Skip to main content
Log in

Logical Deficiencies in Spatial Models: A Constructive Critique

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A fundamental property of any good theoryis logical consistency. However, two commonassumptions in the rational choice approach topolitical analysis (that induced preferences overpolicy are separable and that such preferences areindependent of changes in exogenous factors) are notconsistent with the archetypal assumptions ofindividual utility maximization. These particularpathologies of spatial models of politics have notbeen well recognized in the political scienceliterature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alt, J. and Lowry, R. (1996). The dynamics of fiscal adjustment in a partisan context. Presented at the annual meetings of Midwest Political Science Association (Chicago, IL).

  • Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (1990). Editors introduction. In J. Alt and K. Shepsle (Eds.), Perspectives on positive political economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austin-Smith, D. and Banks, J. (1990). Stable governments and the allocation of policy portfolios. American Political Science Review 84: 891–906.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J. and Hanushek, E. (1995). Introduction. In J. Banks and E. Hanushek (Eds.), Modern political economy: old topics, new directions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartholdi, J., Narsimhan, L. and Tovey, C. (1991). Recognizing majority rule equilibrium in spatial voting games. Social Choice and Welfare 8: 183–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P. and Hinich, M. (1984). Necessary and sufficient conditions for single-peakedness in public economic models. Journal of Public Economics 25: 161–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. and Parks, R. (1977). A problem with public sector preferences. Journal of Economic Theory 14: 454–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. and Parks, R. (1979). Deriving public sector preferences. Journal of Public Economics 11: 335–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diba, B. and Feldman, A. (1984). Utility functions for public outputs and majority voting. Journal of Public Economics 25: 235–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D. and O'Halloran, S. (1994). Administrative procedures, information, and agency discretion. American Journal of Political Science 38: 697–722.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., Filimon, R. and Romer, T. (1984). Equilibrium among local jurisdictions: Toward integrated treatment of voting and residential choice. Journal of Public Economics 24: 281–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. and Grofman, B. (1987). Necessary and sufficient conditions for a majority winner in n-dimensional spatial voting games: An intuitive geometric approach. American Journal of Political Science 31: 709–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. and Krehbiel, K. (1987). The budget process and the size of the budget. American Journal of Political Science 31: 296–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. and Satz, D. (1996). Unification, universalism, and rational choice theory. In J. Friedman (Ed.), The rational choice controversy: Economic models of politics reconsidered. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. In Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. and Jackson, J. (1994). Endogenous preferences and the study of institutions. American Political Science Review 87: 639–656.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A. and Grofman, B. (1988). Limitations of the spatial model. Public Choice 58: 161–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. and Shapiro, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. (1994). The committee outlier debate: A review and reexamination of some of the evidence. Public Choice 80: 265–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T., Levitt, S. and Snyder, J. (1999). Comparing interest group scores across time and chambers: Adjusted ADA scores for the U.S. Congress. American Political Science Review 93: 33–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J. and Quandt, R. (1980). Microeconomic theory: A mathematical approach. New York: McGraw Hill, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzner, D. (1968). A note on the differentiability of consumer demand functions. Econometrica 36: 415–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzner, D. (1970). Static demand theory. New York: Macmillian Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, R. and McCubbins, M. (1985). Appropriations as a bilateral bargaining game between president and congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly 9: 181–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, R. and McCubbins, M. (1988). Presidential influence on congressional appropriations decisions. American Journal of Political Science 32: 713–736.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet, R. and McCubbins, M. (1993). The logic of delegation: Congressional parties and the appropriations process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koehler, D. (1990). The size of the yolk: Computations for odd and even numbered committees. Social Choice and Welfare 7: 231–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koford, K. (1989). Dimensions in congressional voting. American Political Science Review 83: 949–964.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1986). A technique for estimating congressmen's ideal points. Journal of Politics 48: 97–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krehbiel, K. (1990). Are congressional committees composed of preference outliers. American Political Science Review 84: 149–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. and Shepsle, K. (1990). Coalitions and cabinet government. American Political Science Review 84: 873–890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. and Shepsle, K. (1996). Making and breaking governments: Cabinets and legislatures in parliamentary democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann. S. (1996). The poverty of Green and Shapiro. In J. Friedman (Ed.), The rational choice controversy: Economic models of politics reconsidered. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Londregan, J. and Snyder, J. (1994). Comparing committee and floor preferences. Legislative Studies Quarterly 19: 233–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. and Schwartz, T. (1985). The politics of Flatlands. Public Choice 46: 45–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models. Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey R. (1979). General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models. Econometrica 47: 1085–1111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meuller, D. (1989). Public choice II. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary, J. and Roberts, K. (1980). The theory of household behaviour under rationing. European Economic Review 13: 25–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. (1983). Why so much stability? Another opinion. Public Choice 41: 261–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. 1986. Game theory and political theory: An introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. (1990). The emerging discipline of political economy. In K. Shepsle and J. Alt (Eds.), Perspectives on positive political economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. and Rosenthal, H. (1985). A spatial model for legislative roll call analysis. American Journal of Political Science 29: 357–384. Poole, K. and Rosenthal, H. (1991). Patterns of congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science 35: 228-278. Rothbarth, E. (1941). The measurement of changes in real income under conditions of rationing. Review of Economic Studies 35: 228-278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schap, D. (1990). Executive veto and spending limitations: Positive political economy with implications for institutional choice. Public Choice 65: 239–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofiel, N. (1996). Rational choice and political economy. In J. Friedman Ed.), The rational choice controversy: Economic models of politics reconsidered. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N., Grofman, B. and Feld, S. (1988). The core and the stability of group choice in spatial voting games. American Political Science Review 82: 195–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. and Tovey, C. (1992). Probability and convergence for supra-majority rule with euclidean preferences. Center in Political Economy Working Paper No. 163, Washington University, St. Louis, MO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. (1992). Bureaucratic drift, coalitional drift, and time consistency. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8: 111–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B. (1984). Political solutions to market problems. American Political Science Review 78: 85–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky, S. (1975). Majority voting and the allocation of public goods. Yale University: Ph.D. dissertation

  • Slutsky, S. (1977). A voting model for the allocation of public goods: Existence of an equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 14: 299–325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiller, P. and Gely, R. (1990). A rational choice theory of supreme court statutory decisions with application to the State Farm and Grove City cases. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6: 263–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiller, P. and Spitzer, M. (1992). Judicial choice of legal doctrine. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8: 8–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. and Becker, A. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. American Economic Review 67: 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovey, C. (1991). The probability of an undominated central voter in 2-dimensional spatial majority voting. Social Choice and Welfare 9: 43–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovey, C. (1992). The instability of instability. Center in Political Economy Working Paper No. 161, Washington University, St Louis, MO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. and Marshall, W. (1987). The industrial organization of congress. Journal of Political Economy 96: 132–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B., Shepsle, K. and Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy 89: 642–664.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Milyo, J. Logical Deficiencies in Spatial Models: A Constructive Critique. Public Choice 105, 273–289 (2000). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1005203611524

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1005203611524

Keywords

Navigation