Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Agent-Based Mapping of Credit Risk for Sustainable Microfinance

  • Joung-Hun Lee,

    Affiliation Faculty of Sciences, Kyushu University, Fukuoka, Japan

  • Marko Jusup ,

    mjusup@gmail.com

    Affiliation Faculty of Sciences, Kyushu University, Fukuoka, Japan

  • Boris Podobnik,

    Affiliations Faculty of Civil Engineering, University of Rijeka, Rijeka, Croatia, Faculty of Economics, University of Ljubljana, Ljubljana, Slovenia, Zagreb School of Economics and Management, Zagreb, Croatia

  • Yoh Iwasa

    Affiliation Faculty of Sciences, Kyushu University, Fukuoka, Japan

Abstract

By drawing analogies with independent research areas, we propose an unorthodox framework for mapping microfinance credit risk---a major obstacle to the sustainability of lenders outreaching to the poor. Specifically, using the elements of network theory, we constructed an agent-based model that obeys the stylized rules of microfinance industry. We found that in a deteriorating economic environment confounded with adverse selection, a form of latent moral hazard may cause a regime shift from a high to a low loan payment probability. An after-the-fact recovery, when possible, required the economic environment to improve beyond that which led to the shift in the first place. These findings suggest a small set of measurable quantities for mapping microfinance credit risk and, consequently, for balancing the requirements to reasonably price loans and to operate on a fully self-financed basis. We illustrate how the proposed mapping works using a 10-year monthly data set from one of the best-known microfinance representatives, Grameen Bank in Bangladesh. Finally, we discuss an entirely new perspective for managing microfinance credit risk based on enticing spontaneous cooperation by building social capital.

Introduction

Contradictory evidence of the impact of microfinance [14] has simultaneously been the root of high praise and harsh criticism. Proponents argue that the benefit from the access to credit makes microfinance an effective tool for improving the welfare of the poor [5]. Conversely, opponents accuse microfinance institutions (MFIs) of creating even more poverty [6], while some have gone so far as to claim that MFIs may harbor private groups with vested interest in perpetuating the current situation in many poor regions of the world [7]. Both sides, despite ideological differences, have devoted a great deal of debate to the sustainability of microfinance, particularly the reduction of information asymmetries [1, 810] and the non-profit versus for-profit dilemma [1, 4, 811].

If an MFI is to operate sustainably, the need to balance reasonable pricing of loans (the social mission) with self-financing through profits (the financial objective) appears to be of utmost importance [9, 12]. Achieving the desired balance rests on the successful control of credit risk, which is a task complicated by the fact that MFIs often serve a network of borrowers without credit histories. To address the issues involved, we build upon a recent argument that by drawing analogies with independent research areas it is possible to unravel the complexities of financial risks [1317]. Specifically, we treated the network of borrowers served by an MFI as a dynamical network, a versatile concept that has proven relevant in studies of many real-world phenomena, including finance [1824]. The dynamical network was set up to obey the stylized rules of microfinance, where the operations of one of the best established representatives of the industry, Grameen Bank in Bangladesh [1], constituted a working template.

Microfinance in a nutshell

The distinctive idea of microfinance is outreach to the poor. Every loan manager, accordingly, has the task to recruit customers by visiting their villages and subsequently to organize management units, where each unit covers several villages located near one another. A few units make up a branch under a single manager (i.e. a loan officer in a more traditional context). The importance of such a setup arises from the limited mobility of the potential customers who usually reside away from dense city centers, lack access to credit facilities, and occasionally fall prey to loan sharks.

Another key idea behind microfinance is that the intended purpose for the loans is not consumption. Instead, borrowers are supposed to invest into small businesses that can help boost their income. Each borrower is thus expected to justify the loan with a rudimentary business plan. The potential customers typically earn low incomes, less than $5 US per person or about $2 to $30 US per household daily. A representative loan amount is around $100 US, to be repaid in weekly installments over a period of 52 weeks (one year) with a 20% nominal interest rate [1]. To overcome the above-mentioned mobility problem, the manager visits each unit once a week to collect the installments.

Given that MFIs cannot rely on elaborate credit history calculations, it was necessary to establish microfinance-specific mechanisms for securing the regular payment of installments. Originally, six customers constituted a group, chose a leader from among themselves, and shared liability for loans to the individual members. Because of the shared liability, individual members were subject to peer monitoring and pressure, further reinforced by loan access for other group members being restricted in the case of a default (dynamic incentive). Currently, borrowing implies only individual liability, yet the group structure still exists, presumably to retain some of the benefits of group lending [1, 8, 9, 25]. Furthermore, all borrowers belonging to a unit (i.e. about 10 groups) are supposed to attend the weekly meeting with the manager and pay their installments publicly.

