche O (2013) Precautionary hoarding of liquidity and interbank markets: evidence from the subprime crisis. Rev Finance 19:107–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aksoy Y, Basso HS (2015) Securitization and asset prices. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 5213

  • Allen & Overy (2014a) CRD IV framework: standardised approach to credit risk in the banking book. Client Briefing Paper 3, January

  • Allen & Overy (2014b) Capital Requirements Directive IV framework internal ratings-based approach to credit risk in the banking book. Client Briefing Paper 4, January

  • Andersen H (2011) Procyclical implications of Basel II: can the cyclicality of capital requirements be contained? J Financial Stab 7:138–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelkort A, Stuwe A (2011) Basel III and SME financing. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Mainz

    Google Scholar 

  • Association of Sparda Banks e.V. (2013) The regulatory framework: balancing risk sensitivity, simplicity and comparability. 10 October 2013

  • Avdjiev S, Kartasheva A, Bogdanova B (2013) CoCos: a primer. BIS Q Rev (2013):43–56

  • Baker M, Wurgler J (2015) Do strict capital requirements raise the cost of capital? Bank regulation, capital structure, and the low-risk anomaly. Am Econ Rev 105:315–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BCBS (2001) The internal ratings-based approach. Consultative Document, January 2001

  • BCBS (2010a) Countercyclical capital buffer proposal. Consultative Document, July 2010

  • BCBS (2010b) Results of the comprehensive quantitative impact study, December 2010

  • BCBS (2011) Basel III: a global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems—revised version, June 2011

  • BCBS (2013) Basel III: the liquidity coverage ratio and liquidity risk monitoring tools, January 2013

  • BCBS (2014a) Basel III leverage ratio framework and disclosure requirements, January 2014

  • BCBS (2014b) Basel III: the net stable funding ratio, October 2014

  • BCBS (2014c) Regulatory Consistency Assessment Programme (RCAP). Assessment of Basel III regulations—European Union, December 2014

  • Behn M, Haselmann RF, Vig V (2014) The limits of model-based regulation. SAFE Working Paper 75

  • Berger AN, Humphrey DB (1993) Bank scale economies, mergers, concentration, and efficiency: the U.S. experience. Revue d’économies financière 27:123–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Udell GF (2002) Small business credit availability and relationship lending: the importance of bank organizational structure. Econ J 112:F32–F53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Miller NH, Petersen MA, Rajan RG, Stein JC (2005) Does function follow organizational form? Evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks. J Financ Econ 76:237–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B, Gertler M, Gilchrist S (1996) The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. Rev Econ Stat 78:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS, Gertler M, Gilchrist S (1999) The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In: Taylor JB, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 1. Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam, pp. 1341–1393

    Google Scholar 

  • Berrospide J (2013) Bank liquidity hoarding and the financial crisis: an empirical evaluation. FED Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-3

  • Biljanovska B (2016) Aligning market discipline and financial stability: contingent convertible instruments and bail-ins. Eur Bus Organ Law Rev 16(4). doi:10.1007/s40804-016-0028-0

  • Bini Smaghi L (2007) Banking consolidation, innovation and access to credit. Speech held at CESIFIN, Florence, 11 December 2007

  • BIS (2009) The global financial crisis. 79th Annual Report

  • Blanchard OJ (2009) The crisis: basic mechanisms, and appropriate policies. MIT Department of Economics Working Paper 1

  • Blundell-Wignall A, Atkinson P (2010) Thinking beyond Basel III: necessary solutions for capital and liquidity. OECD J Financ Mark Trends 1:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell-Wignall A, Atkinson P, Lee SH (2008) The current financial crisis: causes and policy issues. OECD J Financ Mark Trends 2:11–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Borgioli S, Gouveia AC, Labanca C (2013) Financial stability analysis—insights gained from consolidated banking data for the EU. ECB Occasional Paper Series 140

  • Borio C (2003) Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation? BIS Working Paper 128

  • Borio C (2009) Implementing the macroprudential approach to financial regulation and supervision. Banque de France Financ Stab Rev 13:31–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio C, Shim I (2007) What can (macro-)prudential policy do to support monetary policy? BIS Working Paper 242

  • Borio C, Furfine C, Lowe P (2001) Procyclicality of the financial system and financial stability: issues and policy options. BIS Pap 1

  • Brei M, Gambacorta L (2014) The leverage ratio over the cycle. BIS Working Paper 471

