Skip to main content
Log in

Arm your friends and save on defense? The impact of arms exports on military expenditures

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Is there a substitution effect between arms exports and military spending? Do arms producing countries use weapon deliveries as a means to affect their external security? Whereas free-riding in alliances is extensively discussed by researchers and practitioners, the literature has surprisingly neglected the effect of transfers in defense goods on domestic military budgets. We develop a formal theoretical framework that conditions a country’s budgeting calculus on its arms trade decisions. The general conclusion is that exports lead to domestic cuts in military spending—provided suppliers expect positive security externalities. We use an innovative measure for external security based on UN voting records and regime type to test our model predictions on data covering both the Cold War as well as the post-Cold War period. Our results strongly suggest that democratic and non-democratic countries behave very differently. We find a clear substitution effect only for arms transfers by democratic states to other aligned democracies during the post-Cold War years. No such effect can be found for the Cold War era. There is no evidence for a substitution effect in either period for non-democratic suppliers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We do not assume that arms are produced only by state-owned enterprises. However, given the sensitive nature of arms exports, governments always have the final decision power by granting export licenses. They, in effect, determine a country’s export levels and export destinations.

  2. A convex cost function also can be interpreted as capturing rising political or societal costs associated with arms production.

  3. From an algebraic point of view, the security externality specification herein ensures the existence of an optimum in the positive value range of \(x_{t}\) as well as \(q_{t}\).

  4. Note that this result holds true for \(e>0\) as well if \(\frac{e}{{\delta ^{2}}}<1+b\). However, the assumption simply implies that the effect of e is small enough to be outweighed by the negative quadratic elements of the objective function.

  5. Note that for sufficiently small values of e, i.e., \(e<b\delta ^{2}\), \(\bar{q}\) bears a positive sign as well. However, this assumption is even more restrictive than the one outlined in the previous footnote.

  6. Autocratic regimes in particular have been identified in the intrastate conflict literature as being prone to violent internal strife (see for instance Fearon and Laitin 2003).

  7. Following the discussion in Häge (2011) and Häge and Hug (2016), we use as our measure Cohen’s \(\kappa\) (Cohen 1960), which is calculated as \(\kappa =1-\frac{\sum (X-Y)^{2}}{\sum (X-\bar{X})^{2}+\sum (Y-\bar{Y})^{2}+\sum (\bar{X}-\bar{Y})^{2}}\), where X and Y contain the voting decisions of two countries.

  8. We followed the usual convention and chose +5 as the threshold on the Polity IV index.

  9. Detailed definitions and sources for all dependent and independent variables are provided in Appendix Table 6.

  10. Major conventional weapons include armored vehicles, ships, submarines and aircraft as well as their components, such as engines, sensors, satellites, and other defense systems. They do not include weapons of mass destruction (see http://www.sipri.org/databases/yy_armstransfers/background/coverage).

  11. TIVs are not meant to measure the financial value of an arms transfer but are based on the estimated production cost of a core weapon system. The intention is to measure the amount of military resources that are being transferred through the trading of arms.

  12. See the Norwegian Initiative on Small Arms Transfers (NISAT), which collects trade data on SALW (http://nisat.prio.org/Trade-Database).

  13. The top five exporting countries between 2012 and 2016 have been the United States, Russia, China, France and Germany (Fleurant et al. 2016: 2), with the US and Russia comprising a combined 56% of the global arms market.

  14. A list of these countries can be found in Appendix Table 7.

  15. Note that using different cutoff points leads to slight changes in significance levels.

  16. Scott’s \(\pi\) is calculated by \(\pi =1-\frac{\sum (X-Y)^{2}}{\sum (X-\frac{\bar{X}+\bar{Y}}{2})^{2}+\sum (Y-\frac{\bar{X}+\bar{Y}}{2})^{2}}\), where X and Y contain the UN voting decisions of two countries (Häge 2011).

