Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-jr42d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T06:06:52.246Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The choice of the social discount rate and the opportunity cost of public funds

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 January 2015

Mark A. Moore*
Affiliation:
Simon Fraser University, Beedie School of Business, 500 Granville Street, Vancouver, British Columbia V6C 1W6, Canada
Anthony E. Boardman
Affiliation:
University of British Columbia, 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver V6T 1Z2, Canada
Aidan R. Vining
Affiliation:
Simon Fraser University, Beedie School of Business, 500 Granville Street, Vancouver, British Columbia V6C 1W6, Canada
*
Mark A. Moore, Simon Fraser University, Beedie School of Business, 500 Granville Street, Vancouver, British Columbia V6C 1W6, Canada, Tel.: +778-782-7715, e-mail: markm@sfu.ca
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

The decades-old literature on the correct method for choosing and estimating a social discount rate (SDR) has resulted in two, largely opposing viewpoints. This note seeks to clarify the key sources of disagreement between these two camps. One view advocates that the choice should be based chiefly on the social opportunity cost of the return to foregone private capital investment (SOC), and suggests a SDR of around 7%. The other viewpoint, expressed by the authors, argues that the choice should be based on the social rate of time preference (STP), the rate at which society is willing to trade present for future consumption, suggesting a SDR of around 3.5%. Because of the fundamentally normative basis of the SDR choice, neither approach generates testable hypotheses that would allow falsification. For government project evaluation, the choice ultimately depends on the opportunity cost of public funds, which in turn depends on how fiscal policy actually operates. The STP approach contends that governments set targets for deficits and public debt, so that a marginal government project will be tax-financed, largely crowding out current consumption. The SOC belief is that governments set revenue targets, so that any government project will be deficit-financed on the margin, which will largely crowd out private investment. The authors also argue that a SDR based on the STP approach is appropriate for: benefit-cost analysis of government regulations, self-financing government projects, and government cost-effectiveness studies.

Type
Comments
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2013

References

Arrow, K. J. (1995). Intergenerational equity and the rate of discount in long-term social investment. Paper presented at the IEA World Congress. Retrived from http:www-econ.stanford.edu/faculty/workp/swp97005.pdf. Accessed on 11 February 2008.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., & Lind, R. C. (1970). Uncertainty and the evaluation of public investment decisions. American Economic Review, 60(2), 364378.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 10951117.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. (1987). Ricardian equivalence: an evaluation of theory and evidence. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 2330.Google Scholar
Boardman, A. E., Moore, M. A., & Vining, A. R. (2010). The social discount rate for canada based on future growth in consumption. Canadian Public Policy, 36(3), 323341.Google Scholar
Bradford, D. F. (1975). Constraints on government investment opportunities and the choice of discount rate. American Economic Review, 65(5), 887899.Google Scholar
Burgess, D. F. (2010). Toward a reconciliation of alternative views on the social discount rate. In Burgess, D. F. & Jenkins, G. P. (Eds.), Discount Rates for the Evaluation of Public Private Partnerships. Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press.Google Scholar
Burgess, D. F. (2013). Reconciling alternative views about the appropriate social discount rate. Journal of Public Economics, 97(1), 917.Google Scholar
Burgess, D. F. and Zerbe, R. O. (2013). The most appropriate discount rate. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis. DOI: 10.1515/jbca-2013-0016.Google Scholar
Burgess, D. F., & Zerbe, R. O. (2011). Appropriate discounting for benefit-cost analysis. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2(2). DOI: 10.2202/2152-2812.1065.Google Scholar
Chinn, M. (2012). Fiscal Multipliers. Forthcoming in: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Available at http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/~mchinn/Fiscal%20Multipliers.pdf. Accessed on 14 July 2013.Google Scholar
Cropper, M. L. (2012). How should benefits and costs be discounted in an intergenerational context? Resources for the Future Discussion Paper, 1242.Google Scholar
Evans, D. J. (2005). The elasticity of marginal utility of consumption: estimates for 20 OECD countries. Fiscal Studies, 26(2), 197224.Google Scholar
Lind, R. C. (Ed.). (1982). Discounting for Time and Risk in Energy Policy. Baltimore and Washington, DC: Johns Hopkins University Press and Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Lind, R. C. 1990. Reassessing the government′s discount rate policy in light of new theory and data in a world economy with a high degree of capital mobility. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18(2), Part 2, S8S28.Google Scholar
Moore, M. A., Boardman, A. E., & Vining, A. R. (2013). More appropriate discounting: the rate of social time preference and the value of the social discount rate. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 4(1), 116.Google Scholar
Moore, M. A., Boardman, A. E., Vining, A. R., Weimer, D. W., & Greenberg, D. H. (2004). ′Just give me a number!′: Practical values for the social discount rate. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 23(4), 789812.Google Scholar
OECD. (2010). OECD statextracts: taxing wages. Available at http://www.stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx. Accessed on 21 July 2011.Google Scholar
Office of Management and Budget (OMB). (1992). Circular A-94, Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs, 57 Fed. Regultion at 53,520 (November 10, 1992).Google Scholar
OMB. (2003). Circular A-4, 33-34 (September, 2003). Available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/inforeg/regpol.html. Accessed on 6 June 2005.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38(151), 543559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seater, J. J. (1993). Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Economic Literature, 31(1), 142190.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. (2005). Irrational Exuberance (2nd ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Data available at http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/data/chapt26.xls. Accessed on 30 June 2011.Google Scholar