  • Burroni M, Quagliariello M, Sabatini E, Tola V (2009) Dynamic provisioning: rationale, functioning, and prudential treatment. Banca d’Italia Occasional Paper 57

  • Calomiris CW (2009) Financial innovation, regulation and reform. Cato J 29:65–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Caruana J (2010) Basel III: towards a safer financial system. Speech at the 3rd Santander International Banking Conference, Madrid, 15 September 2010

  • Caruana J, Cohen BH (2014) Five questions and six answers about macroprudential policy. Banque de France Financ Stab Rev, Macroprudent Policies Implement Interact 18:15–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerutti E, Claessens S, Laeven L (2015) The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: new evidence. IMF Working Paper 61

  • CGFS (2010) The role of margin requirements and haircuts in procyclicality. CGFS Paper 36

  • Chan NT (2011) Excessive leverage—root cause of financial crisis. Speech at the Economic Summit 2012 ‘Roadmap to Hong Kong Success’. Hong Kong, 9 December 2011

  • Chorafas DN (2011) Basel III, the devil and global banking. Palgrave MacMillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Kodres L (2014) The regulatory responses to the global financial crisis: some uncomfortable questions. IMF Working Paper 46

  • Claessens S, Kose MA, Laeven L, Valencia F (2013) Understanding financial crises: causes, consequences, and policy responses. CAMA Working Paper 5

  • Cohen HB (2013) How have banks adjusted to higher capital requirements? BIS Q Rev (2013):25–41

  • Cohen HB, Scatigna M (2014) Banks and capital requirements: channels of adjustment. BIS Working Papers 443

  • Conference of State Bank Supervisors (2011) Community banks and capital. Assessing a community bank’s need and access to capital in the face of market and regulatory challenges. December 2011

  • Cornelis L (ed) (2015) Finance and law: twins in trouble. Intersentia, Mortsel, Belgium

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornett M, McNutt J, Strahan P, Tehranian H (2011) Liquidity risk management and credit supply in the financial crisis. J Financ Econ 101:297–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford C (2011) The repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act and the current financial crisis. J Bus Econ Res 9:127–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings JR, Durrani KJ (2014) Effect of the Basel Accord capital requirements on the loan-loss provisioning practices of Australian banks. CIFR Working Paper 26

  • D’Hulster K (2009) The leverage ratio. A new binding limit on banks. World Bank Crisis Response, Note 11

  • De Bandt O, Hartmann P (2000). Systemic risk: a survey. ECB Working Paper 35

  • Delli Gatti D, Gallegati M, Minsky H (1994) Financial institutions, economic policy, and the dynamic behavior of the economy. Jerome Levy Economics Institute Working Paper 126

  • Detken C, Weeken O, Alessi L, Bonfim D, Boucinha MM, Castro C et al (2014) Operationalising the countercyclical capital buffer: indicator selection, threshold identification and calibration options. ESRB Occasional Paper 5

  • Deutsche Bundesbank (2013) Implementing Basel III in European and national law. Monthly Report, June

  • Dierick F (2004) Procyclicality and dynamic provision. In: The new Basel Capital Accord and the future of the European financial system. CEPS Task Force Report 51

  • Drehmann M, Tsatsaronis K (2014) The credit-to-GDP gap and countercyclical capital buffers: questions and answers. BIS Q Rev (2014):55–73

  • Driesen DM (2014) Legal theory lessons from the financial crisis. J Corp Law 40:55–97

    Google Scholar 

  • EBA (2015) Future of the IRB approach. EBA Discussion Paper

  • Elizalde A (2007) From Basel I to Basel II: an analysis of the three pillars. CEMFI Working Paper 4

  • ESRB (2014) The ESRB handbook on operationalising macro-prudential policy in the banking sector, March 2014

  • European Commission (2013) Capital requirements—CRD IV/CRR—Frequently asked questions. Press Release, Memo 16 July

  • Friedman J (2010) What caused the financial crisis. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Frydman R, Goldberg MD (2007) Imperfect knowledge economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • FSB, BIS, IMF (2011) Macroprudential policy tools and frameworks—update to G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors, 14 February 2011

  • FSF, BCBS (2009) Reducing procyclicality arising from the bank capital framework. Joint FSF-BCBS Working Group on Bank Capital Issues, March 2009

  • Galati G, Moessner R (2011) Macroprudential policy—aliterature review. J Econ Surv 27:847–878

    Google Scholar 

  • Gale D, Yorulmazer T (2011) Liquidity hoarding. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 488