References

  • Albalate, D., Bel, G., & Elias, F. (2012). Institutional determinants of military spending. Journal of Comparative Economics, 40, 279–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderton, C. H., & Carter, J. R. (2009). Principles of conflict economics. A primer for social scientists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial condititions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bove, V., & Brauner, J. (2016). The demand for military expenditure in authoritarian regimes. Defense and Peace Economics, 27(5), 609–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bove, V., Efthyvoulou, G., & Navas, A. (2017). Political cycles in public expenditure: Butter vs guns. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45(3), 582–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bove, V., & Nistico, R. (2014). Coups d’etat and defense spending: A counterfactual analysis. Public Choice, 161(3–4), 321–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brauer, J. (2002). Survey and review of the defense economics literature on Greece and Turkey: What have we learned? Defence and Peace Economics, 13(2), 85–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brauner, J. (2012). Military spending and democratisation. Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 18(3), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brito, D. L., & Intriligator, M. D. (1995). Arms races and proliferation. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics (Vol. 1). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G. S. (2005). Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters, 87(3), 361–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brzoska, M. (2004). The economics of arms imports after the end of the cold war. Defence and Peace Economics, 15(2), 111–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J. (1960). A coefficient of agreement for nominal scales. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 20, 37–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, H. (2017). Defense secretary mattis tells nato allies to spend more, or else. The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2017/02/15/world/europe/jim-mattis-nato-trump.html; posted 15-February-2017.

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984). Easy riders, joint production, and public goods. Economic Journal, 94(3), 580–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dudley, L., & Montmarquette, C. (1981). The demand for military expenditures: An international comparison. Public Choice, 37, 5–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., & Perlo-Freeman, S. (2003). The demand for military spending in developing countries: a dynamic panel analysis. Defence and Peace Economics, 14(6), 461–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, J. P., Perlo-Freeman, S., & Smith, R. P. (2008). The demand for military expenditure in developing countries: Hostility versus capability. Defence and Peace Economics, 19(4), 293–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, P. J., & Smith, R. P. (2007). The econometrics of military arms races. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics (Vol. 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurant, A., Wezeman, P. D., Wezeman, S. T., & Tian, N. (2016). Trends in international arms transfers, 2016. SIPRI Fact Sheet, February 2017.

  • Flores, A. Q. (2011). Alliances as contiguity in spatial models of military. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 28(4), 402–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fordham, B. O., & Walker, T. C. (2005). Kantian liberalism, regime type, and military resource allocation: Do democracies spend less? International Studies Quarterly, 49, 141–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia-Alonso, M. D., & Levine, P. (2007). Arms trade and arms races: A strategic analysis. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics (Vol. 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • George, J., & Sandler, T. (2017). Demand for military spending in NATO, 1968–2015: A spatial panel approach. European Journal of Political Economy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.09.002.

  • Gleditsch, K. S. (2002). Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 712–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, B. E. (2003). Bearing the defense burden, 1886–1989—Why spend more? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(5), 551–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Häge, F. M. (2011). Choice or circumstance? Adjusting measures of foreign policy similarity for chance agreement. Political Analysis, 19(3), 287–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Häge, F. M., & Hug, S. (2016). Consensus decisions and similarity measures in international organizations. International Interactions, 42(3), 503–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, L. Y., & Robbins, J. W. (2016). Military spending and electoral systems: A reconsideration. Armed Forces & Society, 42(1), 51–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2016). The growth in military expenditure in Germany 1951–2011: Did parties matter? Defence and Peace Economics, 27(4), 503–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lebovic, J. H. (1998). Consider the source: Organizational bias in estimates of foreign military spending. International Studies Quarterly, 42(1), 161–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leon, G. (2014). Loyalty for sale? Military spending and coups detat. Public Choice, 8(3–4), 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, P., Sen, S., & Smith, R. (1994). A model of the international arms market. Defence and Peace Economics, 5(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, P., Sen, S., & Smith, R. (1995). The arms trade and arms control. The Economic Journal, 105(429), 471–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, P., Sen, S., & Smith, R. (2000). Arms export controls and proliferation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(6), 885–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. (2014). Major episodes of political violence (MEPV) and conflict regions 1946–2013. http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/MEPVcodebook2013.pdf. Accessed February 10, 2015.

  • Marshall, M., Gurr, T., & Jaggers, K. (2014). Polity IV project. http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2013.pdf. Accessed February 10, 2015.

