Skip to main content
Log in

Complexity in international business: The implications for theory

  • Counterpoint
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

International business is inherently complex for four main reasons: the large number of countries, products, technologies and firms involved, the intricate connectivity of international transport and communications networks, the diversity of the political, cultural and regulatory environment, and the speed and unpredictability of change. The complexity created by these features can be measured using the techniques presented in this paper. IB has developed simple and powerful theories which abstract from inessential details and thereby reduce the complexity of theory to a minimum. The assumptions underlying this theory are common to other disciplines, and provide a basis for future inter-disciplinary research.

Résumé

Les affaires internationales sont intrinsèquement complexes pour quatre raisons principales : le grand nombre de pays, de produits, de technologies et d'entreprises impliquées, l’imbrication étroite des réseaux de communication et de transport internationaux, la diversité de l'environnement réglementaire, politique et culturel, ainsi que la rapidité et l'imprévisibilité du changement. La complexité créée par ces caractéristiques peut être mesurée à l'aide des techniques présentées dans cet article. Le domaine des affaires internationales a développé des théories simples et puissantes qui font abstraction des détails non essentiels et réduisent ainsi la complexité de la théorie au minimum. Les postulats qui sous-tendent cette théorie sont communs à d'autres disciplines et fournissent une base pour de futures recherches interdisciplinaires.

Resumen

Los negocios Internacionales son inherentemente complejos por cuatro razones principales: el gran número de países, productos, tecnologías y empresas involucradas; la intrincada conectividad del transporte internacional y de las redes de comunicaciones, la diversidad del entorno político, cultural y regulatorio, y la velocidad e imprevisibilidad del cambio. La complejidad creada por estas características puede ser medida usando técnicas presentadas en este manuscrito. Negocios Internacionales ha desarrollado unas teorías simples y poderosas las cuales se abstraen de los detalles no esenciales, y, por lo tanto, reducen la complejidad de la teoría al mínimo. Los supuestos subyacentes a esta teoría son comunes a otras disciplinas y proporcionan una base para futuras investigaciones interdisciplinarias.

Resumo

Negócios internacionais são inerentemente complexos por quatro razões principais: o grande número de países, produtos, tecnologias e empresas envolvidas; a intrincada conectividade de redes internacionais de transporte e comunicação, a diversidade do ambiente político, cultural e regulatório e a velocidade e imprevisibilidade de mudanças. A complexidade criada por essas características pode ser medida usando as técnicas apresentadas neste artigo. IB desenvolveu teorias simples e poderosas que abstraem de detalhes não essenciais e, portanto, reduzem a complexidade da teoria ao mínimo. Os pressupostos subjacentes a esta teoria são comuns a outras disciplinas e fornecem uma base para futuras pesquisas interdisciplinares.

摘要

国际商务本质上是复杂的, 主要有四个原因: 涉及的国家、产品、技术和公司数量众多; 国际运输和通讯网络错综复杂的连通性, 政治、文化和监管环境的多样性, 以及变化的速度和不可预测性。由这些特征产生的复杂性可用本文介绍的技术来测量。国际商务(IB)开发了从非本质的细节中抽象出来的简单而强大的理论, 从而将理论的复杂性降至最低。这一理论所依据的假设与其它学科相同, 并为未来的跨学科研究提供了基础。