  • Gavalas D, Syriopoulos T (2014) Basel III and its effects on banking performance: investigating lending rates and loan quantity. J Finance Bank Manag 2:17–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerding EF (2013) Law, bubbles, and financial regulation (the economics of legal relationships). Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, London and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gohari B, Woody KE (2015) The new global financial regulatory order: can macroprudential regulation prevent another global financial disaster? J Corp Law 40:403–437

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart C, Segoviano MA (2004) Basel and procyclicality: a comparison of the standardised and IRB approaches to an improved credit risk method. Financial Markets Group, LSE Discussion Paper 524

  • Gordy M, Howells B (2006) Procyclicality in Basel II: can we treat the disease without killing the patient? J Financ Intermed 15:395–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton GB (2010) E-coli, repo madness, and the financial crisis. Bus Econ 45:164–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton GB, Metrick A (2010) Haircuts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, November/December, pp. 507–520

  • Gorton GB, Metrick A (2012) Securitized banking and the run on repo. J Financ Econ 104:425–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gros D, Alcidi C (2010) The impact of the financial crisis on the real economy. Intereconomics 45:4–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagendorff J, Nieto MJ (2015) The safety and soundness effects of bank M&A in the EU: does prudential regulation have any impact? Eur Financ Manag 21:462–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakenes H, Schnabel I (2006) Bank size and risk-taking under Basel II. SFB/TR 15 Discussion Paper 88

  • Hanson SG, Kashyap A, Stein JC (2011) A macroprudential approach to financial regulation. J Econ Perspect 25:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Härle P, Lüders E, Pepanides T, Pfetsch S, Poppensieker T, Stegemann U (2010) Basel III and European banking: its impact, how banks might respond, and the challenges of implementation. McKinsey Working Paper on Risk No. 26

  • Heid F (2007) The cyclical effects of the Basel II capital requirements. J Bank Finance 31:3885–3900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heider F, Hoerova M, Holthausen C (2009) Liquidity hoarding and interbank market spreads. The role of counterparty risk. ECB Working Paper Series 1126

  • Heremans D, Bosquet K (2011) The future of law and finance after the financial crisis: new perspectives on regulation and corporate governance for banks. Univ Ill Law Rev 2011:1551–1576

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2012) Global financial stability report. Restoring confidence and progressing on reforms. Washington, DC

  • Jiménez G, Ongena S, Peydró J-L, Saurina J (2012) Macroprudential policy, countercyclical bank capital buffers and credit supply: evidence from the Spanish dynamic provisioning experiments. European Banking Center Discussion Paper 2012-011

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Sorensen B, Yesiltas S (2012) Leverage across firms, banks, and countries. J Int Econ 88:284–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan CM (2013) The Legal Theory of Finance is a starting point. The CLS Blue Sky Blog. http://clsbluesky.law.columbia.edu/2013/07/23/the-legal-theory-of-finance-is-a-starting-point/

  • Kashyap AK, Stein JC (2004) Cyclical implications of the Basel II capital standards. Econ Perspect (1Q/2004):18–31

  • Kashyap AK, Stein JC, Hanson S (2010) An analysis of the impact of ‘substantially heightened’ capital requirements on large financial institutions. Harvard Business School Working Paper, May 2010

  • King J (2013) Hyman Minsky and the financial instability hypothesis. In: Harcourt GC, Kriesler P (eds) The Oxford handbook of post-Keynesian economics 1: theory and origins. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • KPMG (2013) Community Banking Industry Outlook Survey. https://www.kpmg.com/US/en/IssuesAndInsights/ArticlesPublications/Documents/community-banking-industry-outlook-survey-2013.pdf

  • Krishnamurti D, Lee YC (2014) Macroprudential policy framework. A practice guide. The World Bank, Washington

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laeven L, Ratnovski R, Tong H (2014) Bank size and systemic risk. IMF Staff Discussion Note 4

  • Lim C, Columba F, Costa A, Kongsamut P, Otani A, Saiyid M, Wezel T, Wu X (2011) Macroprudential policy: what instruments and how to use them? Lessons from country experiences. IMF Working Paper (238)

  • Lin JY, Treichel V (2012) The unexpected global financial crisis: researching its root cause. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5937

  • Lyngen N (2012) Basel III: dynamics of state implementation. Harvard Int Law J 53:519–535