  • Murdoch, J. C. (1995). Military alliances: Theory and empirics. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics (Vol. 1). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (1984). Complementarity, free riding, and the military expenditure of Nato allies. Journal of Public Economics, 25(1–2), 83–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49, 1417–1426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W., Oneal, J. R., & Russett, B. (2012). The effects of the international security environment on national military expenditures: A multicountry study. International Organization, 66(3), 491–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordlinger, E. (1977). Soldiers in politics: Military coups and governments. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Öcal, N. (2003). Are the military expenditures of India and Pakistan external determinants for each other: An empirical investigation. Defence and Peace Economics, 14(2), 141–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M., & Zeckhauser, R. (1966). An economic theory of alliances. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48(3), 266–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pamp, O., & Thurner, P. W. (2017). Trading arms and the demand for military expenditures: Empirical explorations using new SIPRI-data. Defense and Peace Economics, 28(4), 457–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plümper, T., & Neumeyer, E. (2015). Free-riding in alliances: Testing an old theory with a new method. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 32(3), 247–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, L. F. (1960). Arms and insecurity. A mathematical study of the causes and origins of war. Pittsburgh, PA: Boxwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1977). Impurity of defense: An application to the economics of alliances. Kyklos, 30, 443–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T., & Hartley, K. (1995). The economics of defense. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T., & Hartley, K. (2001). Economics of alliances: The lessons of collective action. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(3), 869–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. A. (1955). Reliability of content analysis: The case of nominal scale coding. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 19(3), 321–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shear, M. D. & Steinhauer, J. (2017). Trump to seek \$54 billion increase in military spending. The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2017/02/27/us/politics/trump-budget-military.html; posted 27-February-2017.

  • Signorino, C. S., & Ritter, J. M. (1999). Tau-b or not tau-b: Measuring the similarity of foreign policy positions. International Studies Quarterly, 43(1), 115–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. P. (1980). The demand for military expenditure. The Economic Journal, 90(360), 811–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. P. (1995). The demand for military expenditure. In T. Sandler & K. Hartley (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics (Vol. 1). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. P., Sola, M., & Spagnolo, F. (2000). The prisoner’s dilemma and regime-switching in the greek-turkish arms race. Journal of Peace Research, 37(6), 737–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, G. H. (1997). Alliance politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Töngür, U. & Hsu, S. (2013). Military expenditures and political regimes: An analysis using global data, 1963–2001. ERC Working Papers in Economics, 13/07.

  • Voeten, E. (2013). Data and analyses of voting in the UN general assembly. In B. Reinalda (Ed.), Routledge handbook of international organization. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wezeman, P. D., Fleurant, A., Kuimova, A., Tian, N., & Wezeman, S. T. (2018). Trends in international arms transfers, 2017. SIPRI Fact Sheet, March 2018.

Download references

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 2017 annual MPSA meeting. We would like to thank David Rowe, Han Dorussen, an anonymous referee and the editors for their very helpful comments. Special thanks go to SIPRI, and in particular to Aude Fleurant, Siemon Wezeman and Pieter Wezeman. Finally, we are very grateful to Andreas Mehltretter for his valuable research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Oliver Pamp.

Appendices

Appendix 1: A Derivations of results

1.1 A.1

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \mathcal{L} = \mathop \sum \limits _{t = 0}^{t = \infty } {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {S_t^x + dS_t^q + e(S_t^q)^2 + \left( {a - b{q_t}} \right) {q_t} - c\left( {{x_t} + \;{q_t}} \right) ^2} \right] \\ + {\mu _{1,t}}\left( {\left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^q + {q_t} - S_t^q} \right) + {\mu _{2,t}}\left( {\left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^x + {x_t} - S_t^x} \right) \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

1.2 A.2

  1. (1)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {x_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ { - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{2,t}} = 0\)

  2. (2)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {q_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {a - 2b{q_t} - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{1,t}} = 0\)

  3. (3)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial S_t^q}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {d + 2eS_t^q} \right] - {\mu _{1,t}} + {\mu _{1,t + 1}}\left( {1 - \delta } \right) = 0\)

  4. (4)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial S_t^x}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ 1 \right] - {\mu _{2,t}} + {\mu _{2,t + 1}}\left( {1 - \delta } \right) = 0\)