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aguinis, H., & Gabriel, K. P. 2021. International business studies: Are we really so uniquely complex? Journal of International Business Studies.. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-021-00462-x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguinis, H., Ramani, R. S., & Cascio, W. F. 2020. Methodological practices in international business research: An after-action view of challenges and solution. Journal of International Business Studies, 51: 1593–1608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aksentijevic, A., & Gibson, K. 2012. Psychological complexity and the cost of information processing. Theory and Psychology, 22(5): 572–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asmussen, C. G., Benito, G. R. G., & Petersen, B. 2009. Organizing foreign market activities: From entry mode choice to configuration decisions. International Business Review, 18: 145–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekes, G., Benito, G. R. G., Castellani, D., & Murakozy, B. 2021. Into the unknown: The extent and boldness of firm’s international footprints. Global Strategy Journal, 11(3): 468–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bossaerts, P., & Murawski, C. 2017. Computational complexity and human decision-making. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 21(12): 917–929.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W., & Hommes, C. 1997. Models of complexity in economics and finance. In C. Schumacher, B. Hanzon, & C. Praagman (Eds.), System dynamics in economic and finance models: 3–41. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 2001. Strategic complexity in international business. In A. M. Rugman, & T. L. Brewer (Eds.), Oxford handbook of international business: 88–126. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Caligiuri, P., De Cieri, H., Minbaeva, D., Verbeke, A., & Zimmermann, A. 2020. International HRM insights for navigating the COVID-19 pandemic: Implications for future research and practice. Journal of International Business Studies, 51: 691–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casson, M. 2016. The theory of international business: Economic models and methods. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chellappan, R., Gupta, A., & Venkat, R. 2021. Strategy decision making: A study using computational complexity theory. Turkish Journal of Computer and Mathematics Education, 12(11): 3535–3543.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colli, A. 2015. Dynamics of international business. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Contini, R. 2017. Complexity and sociology. Sociology Study, 7(7): 376–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eden, L., & Nielsen, B. 2020. Research methods in international business: The challenge of complexity. Journal of International Business Studies, 51(9): 1609–1620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashai, N., & Adler, N. 2021. Internalization choices under competition: A game-theoretic approach. Global Strategy Journal, 11: 109–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Y., Han, W., & Macbeth, D. 2020. The complexity of collaboration in supply chain networks. Supply Chain Management, 25(3): 393–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manson, S. 2001. Simplifying complexity: A review of complexity theory. Geoforum, 32(3): 405–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merca, M. 2014. A note on the Jacobi-Stirling numbers. Integral Transforms and Special Functions, 25(3): 196–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naldi, M., & Flamini, M. 2018. Dynamics of the Hirschmann-Herfindahl index under new market entry. Economics Papers, 37(3): 344–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouchi, W. 1981. Theory Z: How American business can meet the Japanese challenge. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitelis, C., & Verbeke, A. 2007. Edith Penrose and the future of the multinational enterprise: New research directions. Management International Review, 47(2): 139–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebout, N., Lone, J., De Marco, A., Cozzolino, R., Lemasson, A., & Thierry, B. 2021. Measuring complexity in organisms and organizations. Royal Society Open Science, 8(3): 200895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1962. The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106: 467–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahlne, J., & Johanson, J. 2021. Coping with complexity by making trust an important dimension in governance and coordination. International Business Review, 30(2): 101798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasconcelos, F., & Ramirez, R. 2011. Complexity in business environments. Journal of Business Research., 64(3): 236–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., van Tulder, R., Rose, E. L., & Wei, Y. (Eds.). 2020. The multiple dimensions of institutional complexity in international business research. Bingley: Emerald.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., & Yuan, W. 2020. A few implications of the COVID-19 pandemic for international business studies research. Journal of Management Studies, 58(2): 597–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiedmer, R., Rogers, Z., Polyviou, M., Mena, C., & Chae, S. 2021. The dark and bright sides of complexity: A dual perspective on supply network resilience. Journal of Business Logistics, 42(2): 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark Casson.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Accepted by Liena Kano, Guest Editor, 15 November 2021. This article has been with the authors for one revision.

Appendix: Case study of the measurement of structural complexity in a simple IB model

Appendix: Case study of the measurement of structural complexity in a simple IB model

The complexity of IB studies and the power of IB theory may be illustrated by a simple example. Consider a world composed of N different countries, populated by H firms, all of which are potential MNEs. Each firm uses a different proprietary technology to the others, although consumers regard their final products as basically the same. It is desired to determine which firms supply which markets, what prices will prevail in each market and what profits each firm will make.

Each firm has to decide whether to serve each national market and, if so, where to locate its production for that market. Each firm serves a given market from a single location, but can serve different markets from different locations if it wishes to do so. Whether a firm becomes an MNE depends on the choices that it makes; if it decides not to produce abroad then it does not become an MNE. It is assumed to begin with that headquarters and R&D are collocated at a fixed location. Firms with inferior technologies may not operate at all.

