Skip to main content
Log in

Litigation Versus Legislation: Forum Shopping by Rent Seekers

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To change the law, an interest group must choose between lobbyingthe legislature and litigating for new precedent. Lobbyingbecomes more likely as the relative benefits from rule changebecome greater, as the costs of lobbying become smaller and asthe voting strength of the interest groups becomes larger.Litigating becomes more likely as trial costs fall, as therelative benefits from rule change become greater, as theinclination of courts to change existing precedents increases,and as the interest group is involved in more trials. Examplesof using a litigating strategy include the NAACP is its battlefor racial integration and attorneys seeking change in tort law.Business, in resisting changes to tort law, has used the judicialprocess. The nature of equilibrium, if any, is not clear.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Bailey, M.J. and Rubin, P.H. (1994). A positive theory of legal change. International Review of Law and Economics 14: 467–477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 371–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkowitz, E.D. and Berkowitz, M. (1985). Challenges to workers' compensation: An historical analysis. In J.D. Worrall and D. Appel (Eds.), Workers' compensation benefits: Adequacy, equity, and efficiency. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commerce Clearing House (1981). Products liability reporter. New York: Commerce Clearing House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curran, C. (1992). The spread of the comparative negligence rule in the United States. International Review of Law and Economics 12: 317–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farber, D.A. and Frickey, P.P. (1991). Law and public choice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer, A. and Pecorino, P. (1999). Legal expenditure as a rent-seeking game. Public Choice 100: 271–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gedde, D. (1992). The determinants of products liability law: An interest group perspective. Unpublished paper.

  • Hillman, A.L. and Riley, J.G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Public Choice 1: 17–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1991). The paradox of power. Economics and Politics 3: 177–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, P.W. and Litan, R.E. (Eds.). (1991). The liability maze. Washington: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W.M. and Posner, R.A. (1987). The economic structure of tort law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leubsdorf, J. (1984). Toward a history of the American rule on attorney fee recovery. Law and Contemporary Problems 47: 9–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1998). Economic analysis of law. Fifth Ed. New York: Aspen Law & Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prichard, R.S. (1988). A systemic approach to comparative law: The effect of cost, fee, and financing rules in the development of the substantive law. Journal of Legal Studies 17: 451–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G.L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. Journal of Legal Studies 6: 65–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. and Weingast, B.R. (1988). Constitutional regulation of legislative choice: The political consequences of judicial deference to legislatures. Virginia Law Review 74: 373–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? Journal of Legal Studies 6: 51–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H. (1995). Fundamental reform of tort law. Regulation 4: 26–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H. and Bailey, M.J. (1994). The role of lawyers in changing the law. Journal of Legal Studies 23: 807–831.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H., Calfee, J.E. and Grady, M.F. (1997). BMW v. Gore: Mitigating the punitive economics of punitive damages. Supreme Court Economic Review 5: 179–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R.D. (1988). Public choice and legislation. Virginia Law Review 74: 339–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J.M. Buchanan, R. Tollison and G. Tullock (Eds.) Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, 269–282. College Station: Texas A&M Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Tushnet, M.V. (1987). The NAACP's legal strategy against segregated education. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rubin, P.H., Curran, C. & Curran, J.F. Litigation Versus Legislation: Forum Shopping by Rent Seekers. Public Choice 107, 295–310 (2001). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010337522287

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1010337522287

Keywords

Navigation