Other aspects of microfinance intended to encourage borrowers to comply include compulsory savings, dividends, and access to higher loans subject to an exemplary past performance. When borrowers open an account with the bank, they are supposed to save a certain percentage of the loan amount. Although access to these savings is limited, the borrower does obtain certain shareholder rights and is entitled to a dividend. Moreover, borrowers are motivated to stick to the payment schedule because an exemplary performance qualifies them for a progressively higher loan amount in the future. For successful MFIs such as Grameen bank, these mechanisms are sufficient to ensure a payment probability of around 95% [1, 12].

Overview of the modeling framework

Several assumptions, motivated by Grameen’s operations, regulate the network dynamics. First, borrowers are represented as agents (i.e. equal-sized nodes of the network) that can be in an active (paying installments) or an inactive (defaulted) state. The total fraction of active agents, f, indicates the overall state of the network. Second, agents can switch from an active to an inactive state with the probability pint to account for the possibility that some borrowers may default due to owning unsuccessful small enterprises. These events are called intrinsic failures. Third, agents are connected (i.e. posses information on each other’s state) in the sense of network theory because MFIs entice peer monitoring [1, 8, 9, 25] by forming groups of borrowers. Several groups make a unit whose members meet weekly with a loan manager to pay their installments publicly. One manager controls a branch comprised of multiple units from within a geographically limited area. The size of the network is determined by the number of managers employed by a particular MFI. To account for such a structure, we set up a hierarchical network (Fig 1) in a way that n1 < n2 < n3 < n4 agents corresponding to a group, a unit, a branch, and the whole MFI, respectively, are connected with the probabilities q1 > q2 > q3 > q4, respectively. Agents connected to each other are referred to as neighbors. Fourth, if a certain critical fraction of neighbors, th, turns inactive, an agent is tempted—with the small probability pext—to purposely do the same [22, 23, 26]. Such an extrinsic failure accounts for the latent moral hazard of strategic default when borrowers become wary of the willingness of other borrowers to continue honoring their loan agreements [6, 27, 28]. The last, fifth assumption of the network dynamics is that the inactive agents in the network, irrespective of whether they failed intrinsically or extrinsically, recover after a time τ because unsuccessful borrowers may have their payments rescheduled or may be issued new loans to jump-start their businesses. The recovery time has two components, τ = τ0 + Δτ, where τ0 is a certain minimum time needed for loan managers to address the problems of borrowers in default and Δτ is an exponentially distributed random variable [23] with the standard deviation σ, measuring the diverse abilities of the managers. A complete description of the model can be found in the Methods section, including the derivation of a deterministic analogue. For reference, a summary of mathematical symbols is given in Table 1. In what follows, our main interest is in applying the introduced dynamical network to identify the effect of the key parameters (th, pext, τ0, and σ) on the fraction of active agents (f) given the outside forcing (pint).

thumbnail
Fig 1. Visualization of the network structure.

Blue dots represent agents. Black, orange, and red lines represent the connections within groups, units, and branches, respectively, whereas the gray lines represent the connections across branches. The parameter values are n1 = 6, n2 = 60, n3 = 420, and n4 = 2100, with the connectedness probabilities q1 = 1, q2 = 0.05, q3 = 0.001, and q4 = 10−4. Five distinct branches are recognizable at a glance, while a closer inspection reveals seven units per branch. Individual groups are more difficult to distinguish. For clarity, the displayed network is much smaller than the ones used in simulations.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g001

thumbnail
Table 1. List of mathematical symbols in alphabetical order.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.t001

Results

To sustainably provide loans to borrowers not served by the traditional financial system, MFIs are critically dependent on a high loan payment probability, itself largely driven by the economic environment in which a given MFI operates. We therefore examined the performance of the network of borrowers within a deteriorating economic environment by using the described dynamical framework (Fig 2). For fixed values of th, pext, τ0, and σ, the results showed that the performance as measured by the fraction of active agents (f) responds linearly to the probability of intrinsic failure (pint) up to a certain point. When the value of pint increases sufficiently, the high rate of intrinsic failures drives the fraction of inactive neighbors of some agents close to the critical value, th, causing extrinsic failures to occur for the first time. The dynamical network thereafter undergoes a regime shift evident from a highly nonlinear decline in f (Fig 2). Additionally, the recovery of the network can be delayed, meaning that pint must be lower than the value that caused the downward regime shift before the fraction of active agents undergoes the reverse shift. In some cases, recovery is altogether absent. To understand these patterns better, we proceeded with a systematic analysis of the dynamics.

thumbnail
Fig 2. Time evolution of the dynamical network in a stylized economic downturn.

