Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T05:18:13.078Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Property Rules or the Rule of Property? Carol Rose on the History, Theory, and Rhetoric of Ownership

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 December 2018

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © American Bar Foundation, 1996 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Friedrich Hayek, The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1944) (“Hayek, Road to Serfdom”)Google Scholar

2 Rose, , Property and Persuasion at 3; for a slightly different take on her debts to Bentham, see her “Property as a Keystone Right?” 71 Notre Dame Law Rev. 330 (1996); Jeremy Bentham, The Principles of Morals and Legishtion (New York: Macmillan, 1948, orig. 1780 & 1789).Google Scholar

3 Coase, R. H., “Law and Economics at Chicago,” 36 J. L. & Econ. 239, esp. 248–50 (1993).Google Scholar

4 Lord Robbins, Autobiography of an Economist 105–31 (London: Macmillan, 1971); Elizabeth Durbin, New Jerusalems: The Labour Party and the Economics of Demomaric Socialism 101–36 (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1985).Google Scholar

5 Coase, R. H., “Economics at the LSE in the 1930s,” 10 Atlantic Econ. J. 3134 (1982); Coats, A. W., “The Distinctive LSE Ethos in the Inter-War Years,” 10 Atlantic Econ. J. 1830 (1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 Coase, 36 J. L. & Econ., at 243–48. I do not wish to obscure important discrepancies and tensions within this group. For a useful sample, see George Stigler, “Law or Economics?” 30 J. L. & Econ. 455–68 (1992).Google Scholar

7 Hayek, Road to Serfdom and his “History and Politics,” in Hayek, ed., Capitalism and the Historians 3–29 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1954); T. E. Flanagan, “F. A. Hayek on Property and Justice,”in Anthony Parel & Thomas Flanagan, eds., Theories of Property: Aristotle to the Present 355–57 (Waterloo, Ont.: Wilfred Laurier University Press, 1979). I leave aside Hayekian implications of his version of the rule of law for democratic theory, although there are some quite obvious insalubrities, both in formulation and legacy. On the relationship between Carl Schmitt's critique of liberalism and Hayek, see Cristi, F. R., “Hayek and Schmitt on the Rule of Law,” 17 Can. J. Pol. Sci. 521–35 (1984). On the gruesome fallout of this world-view in Latin America, see Juan Gabriel Valdéz, Pinochet's Economists: The Chicago School in Chile (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), and on the left‘s efforts to come to terms with this force majeure, see Jeffrey M. Puryear, Thinking Politics: Intellectuals and Democracy in Chile, 1973–1988 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994). For a Hayekian theory of democracy, see Wittman, Donald, “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results,” 97 J. Pol. Econ. 13951424 (1989).Google Scholar

8 Douglass C. North, “A Theory of Institutional Change and the Economic History of the Western World,”in Michael Hechter, ed., The Micro-Foundations of Macrosociology 190–215 (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983), and id., Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Demsetz, Harold, “Some Aspects of Property Rights,” 9 J. L. & Econ. 6070 (1966), and Demsetz, Harold & Alchian, Armen, “The Property Rights Paradigm,” 33 J. Econ. Hist. 1627 (1973). For an effort to place bargaining in a non-level-playing-field setting, and thus confront the problem of systematic asymmetries, see Ayes, Ian & Gertner, Robert, “Strategic Contractual Inefficiency and the Optimal Choice of Legal Rules,” 101 Yale L. J. 729–67 (1994).Google Scholar

9 William Blackstone, Commentaries on the Laws of England, 4 vols. (London, orig. 1765–69); Kennedy, Duncan, “The Structure of Blackstone's Commentaries,” 28 Buff. L. Rev. 205382 (1979).Google Scholar

10 Douglas C. North & Robert Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11 Munzer, A Theory of Property (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 J. G. A. Pocock, Virtue, Commerce and History: Essays on Political Thought and History, Chiefly in the Eighenth-Century (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, esp. at 17–20 (Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1976). For a broader discussion, see Albert Hirschman, The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph (Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University Press, 1977) (“Hirschman, Passions”), and Donald Winch, Adam Smith‘s Politics: An Essay in Historigraphic Revision (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978).Google Scholar

14 For further discussion of her retrieval of doux commerce, see also Rose's, Giving, Trading, Thieving and Trusting: How and Why Gifts Become Exchanges, and (More Importantly) Vice Versa,” 44 Fla. U. L. Rev. 295317 (1992).Google Scholar

15 North, Structure and Change in Economic History, passim (New York: Norton, 1981).Google Scholar

16 For a classic case, see Garrett Hardin, “The Tragedy of the Commons,” 162 Science 1243–48 (13 Dec. 1968); and more recently, with a “property rights” spin, see Gary Libecap, Locking up the Range: Federal Land Controls and Grazing (San Francisco: Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research, 1981), and his extended discussion of “common pool problems” in Contracting for Property Rights (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989). For a parallel story involving seafood, see Agnello, Richard J. & Donnelley, Lawrence P., “Property Rights and Efficiency in the Oyster Industry,” 18 J. L. & Econ. 521–33 (1975).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 Morton J. Horwitz, The Transformation of American Law, 1780–1860, esp. chap. 2 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1977).Google Scholar

18 This fits, as Rose shows, Thomas Merrill's argument that as transaction costs mount, law becomes more discretionary, or “judgmental,” and conversely, as transaction costs fall, law becomes more “mechanical,” yielding to all-or-nothing solutions. See Merrill, , “Trespass, Nuisance and the Costs of Determining Property Rights,” 14 J. Legal Stud. 1348 (1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 It is worth underscoring the complexity with which she treats exchange–but it is exchange nonetheless. See her article in 44 Fla. U. L. Rev., esp. at 315.Google Scholar

20 In this sense, Rose also offers something of an alternative reading the evolution of discourses about rights from Mary Ann Glendon's counter-“hyperindividualist” Jeremiad. See Glendon, Rights Talk: The Impovershment of Political Discoure (New York: Free Press, 1991).Google Scholar

21 This itself, as Rose acknowledges, is a classical formulation, explored by Hirschman in Passions.Google Scholar

22 C. B. Macpherson, The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: Hobbes to Locke (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1962). This of course does not mean that Macpherson's account of the political language framing the origins of capitalism was entirely accurate but simply that he captured a widespread view about contractarian origins of commercial society.Google Scholar

23 Basu, Kaushik, Jones, Eric & Schlicht, Ekkehart, “The Growth and Decay of Custom: The Role of the New Institutional Economics in Economic History,” 24 (4) Explorations Econ. Hist. 121 (1987); Bates, Robert H., “Contra Contractarianism: Some Reflections on the New Institutionalism,” 16 Politics & Soc'y 387401 (1988), id., “Social Dilemmas and Rational Individuals: An Assessment of the New Institutionalism,”in J. Harris, J. Hunter, & C. M. Lewis, eds., The New Institutional Economics and Third World Development 27–48 (London: Routledge, 1995).CrossRefGoogle Scholar