Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-27gpq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T08:53:44.668Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Uncovering Evidence of Conditional Party Government: Reassessing Majority Party Influence in Congress and State Legislatures

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 September 2005

WILLIAM T. BIANCO
Affiliation:
Penn State University
ITAI SENED
Affiliation:
Washington University in St. Louis

Abstract

This paper aims at enriching the debate over the measurement of majority party influence in contemporary American legislatures. Our use of a new analytic technique, a grid-search program for characterizing the uncovered set, enables us to begin with a better model of legislative proceedings that abandons the simple one-dimensional spatial models in favor of the more realistic two-dimensional version. Our conclusions are based on the analysis of real-world data rather than on arguments about the relative merits of different theoretic assumptions. Our analysis confirms that when legislators' preferences are polarized, outcomes will generally be closer to the majority party's wishes, even if the majority-party leadership does nothing to influence the legislative process. This conclusion notwithstanding, our analysis also shows that at the margin of the majority party's natural advantage, agenda setting by the majority party remains a viable and efficacious strategy.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2005 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aldrich John, and David Rohde. 1998. “Theories of Party in the Legislature and the Transition to Republican Rule in the House,” Political Science Quarterly 112: 11235.Google Scholar
Aldrich John H., and David W. Rohde. 2001. “The Logic of Conditional Party Government: Revisiting the Electoral Connection.” In Congress Reconsidered, Lawrence Dodd and Bruce Oppenheimer, eds. Washington: CQ Press.
Aldrich John H. 1995. Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Aldrich John H., and James S. Battista. 2000. “Conditional Party Government in the States.” American Journal of Political Science 46: 23556.Google Scholar
Bianco William T., Ivan Jeliaskov, and Itai Sened. 2004a. “The Uncovered Set and the Limits of Majority Rule.” Political Analysis 12: 25676.Google Scholar
Bianco William T., Michael S. Lynch, Gary J. Miller, and Itai Sened. 2004b. “A Theory Waiting to Be Discovered and Used: A Reanalysis of Canonical Experiments on Majority Rule Decision-Making.” Unpublished manuscript.
Bianco William, James Holloway, Michael Lynch, Gary Miller, and Itai Sened. 2004c. “Constrained Instability: Experiments on the Robustness of the Uncovered Set.” Unpublished manuscript, presented at the 2004 APSA meetings, Chicago, IL.
Cox Gary W. 1987. “The Uncovered Set and the Core.” American Journal of Political Science 31/2: 40822.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W., and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Cox Gary W., and Mathew D. McCubbins. 2003. Legislative Leviathan Revisited. Unpublished manuscript.
Clinton Joshua, Simon Jackman, and Doug Rivers 2004. “The Statistical Analysis of Roll Call Data.” American Political Science Review. 98 (2): 35570.Google Scholar
Cox Gary W., and Keith T. Poole. 2002. “On Measuring Partisanship in Roll-Call Voting: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1877–1999. American Journal of Political Science 46: 47789.Google Scholar
Groseclose Tim, and James M. Snyder, Jr. 2000. “Estimating Party Influence in Congressional Roll-Call Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (2): 193211.Google Scholar
Groseclose Tim, and James M. Snyder, Jr. 2001. “Explaining Party Influence in Roll Call Voting: Regression Coefficients vs. Classification Success. American Political Science Review 95: 68998.Google Scholar
Jenkins Jeffrey, and Marc Weidenmier. 1999Ideology, Economic Interests, and Congressional Roll-Call Voting: Partisan Instability and Bank of the United States Legislation, 1811–1816.” Public Choice 100: 22543.Google Scholar
King David C., and Richard L. Zeckhauser. 2003. “Congressional Vote Options.” Legislative Studies Quarterly, 28 (August): 387411.Google Scholar
Krehbiel Keith. 1999. “Paradoxes of Parties in Congress.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 24: 3164.Google Scholar
Krehbiel Keith. 2000. “Party Discipline and Measures of Partisanship.” American Journal of Political Science 44: 21227.Google Scholar
Londregan John. 1999. “Estimating Legislators' Preferred Points.” Political Analysis 8: 3556.Google Scholar
McCarthy Nolan, Keith Poole, and Howard Rosenthal. 2001. “The Hunt for Party Discipline in Congress.” American Political Science Review 95: 67388.Google Scholar
McKelvey Richard D. 1986. “Covering Dominance and Institution Free Properties of Social Choice,” American Journal of Political Science 30: 283314.Google Scholar
Miller Nicholas. 1980. “A New Solution Set for Tournament and Majority Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 24: 6896.Google Scholar
Poole Keith T., and Howard Rosenthal. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll-Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.
Shepsle Kenneth. A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibria in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science, 23: 2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle Kenneth, and Barry R. Weingast. 1984. “Uncovered Sets and Sophisticated Voting Outcomes with Implications for Agenda Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 28: 4974.Google Scholar
Shepsle Kenneth A., and Barry R. Weingast. 1994. “Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions,” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 19: 14981.Google Scholar