The probability of intrinsic failure, pint, steadily increases (decreases) throughout the first (second) half of the simulation at a rate 3.854 × 10−6 per time-step, symbolizing a deteriorating (recovering) economic environment. The network is seen switching between regimes with high and low fractions of active agents, f. Depending on the probability of extrinsic failure, pext, the network performance may lag behind that of the economy (red curve) or it may never return to the high-f regime (blue curve). Other parameter values are th = 0.2, τ0 = 7, and σ = 30. In all simulations, n1 = 6, n2 = 60, n3 = 420, with the total number of agents set to n4 ≈ 104 for computational reasons. The connectedness probabilities are q1 = 1, q2 = 0.7, and q3 = 0.05, and q4 is constrained so that the total average number of connections is 100 [31]. The scale for pint is reversed and magnified 32 times for easier visual comparison.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g002

We began the analysis by observing how the fraction of active agents changes with time when the probability of intrinsic failure, pint, is kept constant (Fig 3a). Several important aspects of the dynamical network are revealed this way. The performance as measured by the fraction of active agents, f, converges to an equilibrium, f*. There are two types of equilibria, one with a high and one with a low fraction of active agents, denoted f+* and f*, respectively. Convergence to a high-f or a low-f equilibrium depends on the value of pint and, somewhat surprisingly, on the initial state, in which all inactive agents are assumed to have failed intrinsically and have had their recovery time drawn from the exponential distribution with the parameter σ. The dependence on the initial state is exemplified by the two dashed curves in Fig 3a, which, although generated with the same value of pint, converge to equilibria of different types. Before turning to the implications of these outcomes, we first explore the origin of the two types of equilibria.

thumbnail
Fig 3. Two types of equilibria and the regime shift.

(a) The performance of the dynamical network as measured by f converges either to a high-f or a low-f equilibrium, depending on the probability of intrinsic failure, pint, and the initial state. The parameter pint ranges from 0.001 (triangles) to 0.005 (stars) in increments of 0.001. The dependence on the initial state is exemplified by the dashed curves, which converge to different equilibria although both were generated with the same pint. (b) The equilibrium states (f*) of the dynamical network form a hysteresis loop. Numerical results (black) compare favorably with the analytically derived high-f and low-f equilibria (red and blue curves, respectively; see Eq (1) and its limits in the text). A major consequence of hysteresis is that the recovery of the network lags that of the economy because the probability of intrinsic failure, pint, causing a shift from a high-f to a low-f regime is larger than the corresponding probability permitting the opposite regime shift. Parameter values are th = 0.2, pext = 0.009, τ0 = 7, and σ = 30.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g003

In the equilibrium state, by definition, rates at which agents fail and recover are the same. As long as the overall equilibrium fraction of active agents in the network, f*, is sufficiently high, the majority of agents will be aware of a fraction of inactive neighbors below the critical value th. In this case, all failures are intrinsic and the equilibrium failure rate is simply f* pint. Worsening performance of the network complicates matters because it increases the probability (denoted E) of having a critically inactive neighborhood, i.e. the probability that a randomly chosen agent has a fraction of inactive neighbors higher than th. Therefore, in addition to intrinsic failures, the remaining active agents in the equilibrium state, f*(1 − pint), can fail extrinsically, increasing the total failure rate by f*(1 − pint)Epext. The recovery rate is determined by the reciprocal of the average time to recovery, τ¯=τ0+σ, and the fraction of inactive agents, 1 − f*, producing the term (1f*)/τ¯. By balancing failure and recovery rates, and solving for f*, we get (1) From this equation, in the limits E → 0 and E → 1, we obtain high-f (f+*) and low-f (f*) equilibria, respectively. When the conditions pintτ¯1 and Epextτ¯1 are satisfied, a series expansion of Eq (1) yields f*1(pint+EpextEpintpext)τ¯, which is the result reported by Ref. [22] after assuming independent intrinsic and extrinsic failures. This mean-field approximation works much better for regular, as opposed to Erdős-Rényi, networks [22], and the larger the system the more appropriate it becomes. The other terms in the series (not shown) originate from the fact that intrinsic and extrinsic failures in our model are dependent. The insight gained from Eq (1) and its limits puts us in a better position to understand the implications of the previously described outcomes, but before discussing these implications, we first present an additional visual aid.

The visual aid in question (Fig 3b) is a plot that shows how the equilibrium state (f*) depends on the probability of intrinsic failure (pint). The most prominent feature of the plot is that the equilibrium states of the dynamical network form a hysteresis loop. Namely, the critical value of pint causing the shift from a high-f to a low-f equilibrium is larger than the corresponding critical value at which the opposite shift is possible. An immediate consequence is that the convergence depends on the initial state, as demonstrated in Fig 3a, or, more generally, on the path traversed by the fraction of active agents over time. Another consequence is the delayed recovery illustrated in Fig 2. In fact, when the parameter values are such that the returning branch of the hysteresis loop (dashed curve in Fig 3b) gets pushed beyond the range of possible forcings (i.e. below pint = 0, which is accomplished, for instance, by increasing pext), a recovery is no longer observed. We next argue that important insights into microfinance credit risk management follow from these results and extensions thereof, shown in the form of the phase diagrams.