  5. (5)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial \mu _1^t}} = \left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^q + {q_t} - S_t^q = 0\)

  6. (6)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial \mu _2^t}} = \left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^x + {x_t} - S_t^x = 0\)

1.3 A.3

Rewrite the \(S_t^x\) and \(S_t^q\) as functions of \(x_0,\ldots ,x_t\) and \(q_0,\ldots ,q_t\) respectively, such that

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal{L}} & = \sum\limits_{{t = 0}}^{{t = \infty }} {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} } \left[ {S_{t}^{x} (x_{0} , \ldots ,x_{t} ) + dS_{t}^{q} \left( {q_{0} , \ldots ,q_{t} } \right) + eS_{t}^{q} \left( {q_{0} , \ldots ,q_{t} } \right)^{2} + \left( {a - bq_{t} } \right)q_{t} - c\left( {x_{t} + q_{t} } \right)^{2} } \right] \\ & \quad + \mu _{{1,t}} \left( {\left( {1 - \delta } \right)S_{{t - 1}}^{q} \left( {q_{0} , \ldots ,q_{{t - 1}} } \right) + q_{t} - S_{t}^{q} \left( {q_{0} , \ldots ,q_{t} } \right)} \right) \\ & \quad + \mu _{{2,t}} \left( {\left( {1 - \delta } \right)S_{{t - 1}}^{x} (x_{0} , \ldots ,x_{{t - 1}} ) + x_{t} - S_{t}^{x} (x_{0} , \ldots ,x_{t} )} \right) \\ \end{aligned}$$

The first-order conditions then read

  1. (1)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {x_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {\frac{{\partial S_t^x}}{{\partial {x_t}}} - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{2,t}}\left( {1 - \frac{{\partial S_t^x}}{{\partial {x_t}}}} \right) = 0\)

  2. (2)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {q_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {a - 2b{q_t} + d\frac{{\partial S_t^q}}{{\partial {q_t}}} + 2eS_t^q\frac{{\partial S_t^q}}{{\partial {q_t}}} - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{1,t}}\left( {1 - \frac{{\partial S_t^q}}{{\partial {q_t}}}} \right) = 0\)

As \(\frac{{\partial S_t^x}}{{\partial {x_t}}}\) and \(\frac{{\partial S_t^q}}{{\partial {q_t}}}\) equal the infinite sequence \(1 + \left( {1 - \delta } \right) + {\left( {1 - \delta } \right) ^2} \ldots = \frac{1}{\delta }\), the first order conditions can be reformulated as

  1. (1)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {x_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {\frac{1}{\delta } - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{2,t}}\left( {1 - \frac{1}{\delta }} \right) = 0\)

  2. (2)

    \(\frac{{\partial \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {q_t}}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ {a - 2b{q_t} + \frac{d}{\delta } + \frac{{2e}}{\delta }S_t^q - 2c\left( {{x_t} + {q_t}} \right) } \right] + {\mu _{1,t}}\left( {1 - \frac{1}{\delta }} \right) = 0\)

The second-order (cross) derivatives then read

  1. (1)

    \(\frac{{\partial ^2 \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {x_t}^2}} = - 2c{\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t} < 0\)

  2. (2)

    \(\frac{{\partial ^2 \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {q_t}^2}} = {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\left[ { - 2b + \frac{{2e}}{{\delta ^2 }} - 2c} \right] < 0\)

  3. (3)

    \(\frac{{\partial ^2 \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {q_t}\partial {x_t}}} = \frac{{\partial ^2 \mathcal{L}}}{{\partial {x_t}\partial {q_t}}} = - 2c{\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t} < 0\)

Computing the Hessian matrix yields

\(\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - 2c\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} } & { - 2c\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} } \\ { - 2c\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} } & {\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} \left[ { - 2b + \frac{{2e}}{{\delta ^{2} }} - 2c} \right]} \\ \end{array} } \right)\)

The determinant of the first principal minor \({D_1} = - 2c{\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^t}\;\) is negative. The determinant of the second principal minor \({D_2} = - 2c{\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) ^{2t}}\left[ { - 2b + \frac{{2e}}{\delta } - 2c + 2c} \right]\) is positive, if \(e<0\). We conclude that the Hessian matrix is negative definite, which constitutes a sufficient condition for an interior maximum at values of \(x_t\) and \(q_t\) satisfying the first-order conditions.