    Google Scholar 

  • MAG (Macroeconomic Assessment Group) (2010) Assessing the macroeconomic impact of the transition to stronger capital and liquidity requirements. Final report

  • Masera R (2013) US Basel III Final Rule on banks’ capital requirements: a different-size-fits-all approach. PSL Q Rev 66:387–402

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera R (2014) CRR/CRD IV: the trees and the forest. PSL Q Rev 67:381–422

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonnell BH (2014) Designing countercyclical capital buffers. Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper Series No. 14–16

  • Mehrling P (2011) The new Lombard Street: how the Fed became the dealer of last resort. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Mersch Y (2015) The future of banking—a central banker’s view. Speech at the Economist Future of Banking Summit, Paris, 10 March 2015

  • Minsky HP (1986a) Stabilizing an unstable economy. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky HP (1986b) Stabilizing an unstable economy. Paper prepared for a Bank Credit Analyst Conference, New York. Hyman P. Minsky Archive, Paper 144

  • Minsky HP (1992) The financial instability hypothesis. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper 74

  • Minsky HP (1992b) The capital development of the economy and the structure of financial institutions. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper 72

  • Musch FC, Ayadi R, Nieto M, Schmit M (2008) Basel II implementation in the midst of turbulence. CEPS Task Force

  • Nier EW (2011) Macroprudential policy—taxonomy and challenges. Natl Inst Econ Rev 216:R1–R15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Sullivan V, Kinsella S (2011) Deleveraging in the eurozone. VOX CEPR’s Policy Portal, 17 December

  • Ollivaud P, Turner D (2014) The effect of the global financial crisis on OECD potential output. OECD Economics Department Working Paper 1166

  • Ötker-Robe I, Podpiera AM (2013) The social impact of financial crises. Evidence from the global financial crisis. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6703

  • Palley TI (2013) Financialization: the economics of finance capital domination. Palgrave Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Peirce H, Robinson IC, Stratmann T (2014) How are small banks faring under Dodd-Frank? GMU Working Paper in Economics 49

  • Pistor K (2012) On the theoretical foundations for regulating financial markets. Columbia Public Law Research Paper 12–304

  • Pistor K (2013) A Legal Theory of Finance. J Comp Econ 41:315–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner RA (2009) A failure of capitalism: the crisis of ‘08 and the descent into depression. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Repullo R, Saurina J (2011) The countercyclical capital buffer of Basel III: a critical assessment. CEPR Discussion Paper DP8304

  • Repullo R, Suarez J (2004) Loan pricing under Basel capital requirements. J Financ Intermed 13:496–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rime B (2003) The new Basel Accord: implications of the co-existence between the standardized approach and the internal ratings-based approach. Studienzentrum Gerzensee Working Paper 03.05

  • Rosengren E (2013) Bank capital: lessons from the U.S. financial crisis. Speech at the Bank for International Settlements Forum on Key Regulatory and Supervisory Issues in a Basel III World, Bank of Korea, Seoul, 25 February 2013

  • Schwarcz SL (2015) Regulating financial change: a functional approach. Minnesota Law Review 100 (forthcoming April 2016)

  • Sharma IA (2013) Rules, discretion, and macro-prudential policy. IMF Working Paper 65

  • Sinapi C (2011) Institutional prerequisites of financial fragility within Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis: a proposal in terms of ‘institutional fragility’. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper 674

  • Solomon D (2012) The rise of a giant: securitization and the global financial crisis. Am Bus Law J. doi:10.1111/j.1744-1714.2012.01143

    Google Scholar 

  • Strah S, Hynes J, Shaffer S (2013) The impact of the recent financial crisis on the capital positions of large U.S. financial institutions: an empirical analysis. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Report, July

  • Tagkalakis A (2013) The effects of financial crisis on fiscal positions. Eur J Polit Econ 29:197–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmermans K (2012) Balance sheet optimisation under Basel III. Slides presented at the ING Investor Day, 13 January 2012

  • Tucker P, Hall S, Pattani A (2013) Macroprudential policy at the Bank of England. Bank Engl Q Bull Q3:192–200

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I gratefully acknowledge research support from the Center of Excellence SAFE, funded by the State of Hessen initiative for research LOEWE.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Amorello.

Additional information

Luca Amorello: Doctoral Candidate.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Amorello, L. Europe Goes ‘Countercyclical’: A Legal Assessment of the New Countercyclical Dimension of the CRR/CRD IV Package. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 17, 137–171 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40804-016-0032-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40804-016-0032-4

Keywords

Navigation