When estimating risk, it is crucial to find out how far the parameters of a given dynamical system are from the regions of the parameter space characterized by high instability. We therefore use phase diagrams to present a comprehensive overview of the dynamics as a function of the parameter values. These diagrams are referred to as risk maps because of the assumed link between the dynamics and credit risk. For a given value of the probability of intrinsic failure (pint), which is, as stated before, beyond the control of MFIs, we can produce three two-dimensional risk maps (Fig 4), one in the thpext plane (constant τ¯=τ0+σ), another in the thτ¯ plane (constant pext), and the last one in the pextτ¯ plane (constant th). Each of the three risk maps shows three distinct regimes of the network dynamics. Regime I is characterized by a high equilibrium fraction of active agents, f+*, thus carrying little credit risk for the MFI. In contrast, regime III has a low equilibrium fraction of active agents, f*, such that the network can never re-enter regime I even if the probability of intrinsic failure improves to pint = 0. Regime III, consequently, implies a high credit risk for an MFI and needs to be avoided at all cost. Intermediate regime II generally leads to the low-f equilibrium, f*, from which it is always possible to recover provided the probability pint improves sufficiently. In addition, for small values of pext (roughly < 0.005; not shown), some paths satisfy f*<f<f+* for an indeterminate period of time because the fraction of failed neighbors ends up distributed around the critical fraction, th. Mathematically, we have 0 < E < 1. These paths always permit a recovery and hence qualitatively belong to regime II. In the context of managing microfinance credit risk, regime II implies a necessity for caution and it should prompt actions aimed at restoring better performance. By classifying the network dynamics into three distinct regimes and identifying their respective implications for credit risk management, we have made the connection between the dynamics and risk more apparent, but we have yet to specify the factors controlling the prevalence of each regime.

thumbnail
Fig 4. Risk maps for credit risk evaluation.

We are interested in where the real-world lender’s parameters are situated relative to the region of the phase space characterized by high instability. Our model depends on three parameters, but instead of a three-dimensional phase space, we plot risk maps in three separate two-dimensional phase planes. The model exhibits three distinct behaviors depending on the parameter values: a high-f regime (I), a low-f regime with recovery (II), and a low-f regime without recovery (III). (a) Phase diagram in the th-pext plane with constant τ¯=τ0+σ, where τ0 = 7 and σ = 30. (b) Phase diagram in the th-τ¯ plane with constant pext = 0.009. (c) Phase diagram in the pext-τ¯ plane with constant th = 0.2. The probability of intrinsic failure is pint = 0.004. Shown are the numerical results and curves of best fit.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g004

The risk maps (Fig 4) reveal the factors that promote the prevalence of each of the network dynamics regimes. Here, it is useful to recall that the smaller the value of th and the larger the value of pext, the more an agent depends on its neighbors. When the average time to agent recovery, τ¯=τ0+σ, is constant (Fig 4a), a high enough value of th always keeps the network in regime I. This result is understandable given that the probability of extrinsic failure, pext, plays a role in the dynamics only if the intrinsic failure rate is sufficient by itself to raise the fraction of failed neighbors of an agent to the level of th. If th is high enough, we may never observe such an outcome. Conversely, a decreasing value of th generally forces the network to jump from regime I to II, unless pext is sufficiently high to force a direct transition to regime III. Qualitatively different behavior is observed when pext is held constant and τ¯ is allowed to change (Fig 4b). In this case, for any value of th, recoveries from failures can be sufficiently slow (i.e. τ¯ sufficiently high) that the network transitions first from regime I to II and then from regime II to III. However, direct transitions from regime I to III are impossible. Finally, when th is held constant (Fig 4c), an increasing τ¯ first drives the network from regime I to II and then from regime II to III, unless again pext is sufficiently high for a direct transition to regime III to be possible. In addition to mapping microfinance credit risk in the described manner, we can also consider the question if there are any early-warning signs that could be exploited to mitigate or even avoid the negative impact of a regime shift.

As a critical point is approached, complex dynamical systems often become less attracted to the equilibrium state, experiencing bigger displacements and slower recoveries from perturbations [29]. This phenomenon—dubbed critical slowing down—should, therefore, reveal itself through a larger standard deviation and longer correlation of the state variables. In Fig 5a, we show that a gradual increase in the probability parameter pext causes the standard deviations of the fractions of active and extrinsically failed agents to spike when the dynamical network approaches a critical point during the shift from regime I to regime II. Because spiking begins noticeably before the regime shift, this critical slowing down may be used as an early-warning indicator of a network breakdown [29]. We also conducted a detrended fluctuations analysis (DFA) [30] to analyze auto-correlation in the model outputs (Fig 5b). The DFA auto-correlation function is of the form F(l) ∝ lα, where l is the scale (lag) and α is an exponent measuring the strength of the correlation. When α<12 (α>12) two consecutive displacements of the network state—e.g. of the fraction of active agents f—are more likely to be in the opposite (same) direction. The exponent α=12 indicates no correlation. In our dynamical network, for small pext, we observe (Fig 5b) a finite-range auto-correlation of the random-walk type (α ≈ 1.5), but its strength gradually diminishes at larger scales [23]. However, as the network undergoes the regime shift at pext = 0.006, the auto-correlation exhibits considerable strength even at large scales. Once pext takes the network decisively into regime II, the strength of the auto-correlation is again similar to that observed in the case of small pext. Accordingly, we identified two potential early-warning indicators complementary to the microfinance credit risk mapping, both of which could help mitigate the negative impact of a regime shift.

thumbnail
Fig 5. Early-warning indicators of a regime shift.