Consider a set of tables summarising the solution of this problem. One subset of tables relates to production and trade. For each firm, there is an N × N table showing how much it supplies from each production location to each market. There are H firms and therefore H such tables and, taken together, they have a total of HN2 cells. There is a smaller table with N cells recording the prices that prevail in each market, and another table with H cells reporting the profits made by each firm (firms that do not operate make a zero profit). The solution is therefore encoded in HN2 + H + N cells. This number is a measure of the ‘tabular complexity of the solution’.

The solution varies according to the assumptions on which the theory is based. Suppose that there are two general principles: that firms maximise profit, and that they compete for market share in each country. Suppose, in addition, that each customer in each market demands a fixed amount of each product and refuses to pay more for the product than some reservation price, p*. Then, the amount of product demanded in each market at or below the reservation price is some amount, q. The prices and quantities demanded vary across markets according to local population, incomes and tastes.

Suppose also that there are constant unit costs of production and transport and that there are no fixed costs. Let the total cost to firm h of supplying a unit of product from a plant in location i to a market j be chij (h = 1,…, H; i, j = 1,…, N). The elements chij are measured gross of production costs, transport costs, tariffs and technology transfer costs. They number HN2 and constitute the elements of H individual N × N tables, each of which represents the cost structure faced by an individual firm.

The other quantitative data required to specify the problem concern the structure of the individual markets: the amount of the product demanded in each market, qj, and the maximum price that consumers will pay p*j (j = 1,.., N). The data is therefore contained in HN2 unit costs cells, a column of N market sizes and another column of N reservation prices. These comprise a total of HN2 + 2N cells. This is almost the same as the number of cells that need to be filled by the solution; indeed, if there were no reservation prices (so that each market was always served), then the two would be identical). This number represents the ‘tabular complexity of the data’.

Each firm can serve any given market from any location: one option is to serve a market by local production and the others are to import from plants in other locations. Each firm plans to serve a given market from the cheapest location, i.e. the location i*hj where its unit cost is a minimum, c*hj = mini chij.

The firm with the lowest cost, c**j = minh c*hj will serve the entire jth market. They will drive out their competitors by setting price just below the unit cost of their closest competitor, which is the firm with the second-lowest unit cost. There are two exceptions, however: if the lowest unit cost is above the local reservation price, then no firm will serve the market at all; and if the second-lowest unit cost exceeds the reservation price, then the firm will charge the reservation price because otherwise it will lose the market altogether.

Let pj* be the price set in the jth market when that market is served by its least cost firm. Let qj be the size of the market, as measured by the quantity of sales. Revenue is equal to Rj = pj*qj, and cost is Cj = c**j qj. In the absence of fixed costs, the profit of the firm serving the jth market is π*j = R*jC*j.

There is no limit to the size or geographical diversification of any firm. Its decisions about whether to serve a particular market are not constrained by its decisions to serve other markets. According to this competitive outcome, some firms may be entirely domestic, serving their home market by local production; some may serve their home country only by imports; others may produce in the home country for export, and perhaps also for their domestic market; while some may serve one or more foreign markets, either by exports from their home country or from a third country.

By counting up the number of arithmetical operations involved in the solution process, a measure of ‘computational complexity’ can be obtained; such measures are widely used to assess the efficiency of computer algorithms. The solution involves four main steps, as indicated above. The first step is to determine for each firm the least cost production location from which to serve each market and the unit cost associated with it. This is effected by moving along the list of location-specific costs for each combination of firm and market and recording the lowest figure. This process involves HN2 operations. The second step is to compare the costs across firms for any given market; it is the least-cost firm that serves the market. This involves HN operations. The third step is to determine market prices by calculating the minimum of the reservation price and the lowest cost in each market. If the reservation price is the minimum, then the market is not served. If the least cost is the minimum, then it is necessary to compare the second least cost with the reservation price. Whichever is the minimum determines the market price. This involves reprocessing the information obtained at the first stage; the amount of reprocessing depends on the number of firms involved. Overall, therefore, the calculations involve a minimum of HN(N + 1) operations; this may be regarded as a measure of the computational complexity.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Casson, M., Li, Y. Complexity in international business: The implications for theory. J Int Bus Stud 53, 2037–2049 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-021-00495-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-021-00495-2

Keywords

Navigation