Skip to main content
Log in

A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation of the Aggregate Production Function Specification

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many growth models assume that aggregate output is generated by a Cobb-Douglas production function. In this article we question the empirical relevance of this specification. We use a panel of 82 countries over a 28-year period to estimate a general constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) production function specification. We find that for the entire sample of countries we can reject the Cobb-Douglas specification. When we divide our sample of countries up into several subsamples, we find that physical capital and human capital adjusted labor are more substitutable in the richest group of countries and are less substitutable in the poorest group of countries than would be implied by a Cobb-Douglas specification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arrow, K. J., H. B. Chenery, B. S. Minhas, and R. M. Solow. (1961). “Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency,” Review of Economics and Statistics 43, 225-250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C. (1993). Intertemporal Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C. (1996). “The Economics of Poverty Traps Part One: Complete Markets,” Journal of Economic Growth 1, 449-486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., and X. Sala-i-Martin. (1995). Economic Growth. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bencivenga, V. R., and B. D. Smith. (1997). “Unemployment, Migration and Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 105, 582-608.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., and M. M. Spiegel. (1994). “The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data,” Journal of Monetary Economics 34, 143-173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bils, M., and P. Klenow. (1996). “Does Schooling Cause Growth or the Other Way Around?” Working Paper, University of Rochester.

  • Boldrin, M. (1992). “Dynamic Externalities, Multiple Equilibria and Growth,” Journal of Economic Theory 58, 198-218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boskin, M. J., and L. J. Lau. (1992). “International and Intertemporal Comparison of Productive Efficiency: An Application of the Meta-Production Function Approach to the Group-of-Five (G-5) Countries,” Economic Studies Quarterly 43, 298-312.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., G. Esquivel, and F. Lefort. (1996). “Reopening the Convergence Debate: A New Look at Cross-Country Growth Empirics,” Journal of Economic Growth 1, 363-389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cass, D. (1965). “Optimum Growth in an Aggregate Model of Capital Accumulation,” Review of Economic Studies 32, 233-240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H., S. Robinson, and M. Syrquin. (1986). Industrialization and Growth. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe, D. T., and E. Helpman. (1997). “International R&D Spillovers,” European Economic Review 39, 859-887.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. (1965). “National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model,” American Economic Review 55, 1126-1150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, J., and C. Papageorgiou. (1999). “Factor Substitutability and Economic Growth.” Working Paper, Louisiana State University.

  • Durlauf, S., and P. Johnson. (1995). “Multiple Regimes and Cross-Country Growth Behavior,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 10, 365-384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger. (1987). “Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing,” Econometrica 55, 251-276.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (1996a). “Convergence? Inferences from Theoretical Models,” Economic Journal 106, 1056-1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (1996b). Club Convergence, Brown University.

  • Gollin, D. (1998). “Getting Income Shares Right: Self-Employment, Unincorporated Enterprise, and the Cobb-DouglasHypothesis.” Working Paper, Williams College.

  • Green, W. (1990). Econometric Analysis. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., and M. Yorukoglu. (1997). “1974,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 46, 49-95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1969). “Capital-Skill Complementarity,” Review of Economics and Statistics 51, 465-468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z., and J. A. Hausman. (1986). “Errors in Variables in Panel Data,” Journal of Econometrics 31, 93-118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R., and C. I. Jones. (1999). “Fundamental Determinants of Output PerWorker Across Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83-116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Islam, N. (1995). “Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 1127-1170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. I. (1997). “Convergence Revisited,” Journal of Economic Growth 2, 131-153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L. E., and R. E. Manuelli. (1990). “A Convex Model of Equilibrium Growth: Theory and Policy Implications,” Journal of Political Economy 98, 1008-1038.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L. E., and R. E. Manuelli. (1992). “Finite Lifetimes and Growth,” Journal of Economic Theory 58, 171-197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L. E., and R. E. Manuelli. (1997). “The Sources of Growth,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21, 75-114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1961). “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth.” In F. A. Lutz, and D. C. Hague (eds.), The Theory of Capital. New York: St. Martin's Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kmenta, J. (1967). “On Estimation of the CES Production Function,” International Economic Review 8, 180-189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, T. C. (1965). “On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth.” In The Econometric Approach to Development Planning. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, F. R., and B. van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie. (1998). “International R&D Spillovers: A Comment,” European Economic Review 42, 1483-1491.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3-42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer, and D. N. Weil. (1992). “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 407-437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nehru, V., and A. Dhareshwar. (1993). “A New Database on Physical Capital Stock: Sources, Methodology and Results” (in English), Revista de Análisis Econòmico 8, 37-59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nehru, V., E. Swanson, and A. Dubey. (1995). “A New Database on Human Capital Stock in Developing and Industrial Countries: Sources, Methodology and Results,” Journal of Development Economics 46, 379-401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W. K., and K. D. West. (1987). A Simple Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix, Econometrica 55, 703-708.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perron, P. (1989). “The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock, and the Unit Root Hypothesis,” Econometrica 57, 1361-1401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. (1994). “Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?” American Economic Review 84, 600-621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitchford, J. D. (1960). “Growth and the Elasticity of Substitution,” Economic Record 36, 491-504.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E. C. (1998). “Needed: A Theory of Total Factor Productivity,” International Economic Review 39, 525-551.

    Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). “Returns to Investment in Education: A Global Update,” World Development 22, 1325-1343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quah, D. (1996a). “Convergence Empirics Across Countries with (Some) Capital Mobility,” Journal of Economic Growth 1, 95-124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quah, D. (1996b). “Twin Peaks,” Economic Journal 106, 1045-1055.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rebelo, S. (1991). “Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 99, 500-521.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002-1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). “Endogenous Technological Change,” Journal of Political Economy 98, part 2, 71-102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 65-94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1957). “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function,” Review of Economics and Statistics 39, 312-320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1958). “A Skeptical Note on the Constancy of Relative Shares,” American Economic Review 48, 618-631.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N. L. (1996). “Free Trade, Factor Returns, and Factor Accumulation,” Journal of Economic Growth 1, 421-447.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, R., and A. Heston. (1991). “The Penn World Tables (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950–1988,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 327-368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tallman, E.W., and P. Wang. (1994). “Human Capital and Endogenous Growth: Evidence From Japan,” Journal of Monetary Economics 34, 101-124.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Duffy, J., Papageorgiou, C. A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation of the Aggregate Production Function Specification. Journal of Economic Growth 5, 87–120 (2000). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009830421147

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009830421147

Navigation