(a) Standard deviations of the fractions of active and extrinsically failed agents spike as the dynamical network undergoes a shift from regime I to regime II at pext = 0.006 (cf. Fig 4a and 4c). (b) Auto-correlation at the network level due to agent failures exhibits a longer memory close to the regime shift at pext = 0.006 (cf. Fig 4a and 4c). In detrended fluctuation analysis (DFA) the strength of the correlation is reflected in the scaling exponent, α (corresponding to the slope in the logarithmic plot). Lines with slopes α = 1.5 and α = 0.5 (no correlation) are plotted for easier visual comparison. Parameter values are th = 0.2, τ0 = 7, and σ = 30. The probability of intrinsic failure is pint = 0.004.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g005

Empirical analysis

To interpret the real-world microfinance data (Fig 6a) in the context of our modeling framework, we performed an empirical analysis by estimating the model parameters from the available data set using the method of moments (see the Methods section). Upon obtaining the parameter estimates, we conducted simulations to visually compare the data set and the model outputs (Fig 6b). The results of the empirical analysis indicate a very small probability of intrinsic failure, p¯int=3.7×104 per day, which is equivalent to saying that each month about 1.1% of the Grameen’s network of active borrowers is at risk of default. Such a low percentage is quite reasonable given that Grameen Bank is a successful MFI that has been maintaining a high loan payment probability for over three decades. The estimated critical fraction, th = 0.0695, is also small, pointing to two plausible interpretations. First, aside from a very general rationale [31], we had no evidence for letting the number of neighbors saturate at around 100, and therefore may have chosen a level that is too high to reflect reality. If so, the estimate of the threshold th should be rather low. Second, because the estimated critical fraction of the average number of neighbors (i.e. 7% of 100) is about the same as the size of borrowing groups (6 people), it would seem that financial decisions of borrowers are determined by the status of their most immediate neighbors. For a borrower in a critically inactive neighborhood, the probability of extrinsic failure, pext = 0.0019 per day, suggests that there is a less than 5.8% chance for a strategic default to occur in the next month. If the borrower defaults, the average time to recovery consistent with the data is τ¯=39.85 days. The obtained parameter values put Grameen Bank rather firmly into the domain of regime I (Fig 6c), as could be expected from the successful operations of this MFI. However, the low value of th is a reason for some concern should the economic environment deteriorate.

thumbnail
Fig 6. Data set, comparison with model runs, and the risk map for Grameen bank.

(a) The data set contains monthly information on amounts due that were actually paid to Grameen bank between June 2002 and Jan 2013. A long-term trend observable in the data is extracted using a smoothing spline, s(t). The trend suggests that the model forcing is of the form pint(t)=p¯int+Δpint(t), where p¯int is a constant and Δpint(t) a zero-mean smooth function of time. (b) Comparison of the data set with typical model runs reveals satisfactory agreement between the two. For the forcing term, we assume Δpint(t)=c[s(t)s¯], where c=18 and s¯ is the average of s(t). (c) Estimated model parameters place Grameen bank in regime I (x-mark) as could be expected from one of the most successful microfinance representatives. Even in the wake of 2007–2008 financial crisis, Grameen Bank continues to operate in the low risk regime (star) despite the more challenging economic environment.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0126447.g006

Discussion

Reducing the major credit risks of MFIs to just a few parameters, as we have done herein, offers practical pathways to risk mapping and management, similar in spirit to the approach used by Ref. [15]. To illustrate this idea, consider that the parameters th and pext describe the risk arising from the latent moral hazard of a strategic default [6, 27, 28]. In particular, th is the critical point at which borrowers start doubting the positive value of further cooperation with the lending program. The value of cooperation may be perceived differently by different individual borrowers, but the important question is how MFIs can strengthen that perception in a general manner. Here we refer to new ideas, independent of the established mechanisms of strict group liability with peer selection and monitoring. The latter mechanisms certainly play an effective role in reducing information asymmetries, but they also transfer the costs of screening and identifying delinquents from lenders to borrowers [25, 32] without guaranteeing lower interest rates in return (especially in the case of a for-profit lender). By contrast, improving the perception of the value of cooperation tends to raise social capital by lowering the transaction costs of working towards common goals [33, 34]. A good example might be educational activities, which, although primarily aimed at raising human capital, also have the capacity to “engender goodwill and sentiments of reciprocity” [35]. Furthermore, emphasis on building social capital may have an additional positive effect of lowering the probability of extrinsic failure, pext. This presumed effect is because social capital is based on relations of trust, reciprocity, and connectedness in networks [33], all of which help not only to establish but also maintain spontaneous cooperation [34].

