Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Two Tales of Adjustment: East Asian Lessons for European Growth

  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In 2008, euro area governments instituted fiscal stimulus to counteract the shock of the Global Financial Crisis. In 2010, they changed tack and pursued consolidation. East Asia also implemented stimulus in response to its 1997–98 financial crisis but, unlike Europe, continued fiscal expansion until growth recovered. The baseline difference between the average growth rate of the east Asian countries and the European Periphery/GIIPS prior to their respective crises was 4.21 percentage points. This difference widens to 7.18 percentage points following the European pivot to austerity in region-specific crisis event time. Panel regressions confirm the statistical significance of this 2.97 percentage point increase in the difference-in-difference estimate suggesting that more gradual fiscal consolidation in the GIIPS might have promoted stronger recovery.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In contrast to previous episodes, disciplined fiscal policy leading up to this crisis gave emerging-market countries room to pursue countercyclical fiscal policies during the crisis, and this made a substantial difference (Blanchard, 2013). The evidence on initial conditions in our paper suggests that east Asian countries consistently ran fiscal surpluses in the run-up to the crisis and had much lower debt-to-GDP ratios on the eve of their crisis in comparison to the GIIPS countries, giving them greater fiscal room to pursue countercyclical policies during the crisis.

  2. The original euro area refers to member countries that adopted the euro before physical notes and coins were first introduced in January 2002.

  3. The crisis year for east Asia is 1998; 2008 for the Global Financial Crisis. The five calendar time periods for the east Asian crisis are therefore 199497 (precrisis), 1998 (crisis), 19972002 (overall performance), 19992000 (postcrisis I), and 200102 (postcrisis II). For the Global Financial Crisis the time periods are 200407 (precrisis), 2008 (crisis), 200712 (overall performance), 200910 (postcrisis I), and 201112 (postcrisis II).

  4. The Appendix provides a detailed derivation showing the correspondence between the Blanchard and Leigh (2014) specification and our baseline specification.

  5. In a related paper, Fatás and Mihov (2003) find that the volatility of output caused by discretionary fiscal policy lowers economic growth by more than 0.8 percentage points for every percentage-point increase in volatility.

  6. The finding is consistent with evidence that countries with less flexible exchange rate regimes tend to face greater macroeconomic and financial vulnerabilities (Ghosh, Ostry, and Qureshi, 2014). Similarly, large currency depreciations increase growth shortly after a crisis (Forbes and Klein, 2013).

  7. Corsetti, Meier, and Müller (2012) demonstrate that the effects of government spending vary with the economic environment and find output and consumption multipliers to be unusually high during times of financial crisis.

  8. The equation estimated in Blanchard and Leigh (2014) is: Forecast Error of Δy i,t:t+1=α+βForecast of ΔF i,t:t+1 i,t:t+1 where under rational expectations, and assuming that the correct model has been used for forecasting, the coefficient on the forecast of fiscal consolidation should be zero.

  9. In Blanchard and Leigh (2014), the corresponding notation is of the form where ΔY i, t: t+1 denotes cumulative (year-over-year) growth of real GDP (Y) in economy i—that is, (Y i, t+1/Y i, t−1−1)—and the associated forecast error is ΔY i,t: t+1fY i,t: t+1 t }, where f denotes the forecast conditional on Ω t , the information set available early in year t.

  10. In Blanchard and Leigh (2014) the corresponding notation is as follows: ΔF i,t:t+1 denotes the change in the general government structural fiscal balance in percent of potential GDP, a widely used measure of the discretionary change in fiscal policy for which we have forecasts. Positive values of ΔF i,t:t+1 indicate fiscal consolidation, whereas negative values indicate discretionary fiscal stimulus. The associated forecast is “Forecast of ΔF i,t:t+1|t ” defined as f{F t+1, i F t−1,i t }.

