Skip to main content
Log in

COMMON ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT ORGANIZATIONS THAT MISLEAD INSTITUTIONAL RESEARCHERS AND THEIR CLIENTS

  • Published:
Research in Higher Education Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Institutional researchers need to be aware ofthe theoretical and normative assumptions they holdregarding the character of institutional behavior. Somecommonly held assumptions can lead to inaccurate assessments of rational organizationalbehavior. Many people's concepts about the nature ofinstitutional intelligence, resources, goals, andproblems appear faulty based on contemporaryorganizational theory. These faulty assumptions lead tomisdiagnosing leaders' and policymakers' actions andlessen the impact of institutional research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

REFERENCES

  • Allen, R., and Chaffee, E. E. (1981). Management fads in higher education. Unpublished paper, National Center for Higher Education Management Systems, Inc., Boulder, CO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balderston, F. E., and Weathersby, G. B. (1972, May). PPBS in Higher Education Planning and Management: From PPBS to Policy Analysis. Berkeley, CA: Report P-31, Ford Foundation Program for Research in University Administration, University of California.

  • Birnbaum, R. (1988). How Colleges Work: The Cybernetics of Academic Organization and Leadership. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, P. M. (1964). Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Capra, F. (1996). The Web of Life. New York: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., and Olsen, J. P. (1972, March). A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Science Quarterly17(1): 1±25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahrendorf, R. (1968). Market and plan: Two types of rationality. In Essays in the Theory of Society. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1968, pp. 215±231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedland, E. I. (1974). Introduction to the Concept of Rationality in Political Science. Morristown, NJ: General Learning Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Georgiou, P. (1973, September). The goal paradigm and notes toward a counter paradigm. Administrative Sciences Quarterly18(3):.

  • Gerth, H. H., and Mills, C. W. (1946). From Max Weber: Essay in Sociology. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, E. (1969). The definition of organizational goals. British Journal of Sociology20: 277±294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. (1961). Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms. New York: Harcourt, Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, P. (1966, July/Aug.). Fallacy of the one big brain. Harvard Business Review44: 84±90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchins, R. M. (1956). The administrator: Leader or officeholder? In Freedom, Education and the Fund: Essays and Addresses, 1946 ± 1956. New York: Meridian Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilchman, W. F., and Uphoff, N. T. (1971). The Political Economy of Change. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, D., and Kahn, R. L. (1966). The Social Psychology of Organizations. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. S. (1962). The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom, C. E. (1959, Spring). The science of muddling through. Public Administration Review19(2): 79±88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters, T. J., and Waterman, R. H., Jr. (1982). In Search of Excellence. New York: Harper & Row, Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidtlein, F. A. (1977). Information systems and concepts of higher education governance. In C. R. Adams (ed.), New Directions for Institutional Research, vol. 15. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidtlein, F. A. (1983). Comprehensive and incremental decision paradigms and their implications for educational planning. In G. H. Copa and J. Moss, Jr. (eds.), Planning and Vocational Education. New York: Greg Division, McGraw-Hill Book Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidtlein, F. A., and Glenny, L. A. (1977). State Budgeting for Higher Education: The Political Economy of the Process. Berkeley, CA: Center for Research and Development in Higher Education, University of California, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickers, G. (1965). The Art of Judgement. New York: Basic Books, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, A. (1966, Dec.). The political economy of efficiency: Cost-benefit analysis, systems analysis, and program budgeting. Public Administration Review26(4): 292± 310.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schmidtlein, F.A. COMMON ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT ORGANIZATIONS THAT MISLEAD INSTITUTIONAL RESEARCHERS AND THEIR CLIENTS. Research in Higher Education 40, 571–587 (1999). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1018700511894

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1018700511894

Keywords

Navigation