Skip to main content
Log in

Fingerspitzengefühl

Towards a relentless quest for soul and (ergodic) precision in (insurance) economics

  • Published:
The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance - Issues and Practice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 27 October 2021

This article has been updated

Abstract

Orio Giarini spent a life working on insurance, growth, wealth and technology. His work was deeply influenced by a famous Austrian novel, namely The Man without Qualities authored by Robert Musil. In this novel, a so-called Secretariat of Soul and Precision plays an important role. Musil's Secretariat turns out to be a remarkable prism through which Orio Giarini's many contributions can be deciphered. In the following text, I submit the hypothesis, among other ideas, that Orio Giarini had a very early intuition on two important and related notions, namely ergodicity and path dependence, whose consequences are still not fully understood in economics. Ergodicity and path dependence are indeed critical when one aims at bringing more precision to soul and more soul to precision.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

Notes

  1. “In any research, even the most ‘quantitative’, it is essential to develop what the English call ‘feeling’, or feeling of things, and the Germans call ‘Fingerspitzengefühl’ (feeling things with your fingertips).”

  2. “Count Leinsdorf! Ulrich said softly. Do you remember that I once advised you to set up a general secretariat for all problems that require as much soul as precision?” Musil (1981, p. 1043).

  3. I still have the book in my personal library. In English: The Diminishing Returns of Technology: An Essay on the Crisis in Economic Growth.

  4. "Je peux dire que ce livre est une des plus grandes lectures que j’aie jamais faites et que c’est un livre éminemment obscur, illisible et irrésistible, que la lecture en est une mystérieuse corvée, presque insurmontable pour la plus grande part des lecteurs, mais que, une fois cette corvée dépassée, tandis que la lecture se dépose, il s’élève d’elle un incomparable enchantement." https://www.lalibre.be/archive/l-homme-sans-qualites-robert-musil-51b8ee9be4b0de6db9c76481.

  5. To put it in Emmanuel Derman's words ““In physics, it takes three laws to explain 99% of the data; in finance, it takes more than 99 laws to explain about 3%.” So quipped MIT finance professor Andrew Lo at a dinner I once attended. Economists, he added, consequently suffer from physics envy.” https://hbr.org/2005/10/beware-of-economists-bearing-greek-symbols.

  6. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Procrustes.

  7. According to Douglass North (North1999), “In fact, Samuelson’s assertion was that if the world is nonergodic, economics is not a science.” https://scholarship.law.duke.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1165&context=delpf.

  8. http://iml.univ-mrs.fr/~lafont/rencontres/esi098.pdf.

  9. Due to compounding effects, investors’ wealth is a convex function of realised returns. Hence, volatility plays a critical role in the growth of wealth. Hence, over the long run, over one single realised return path, the investor’s growth rate should approach the median, not the mean, meaning that volatility plays a crucial role in long-term wealth levels.

  10. This is how the famous Saint Petersburg paradox was solved.

  11. Rates are compounded, hence the multiplicative process over time.

  12. Peters (2019) recognises that optimising time average growth rates is a null model, and as such, it has all the shortcomings null models have. At least this null model is conceptually clearer and less subjective. Note that loss aversion can also be handled through non-ergodicity without having to use a behavioural economics toolkit.

  13. Future dividends are discounted. Here again discounting/compounding introduces non-linearities.

  14. Again, wealth compounds over time.

  15. Even though the causality may work both ways.

  16. See Teich (2006) for more details.

  17. https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=B8YfwpqGJwc

  18. https://necsi.edu/power-law

  19. The clustering can be triggered by various factors including preferential attachment, criticality, multiplicative processes etc.

  20. Pure risk is, in my view, pure as, under non-linear dynamics, unknown unknowns strike unexpectedly. Add path dependency and the traditional cause-effect and the law of large numbers break down (see Thurner et al. 2018, p. 85).

  21. https://a16z.com/2011/08/20/why-software-is-eating-the-world/

  22. See https://jasonzweig.com/what-harry-markowitz-meant/.

  23. With the exception of the Cory Lamberts of this world.

  24. One of his articles is titled in the same vein: Understanding is a poor substitute for convexity (antifragility). www.edge.org.