References

  • Alesina, Alberto and Silvia Ardagna, 2010, “Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus Spending,” in Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 24, ed. by Jeffrey R. Brown (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 35–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto and Roberti Perotti, 1995, “Fiscal Expansions and Adjustments in OECD Economies,” Economic Policy, Vol. 10, No. 21, pp. 207–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, Alan and Yuriy Gorodnichenko, 2012, “Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion,” in Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis, ed. by Alberto Alesina, and Francesco Giavazzi (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, Scott R., Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis, 2013, “Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty,” Chicago Booth Research Paper No. 13-02.

  • Blanchard, Olivier and Daniel Leigh, 2014, “Learning about Fiscal Multipliers from Growth Forecast Errors,” IMF Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 2, pp. 179–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2013, “Monetary Policy Will Never Be the Same,” iMFdirect Blogpost, (accessed November 19, 2013).

  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, André Meier, and Gernot J. Müller, 2012, “What Determines Government Spending Multipliers?,” Economic Policy, Vol. 27, No. 72, pp. 521–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger and Stanley Fischer, 1987, Macroeconomics (New York: McGraw-Hill), 1990, Chapter 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fatás, Antonio and Ilian Mihov, 2003, “The Case for Restricting Fiscal Policy Discretion,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118, No. 4, pp. 1419–1447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fedelino, Annalisa, Anna Ivanova, and Mark A. Horton, 2009, Computing Cyclically-Adjusted Balances and Automatic Stabilizers (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, Kristin and Michael Klein, 2013, “Pick Your Poison: The Choices and Consequences of Policy Responses to Crises,” MIT-Sloan Working Paper 5062-13.

  • Ghosh, Atish, Jun Kim, Enrique Mendoza, Jonathan Ostry and Mahvash Qureshi, 2013, “Fiscal Fatigue, Fiscal Space and Debt Sustainability in Advanced Economies,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 123, No. 566, pp. F4–F30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, Atish, Jonathan Ostry and Mahvash Qureshi, 2014, “Exchange Rate Management and Crisis Susceptibility: A Reassessment,” IMF Working Paper 14/11 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

  • Guajardo, Jaime, Daniel Leigh and Andrea Pescatori, 2011, “Expansionary Austerity: New International Evidence,” IMF Working Paper 11/158 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

  • Henry, Peter Blair, 2007, “Capital Account Liberalization: Theory, Evidence and Speculation,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 45, No. 4, pp. 887–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry, Peter Blair, 2013, Turnaround: Third World Lessons for First World Growth (New York: Basic Books).

    Google Scholar 

  • Henry, Peter Blair and Conrad Miller, 2009, “Institutions versus Policies: A Tale of Two Islands,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 99, No. 2, pp. 261–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2009, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, April).

  • International Monetary Fund. 2010, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, October).

  • Jordà, Oscar and Alan M. Taylor, 2013, “The Time for Austerity: Estimating the Average Treatment Effect of Fiscal Policy,” NBER Working Papers 19414 (National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc).

  • Lane, Philip R., 2013, “Growth and Adjustment Challenges for the Euro Area,” IIIS Discussion Paper No. 427.

  • Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2012, “External Adjustment and the Global Crisis,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 88, No. 2, pp. 252–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2009, This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer, 1989, “Does monetary policy matter? A new test in the spirit of Friedman and Schwartz,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1989, ed. by Olivier Blanchard and Stanley Fischer Volume 4 (MIT Press), pp. 121–184.

  • Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer, 2010, “The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks,” American Economic Review, Vol. 100, No. 3, pp. 763–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vegh, Carlos and Guillermo Vuletin, 2013, “The Road to Redemption: Policy Response to Crises in Latin America,” Working paper.

  • World Bank Group. 2015, Global Economic Prospects, January 2015: Having Fiscal Space and Using It (Washington, DC: World Bank) doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0444-1.

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*Anusha Chari is an Associate Professor of Economics at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and a research fellow at the NBER. Peter Blair Henry is William R. Berkley Professor of Economics and Finance and Dean at New York University’s Leonard N. Stern School of Business. The authors thank Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Ayhan Kose, Morris Goldstein, two anonymous referees, and participants at the IMF’s Fourteenth Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. Allison Cay Parker provided stellar editorial assistance.