Concerning the generality of the present work, we admit that in some aspects our model is more like “a proof of concept” than the general solution that fits the specifics of each and every MFI in existence. However, most real-world cases can be cast into a form analyzable within the proposed modeling framework because of its great flexibility and extendability. For instance, decaying networks could be used to model permanent defaults [6] by excluding intrinsically failed agents with infinite recovery times. Dynamical networks could also be used to imitate mechanisms of moral hazard complementary to the one we have already described. An example would be failed connections between agents [23] when the information exchange is interrupted as a consequence of lax peer monitoring [6, 9]. Additionally, new agents could be allowed to enter the network, leading to a class of models that explicitly incorporates outreach as a vital component of microfinance industry [4, 9]. Finally, competition between two or more MFIs [10] could be modeled in a setting where networks of borrowers overlap, allowing more robust networks to take over parts of more fragile ones. We therefore conclude that the concept of dynamical networks makes a promising new tool for analyzing open questions in microfinance with the potential for greatly improving, if not revolutionizing, the perception of sustainability in this industry.

Methods

We constructed an agent-based model mimicking the characteristics of an MFI by surmising that network theory is a natural framework for such a construct. Agents (i.e. equal-sized nodes of the network) represent borrowers, who can be in an active or an inactive state. The active state signifies that the borrower is regularly paying installments, whereas the inactive state indicates that the borrower is currently unable to pay or refusing to continue with the payments. The overall success of the MFI is indicated by the fraction of active agents, f, which serves as a proxy for the loan payment probability. An agent can fail intrinsically (i.e. switch from an active to an inactive state) as the involuntary consequence of owning an unsuccessful small enterprise. The probability of intrinsic failure, pint, is small because at any moment most enterprises are expected to continue doing business as usual. However, pint increases in a deteriorating economic environment or if the lender is unable to discriminate against risky borrowers with limited collateral (adverse selection). The described formalism is similar to that in Ref. [22] with the exception that here pint is conditional on agents being in the active state. Otherwise, agents in the inactive state could fail again, which would correspond to multiple defaults of a single borrower. We assume that such multiple defaults are impossible. Finally, because the probability of intrinsic failure is beyond the control of MFIs, this variable can be considered as a forcing for the model.

In contrast to intrinsic failure, an owner of a successful small enterprise may be hesitant to pay scheduled installments for extrinsically motivated considerations. These considerations are based on the availability of information on how regularly other borrowers service their loan obligations. We assume that two agents are connected in the usual sense of network theory if each of them knows whether the other one is currently active. Given the way microfinance operations are set up, it is quite certain that such knowledge is common among the members of the same group. The situation becomes progressively more opaque as the geographical reach extends from the group to a management unit, a branch, and, ultimately, the whole MFI. Thus, we set up a hierarchical network (Fig 1) in a way that n1 < n2 < n3 < n4 agents corresponding to a group, a unit, a branch, and the whole institution, respectively, are connected with the probabilities q1 > q2 > q3 > q4, respectively. The size parameters (ni) can be constrained by observing Grameen’s operations with roughly 6 persons per group, 10 groups per unit, and 7 units per branch. The connectedness probabilities (qi) are more loosely constrained by the facts that the group structure and weekly unit meetings guarantee information exchange, a branch covers a limited geographic area, and the average total number of connections per agent should saturate at around 100 [31]. We assume that, as suggested by the Watts model [26] and additionally explored by Refs. [22, 23], if a certain critical fraction of neighbors, th, turns inactive, an agent is tempted—with the small probability pext—to purposely do the same. Such an assumption accounts for the latent moral hazard of strategic default when borrowers no longer believe that other borrowers will continue honoring their loan agreements [6, 27, 28]. Note that the larger the value of th, and the smaller the value of pext, the less an agent depends on its neighbors. The parameter pext is, similarly to the forcing pint, conditional on agents being in the active state. Furthermore, the failure is said to be extrinsic because the available information on the state of the other agents prompts a voluntary reaction.

In microfinance every failure is addressed by a branch manager. Unsuccessful borrowers may have their payments rescheduled or may be issued new loans to jump-start their businesses. Accordingly, we assume that the inactive agents in the network, irrespective of whether they failed intrinsically or extrinsically, recover after a time τ. Because the manager cannot resolve issues immediately, the time to recovery is greater than a certain minimum time, τ0. Managers may also vary in their ability to handle the problems that led to the failure, which is why the recovery time has a random component [23], Δτ, so that τ = τ0 + Δτ. The random variable Δτ is assumed to be exponentially distributed with the standard deviation σ, a measure of the diverse abilities of the managers. One of the properties of the exponential distribution is that σ also serves as the expectation of the random variable Δτ, thus giving the expected time to recovery τ¯=τ0+σ. With these specifications, we are finally in a position to define that an agent is in the inactive state if it has failed either intrinsically or extrinsically, and if the time since failure is less than the time to recovery. Otherwise, the agent is in the active state. A reader keen on better understanding the intricacies of the described model may benefit from the derivation of a deterministic analogue below. Mathematical symbols appearing throughout are given in Table 1.