  25. As the reader may have guessed, Ulrich Tuzzi is Musil's Ulrich’s grandson!

  26. Starting on page 258.

  27. Libraries are the archetype of antifragility!

References

  • Borch, K.H. 1987. Insurance without utility theory. In Theory and decision, essays in honor of Werner Leinfellner, ed. G.L. Eberlain, H. Bergel, and D. Kufstein. New York: Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briys, E., and H. Loubergé. 1983. Le contrat d’assurance comme option de vente. Finance 4 (2): 139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caye, P. 2015. Critique de la destruction créatrice. Paris: Les Belles Lettres.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, R. 1991. Tortoises and hares: Choice among technologies of unknown merit. Economic Journal 101: 407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellul, J. 1988. Le bluff technologique. New York: Hachette.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O. 1984. Cycles, values and employment, responses to the economic crises. Oxford: Pergamon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O. 2002. Itinéraire vers la retraite à 80 ans avec une lettre ouverte à ceux qui ont (ou auront) 65 ans. Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O. 2005. The service economy: The context for the new welfare. http://www.neweconomictheory.org/files/The%20service%20economy%20by%20orio.pdf.

  • Giarini, O. 2012. Secretariat of the soul and uncertainty. Eruditio 1: 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O. 2013. The balance sheet of the parallel action carried out by the secretariat of the soul and precision, 100 years later. Cadmus 2: 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O. 2014. New paradigm in the service economy the search of economics for scientific credibility: In between hard and soft sciences. Cadmus 2014: 94–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O., and H. Loubergé. 1978. The diminishing returns of technology: An essay on the crisis in economic growth. Oxford: Pergamon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarini, O., and H. Loubergé. 1979. La civilisation technicienne à la dérive, les rendements décroissants de la technologie. Dunod.

  • Giarini, O., and W. Stahel. 1993. The limits to certainty. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Haugen, R.A. 1998. Beast on Wall Street. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haugen, R.A. 2009. The new finance: Overreaction, complexity and uniqueness, 4th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. 1991. Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments, 2nd ed. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D., D. Meadows, J. Randers, and W.W. Behrens II. 1972. The limits to growth. New York: The Club of Rome.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molenaar, P.C. 2004. A manifesto on psychology as idiographic science: Bringing the person back into scientific psychology, this time forever. Measurement: Interdisciplinary Research and Perspectives 2: 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musil, R. 1981. Der Mann ohne Eigenschaften. Hamburg: Rohwolt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musil, R. 1990. Precision and soul: Essays and addresses. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R.R. 2005. Technology, institutions and economic growth. Harvard University Press.

  • North, D.C. 1999. Dealing with a non-ergodic world: Institutional economics, property rights, and the global environment. Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum 10: 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Outreville, J.-F. 2013. The relationship between insurance and economic development: 85 empirical papers for a review of the literature. Risk Management and Insurance Review 16 (1): 71–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pappalardo, S. 2021. Modernism in Trieste, the Habsburg mediterranean and the literary invention of Europe, 1870–1945. London: Bloomsbury Academic.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, O. 2019. The ergodicity problem in economics. Nature Physics 15: 1216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, O., and A. Adamou. 2017. Insurance makes wealth grow faster. https://arxiv.org/abs/1507.04655.

  • Peters, O., and M. Gell-Mann. 2016. Evaluating gambles using dynamics. Chaos 26: 23103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper & Bros.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szazs, D. 2000. Boltzmann’s ergodic hypothesis, a conjecture for centuries? In Hard ball systems and the Lorentz gas. Encyclopaedia of mathematical sciences (Mathematical Physics II), vol. 101, ed. D. Szász. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabarrok, A. 2014. Average stock market returns aren’t average. https://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2014/07/average-stock-market-returns-arent-average.html.

  • Taleb, N.N. 2008. The black swan: The impact of the highly improbable. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N.N. 2012. Antifragile: Things that gain from disorder. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teich, A.H. 2006. Technology and the future. Stamford: Thomson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thurner, S., R. Hanel, and P. Klimek. 2018. Introduction to the theory of complex systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • West, G. 2017. Scale. New York: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric Briys.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Please note that the correct German spelling for Fingerspitzengefühl has been used in this text. The word was not correctly written in Orio's original quote (Giarini 2002, p. 159).

The original online version of this article was revised due to an incorrect word in one sentence on page 255.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Briys, E. Fingerspitzengefühl. Geneva Pap Risk Insur Issues Pract 46, 248–265 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41288-021-00214-w

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41288-021-00214-w

Navigation