Appendix

Appendix

Although regressing realized changes in real GDP growth on realized changes in the CAPB provides the most direct evidence for the question at hand (Do changes in the CAPB have an impact on growth?), we provide a detailed derivation below showing the correspondence of our benchmark specification with Blanchard and Leigh (2014). The Blanchard and Leigh specification is logically equivalent to our approach of including lagged terms for output growth and the change in the CAPB. The coefficient β3 in Equation (1) is the coefficient on lagged GDP growth and embeds a parsimonious forecast of current GDP growth under the assumption that the best guess of output growth for country i at time t is its lagged value at time t−1; that is, E(y i, t )=y i,t−1.

A parsimonious forecast model relating output growth to changes in the structural balance can be written as:

where is the forecast of real GDP growth for country i, is the forecast of the change in the CAPB conditional on the information set available early in period t. This implies that if we run the Blanchard and Leigh (2014) specification of the formFootnote 8:

where is the output growth forecast error,Footnote 9 under the null hypothesis that fiscal multipliers used for forecasting were accurate, the coefficient β1 on the fiscal forecast variable should be zero.Footnote 10

Plugging from Equation (A.1) into Equation (A.2), we get:

where u it =e it it and is iid mean zero and uncorrelated with ΔCAPB i,t:t+1|t .

Rewriting:

where and .

This implies that:

Therefore, subtracting (A.5) from (A.4), we get:

Under the assumption that in small samples where it is hard to identify a unit root the best forecast of is γy i,t using quasi-differencing, we get:

under the parameter restrictions γ=β9 and β2=−β1γ. Using quasi-differencing and parameter restrictions, Equation (A.7) our benchmark specification encompasses the Blanchard and Leigh specification (equation (A.2)) albeit written in the form of y it and γy it−1.

Since we have a small sample, we do not want to assume a random walk in growth forecast. Instead we assume an AR(1) model where AR(1) parameter, γ, equal to unity would imply a random walk. To identify a unit root the parameter γ needs to be pinned down at frequency zero to give a value of γ=1 which is, however, a long-run phenomenon and hard to identify in small samples.

To see this in Equation (A.8), the parameter restrictions to identify a unit root would be α0=0, γ=1 where ɛ it is an iid shock with mean zero. In the absence of a theory to pin down the parameter γ on lagged output growth, we allow it to differ from one and leave it as a free parameter to be estimated and to let the data speak. Given model uncertainty we also include other conditioning variables in lagged form to the estimating equation (A.7).

Similarly, under rational expectations, the actual change in the CAPB should correspond to the forecasted change in the CAPB (similar to using realized earnings as a measure of expected earnings in asset pricing equations). Including the current and lagged values of ΔCAPB it therefore corresponds to “Forecast of ΔF i,t: t+1|t ” in the Blanchard and Leigh specification defined as f{F t+1, i F t−1,i t } where f denotes the forecast conditional on Ω t , the information set available early in year t. Notice that in the absence of forecast data, (ΔCAPB i,t −ΔCAPB i,t−1) is numerically equivalent to f{F t , i F t−2,i t−1 }, where ΔCAPB it =CAPB i,t CAPB i,t−1 and ΔCAPB it−1=CAPB i,t−1CAPB i,t−2. Under rational expectations, the actual change in the CAPB should correspond to the forecasted change in the CAPB. To reiterate, the dependent variable of interest in the Blanchard and Leigh specification is the forecast error in the year-over-year growth in real GDP, and the independent variable is the forecast of the change in the CAPB.

Corresponding to Blanchard and Leigh, in our benchmark specification, ΔCAPB i,t:t+1 denotes the change in the general government structural fiscal balance as a percent of potential GDP, a widely used measure of the discretionary change in fiscal policy for which we have forecasts. Positive values of ΔCAPB i,t:t+1 indicate fiscal consolidation, whereas negative values indicate discretionary fiscal stimulus.

Table A1

Table A1 Variable Definitions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chari, A., Henry, P. Two Tales of Adjustment: East Asian Lessons for European Growth. IMF Econ Rev 63, 164–196 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2015.3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2015.3

JEL Classifications

Navigation