Deterministic model

We derive deterministic equations that govern the time evolution of the average number of active, intrinsically failed, and extrinsically failed agents. Let us denote these quantities by f(t), nint(t), and next(t), respectively. The change in f(t) is given by the difference in the total number of recovering, Rtot(t), and failing, Ftot(t), agents at an arbitrary moment t. For recoveries, we have Rtot(t)=[1f(tτ¯)]/τ¯ because out of 1f(tτ¯) agents that are in the failed state at tτ¯, only the fraction 1/τ¯ can recover at t. For failures, we have Ftot(t) = Fint(t) + Fext(t) = f(t)pint + f(t)(1 − pint)E(t)pext because (i) only active agents can fail, (ii) intrinsic failures have priority over extrinsic ones (i.e. the latter are conditional on the former not happening at the same time), and (iii) the probability of an agent having a critically inactive neighborhood is E(t). Furthermore, it holds by definition that Rtot(t+τ¯)=Ftot(t) which yields (2) It is now apparent that the equilibrium fraction of active agents, f*—given in Eq (1)—follows from Eq (2) as the time dependence of the probability E(t) wanes. Next, looking at the number of recoveries from intrinsic, Rint(t), and extrinsic, Rext(t), failures separately, the same logic as before dictates Rint(t)=nint(tτ¯)/τ¯ and Rext(t)=next(tτ¯)/τ¯. The definitions imply Rint(t+τ¯)=Fint(t) and Rext(t+τ¯)=Fext(t), resulting in (3a) (3b) Using Eqs (2, 3a, and 3b) a quick check gives f(t) + nint(t) + next(t) = 1 as it should be. We thus see that the underlying dynamics of our model are relatively simple, yet able to generate rather complex dynamical phenomena owing to the stochasticity and a small set of rules that determine how E(t) depends on time.

Empirical analysis

Real-world microfinance data can be interpreted in the context of our modeling framework by estimating the model parameters from the data. An appropriate method for doing so is the method of moments. We apply this method to a 10-year monthly data set, consisting of loan collection probabilities recorded by Grameen Bank from June 2002 to January 2013. Stated more precisely, “loan collection probabilities” mean the percentage of the amounts due that were actually paid, which is compatible with the model output f. One difficulty in estimating the model parameters is the apparent trend in the data (Fig 6a), suggesting a time-dependent forcing of the form pint(t)=p¯int+Δpint(t), where p¯int is a constant and Δpint(t) a zero-mean smooth function of time. We therefore use a smoothing spline, s(t), to extract the trend and then, during the estimation, treat p¯int as just another parameter. To keep the total number of parameters at a computationally manageable level, we assume without a major loss of generality that the minimum time to recovery, τ0, is seven days. Altogether we aim at reproducing the first four moments of the available data set, i.e. the mean (m1), the standard deviation (m21/2), the standardized skewness (m3/m23/2), and the standardized kurtosis (m4/m22). At the point of best fit, the empirical moments compare favorably with the model-generated ones (mean ± s.d. from 500 runs): 0.9805 vs. 0.9833±0.0004, 0.0023 vs. 0.0023±0.0002, −0.9133 vs. −0.2907±0.2705, and 4.0024 vs. 3.0238±0.5994 for the mean, the standard deviation, the standardized skewness, and the standardized kurtosis, respectively. A comparison of the original data set with three typical model runs is shown in Fig 6b. In these simulations, we assume that the time-dependent forcing is Δpint(t)=c[s(t)s¯], where c is a proportionality constant set to 18 and s¯ is the average of s(t). Such an assumption is justifiable in regime I (Fig 2). Finally, with reasonable agreement between the data and the model results, we construct a risk map for Grameen bank analogous to those shown in Fig 4. In this case, however, we use a pext-pint phase diagram (Fig 6c), where the probability of intrinsic failure should be interpreted as the average forcing, p¯int.

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Ashir Ahmed, Saša Drezgić, Tomislav Lipic, Simon Levin, Tadasu Matsuo, and Zhen Wang for comments and discussions.

Author Contributions

Conceived and designed the experiments: J-HL MJ BP YI. Performed the experiments: J-HL MJ BP YI. Analyzed the data: J-HL MJ BP YI. Wrote the paper: J-HL MJ BP YI.