1.4 A.4

\(\max _{{\left\{ {x_{t} } \right\},\left\{ {q_{t} } \right\}}} W = \mathop \sum \limits_{{t = 0}}^{{t = \infty }} \left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} \left[ {S_{t}^{x} + dS_{t}^{q} + e(S_{t}^{q} )} \right]\;{\text{s.t.}}\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {M_{{t - 1}} + \left( {a - bq_{t} } \right)q_{t} - c\left( {x_{t} + q_{t} } \right)^{2} = M_{t} } \hfill \\ {\mathop {\lim }\limits_{{T \to \infty }} \mu _{1}^{T} M_{T} = 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.\) with \(S_t^q = \left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^q + {q_t}\) and \(S_t^x = \left( {1 - \delta } \right) S_{t - 1}^x + {x_t}\) and \(M_t\) denoting the monetary transfer between period t and \(t+1\).

1.5 A.5

Computing the Hessian matrix yields

$$\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - 2b - 2c} & { - 2c} \\ { - 2c} & { - 2c} \\ \end{array} } \right)$$

The determinant of the first principal minor \(D_1=-2b-2c\) is negative.

The determinant of the second principal minor \(D_2=(-2c)(-2c)\) is positive.

As the Hessian matrix is negative definite, the sufficient condition for the concavity of the function is fulfilled.

1.6 A.6

After setting \(q_t=\bar{q},x_t=\bar{x},S_t^x=\bar{S^x}, S_t^q=\bar{S^q},\mu _{1,t}=\bar{\mu }_1\) and \(\mu _{2,t}=\bar{\mu }_2 \forall t\), rearrange (3) from “Appendix A.2”, such that

$$\frac{1}{\delta }\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right)^{t} \left[ {d + 2e\overline{{S^{q} }} } \right] = \bar{\mu }_{1}$$

Substituting for \(\bar{\mu }_1\) in (2) yields

$$a - 2b\bar{q} - 2c\left( {\bar{x} + \bar{q}} \right) = - \frac{{d + 2e\overline{{S^{q} }} }}{\delta }$$

Rearranging (5), such that \(\overline{{S^q}} = \frac{{\bar{q}}}{\delta }\), combining the resulting expression with (7) and solving for \(\bar{x}\) yields

$$\bar{x} = \frac{{a\delta + d}}{{2c\delta }} - \left( {c + b - \frac{e}{{\delta ^{2} }}} \right)\frac{{\bar{q}}}{c}$$

1.7 A.7

Rearranging (4) from “Appendix A.2”, such that \(\frac{{{{\left( {\frac{1}{{1 + r}}} \right) }^t}}}{\delta } = {\bar{\mu }_2}\), combining with (1) and subsequently solving for \(\bar{x}\) yields

$$\bar{x} = \frac{1}{{2c\delta }} - \bar{q}$$

Equating this result with the result from “Appendix A.6” and subsequently solving for \(\bar{q}\) yields

$$\bar{q} = \delta \frac{{1 - d - a\delta }}{{2\left( {e - b\delta ^{2} } \right)}} > 0\;{\text{if}}\;b\delta ^{2} > e\;{\text{and}}\;a\delta + d > 1$$

1.8 A.8

$$\frac{{\partial \bar{q}}}{{\partial d}} = - \frac{\delta }{{2\left( {e - b\delta ^{2} } \right)}} > 0\;{\text{ if}}\;{\text{ }}b\delta ^{2} > e$$

1.9 A.9

$$\frac{{\partial \bar{q}}}{{\partial e}} = - \delta \frac{{1 - d - a\delta }}{{2\left( {e - b\delta ^{2} } \right)^{2} }} > 0\;{\text{ if}}\;{\text{ }}a\delta + d > 1$$

Appendix 2: B Variables and data

See Tables 6 and 7.

Table 6 Description of variables
Table 7 Countries

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pamp, O., Dendorfer, F. & Thurner, P.W. Arm your friends and save on defense? The impact of arms exports on military expenditures. Public Choice 177, 165–187 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0598-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0598-1

Keywords

Navigation