References

  1. 1. Morduch J. The microfinance promise. J Econ Lit. 1999;37:1569–1614.
  2. 2. Copestake J, Bhalotra S, Johnson S. Assessing the impact of microcredit: A Zambian case study. J Dev Stud. 2001;37:81–100.
  3. 3. Khandker SR. Microfinance and poverty: Evidence using panel data from Bangladesh. World Bank Econ Rev. 2005;19:263–286.
  4. 4. Hermes N, Lensink R. Microfinance: its impact, outreach, and sustainability. World Dev. 2011;39:875–881.
  5. 5. Karlan D, Zinman J. Expanding credit access: Using randomized supply decisions to estimate the impacts. Rev Financ Stud. 2010;23:433–464.
  6. 6. Marr A. A challenge to the orthodoxy concerning microfinance and poverty reduction. J Microfinance. 2003;5:7–42.
  7. 7. Elahi KQ, Danopoulos CP. Microfinance and third world development: a critical analysis. J Polit Mil Soc. 2004;32:61–78.
  8. 8. Hermes N, Lensink R. The empirics of microfinance: what do we know? Econ J. 2007;117:F1–F10.
  9. 9. Conning J. Outreach, sustainability and leverage in monitored and peer-monitored lending. J Dev Econ. 1999;60:51–77.
  10. 10. McIntosh C, Wydick B. Competition and microfinance. J Dev Econ. 2005;78:271–298.
  11. 11. Mersland R, Strøm RØ. Microfinance mission drift? World Dev. 2010;38:28–36.
  12. 12. Dehejia R, Montgomery H, Morduch J. Do interest rates matter? Credit demand in the Dhaka slums. J Dev Econ. 2012;97:437–449.
  13. 13. May RM, Levin SA, Sugihara G. Complex systems: Ecology for bankers. Nature. 2008;451:893–895. pmid:18288170
  14. 14. May RM, Arinaminpathy N. Systemic risk: the dynamics of model banking systems. J R Soc Interface. 2010;7:823–838. pmid:19864264
  15. 15. Beale N, Rand DG, Battey H, Croxson K, May RM, Nowak MA. Individual versus systemic risk and the Regulator’s Dilemma. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2011;108:12647–12652. pmid:21768387
  16. 16. Haldane AG, May RM. Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature. 2011;469:351–355. pmid:21248842
  17. 17. Arinaminpathy N, Kapadia S, May RM. Size and complexity in model financial systems. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2012;109:18338–18343. pmid:23091020
  18. 18. Gale DM, Kariv S. Financial Networks. Am Econ Rev. 2007;97:99–103.
  19. 19. Schweitzer F, Fagiolo G, Sornette D, Vega-Redondo F, Vespignani A, White DR. Economic networks: The new challenges. Science. 2009;325:422–425. pmid:19628858
  20. 20. Gai P, Kapadia S. Contagion in financial networks. Proc R Soc A. 2010;466:2401–2423.
  21. 21. Elliott M, Golub B, Jackson MO. Financial networks and contagion. Am Econ Rev. 2014;104:3115–3153.
  22. 22. Majdandzic A, Podobnik B, Buldyrev SV, Kenett DY, Havlin S, Stanley HE. Spontaneous recovery in dynamical networks. Nature Phys. 2014;10:34–38.
  23. 23. Podobnik B, Majdandzic A, Curme C, Qiao Z, Zhou WX, Stanley HE, et al. Network risk and forecasting power in phase-flipping dynamical networks. Phys Rev E. 2014;89:042807.
  24. 24. Podobnik B, Horvatic D, Ling F, Bertella M, Li B. Systemic risk in dynamical networks with stochastic failure criterion. Europhys Lett. 2014;106:68003.
  25. 25. Stiglitz JE. Peer monitoring and credit markets. World Bank Econ Rev. 1990;4:351–366.
  26. 26. Watts DJ. A simple model of global cascades on random networks. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2002;99:5766–5771. pmid:16578874
  27. 27. Morduch J. The microfinance schism. World Dev. 2000;28:617–629.
  28. 28. Cassar A, Crowley L, Wydick B. The effect of social capital on group loan repayment: evidence from field experiments. Econ J. 2007;117:F85–F106.
  29. 29. Scheffer M. Foreseeing tipping points. Nature. 2010;467:411–412. pmid:20864992
  30. 30. Peng CK, Buldyrev SV, Havlin S, Simons M, Stanley HE, Goldberger AL. Mosaic organization of DNA nucleotides. Phys Rev E. 1994;49:1685–1688.
  31. 31. Dunbar RI. Neocortex size as a constraint on group size in primates. J Hum Evol. 1992;22:469–493.
  32. 32. Ghatak M. Group lending, local information and peer selection. J Dev Econ. 1999;60:27–50.
  33. 33. Pretty J. Social capital and the collective management of resources. Science. 2003;302:1912–1914. pmid:14671287
  34. 34. Ostrom E. A general framework for analyzing sustainability of socio-ecological systems. Science. 2009;325:419–422. pmid:19628857
  35. 35. Karlan D, Valdivia M. Teaching entrepreneurship: Impact of business training on microfinance clients and institutions. Rev Econ Stat. 2011;93:510–527.