Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T16:03:43.154Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Death, Where Is Thy Sting? The Senate as a Ponce (de Leon) Scheme

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 September 2013

A Wuffle
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Thomas Brunell
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
William Koetzle
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine

Extract

Maltzman, Sigelman and Binder (1996), in what we regard as monumental work, have reinvigorated the study of death in office. But their data analysis is incomplete. First, they fail to project realistically the trends in actual and expected congressional deaths illustrated in Figure 1 of their paper. Second, like many congressional scholars, they do not pay sufficient attention to the Senate. We provide new evidence that the U.S. Senate may offer the solution to mankind's oldest quest, the fountain of youth (Gilgamesh n.d.; de Leon 1460–1521).

Table 1 presents data on the proportion of U.S. Senators who died in office, by decade, from 1910 to 1990 (CQ 1995).

We plotted the senatorial mortality rate data reported in Table 1 versus year (for data grouped by decade) as shown in Figure 1.

The r2 for the regression of mortality rates on time is an astonishingly large .87. Rarely have we seen such a clear time trend. Senators are increasingly not dying in office.

However, as our colleague, Bernard Grofman, pointed out to us (personal communication, April 2, 1995), projecting this equation past 1990 would give us negative estimates of mortality rates as early as the year 2000. Given the strength of our empirical results and the scholarly commitment we share with Gelman and King (1990) to investigating incumbency effects without a priori bias, we do not reject the idea of revenants out of hand.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The American Political Science Association 1997

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1.

This paper was not prepared for delivery in Barbara Sinclair's class on the “U.S. Congress,” UC Riverside, Winter Quarter, 1995. Nonetheless it was handed out there. The listing of authors is alphabetical by first name.

Thomas Brunell and William Koetzle are innocent (but very well-trained) political science graduate students at University of California-Irvine, whose empirical research the senior author of this paper is exploiting in accord with the best traditions of European scholarship. The two of them also wrote “Lipreading, Draft-Dodging and Perot-Noia: Party Campaigns in Editorial Cartoons.” Harvard International Journal of Press/Politics. Vol 1 No. 4 (1996): 94–115, and already have a number of other singly authored and multiply authored articles currently under submission.

References

Cain, Bruce. 1996. “The Varying Impact of Legislative Term Limits.” In Grofman, Bernard (ed.) Term Limits: Public Choice Perspectives. Boston, MA: Kluwer Publishers.Google Scholar
Congressional Quarterly Guide to U.S. Elections. 1995. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris. 1989. Congress: Keystone of the Federal Establishment, 2d Edition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew and King, Gary. 1990. “Estimating Incumbency Advantage Without Bias.” American Journal of Political Science 34:11421164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Gary and Gelman, Andrew. 1991. “Systematic Consequences of Incumbency Advantage in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 35.Google Scholar
Kubrick, Stanley and Clarke, Arthur C. 1968. “2001: A Space Odyssey.”Google Scholar
Maltzman, Forrest, Sigelman, Lee and Binder, Sarah. 1996. “Leaving Office Feet First: Death in Congress.” PS 29(4):664–71.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Stone, Alec. 1995. “Of Wuffle and Truffles: Gastronomic Investigations in the Neighborhood of the 1995 ECPR Meeting in Bordeaux.” Unwritten manuscript, School of Social Sciences, UCI, April 30.Google Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1979. “Mo Fiorina's Advice to Children and Other Subordinates.” Mathematics Magazine, Vol. 52, No. 5 (November), 292297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1982. “The Pure Theory of Elevators.” Mathematics Magazine, Vol, 55, No. 1 (January), 3037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1984. “Should You Brush Your Teeth on November 6, 1984?: A Rational Choice Perspective.” PS (Summer), 577580.Google Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1988. “The ‘Minimax Blame’ Model for Voter Choice: A Guide to the Perplexed.” PS (Summer), 8588.Google Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1989. “Finagle's Law and the Finagle Point, a New Solution Concept for Two-Candidate Competition in Spatial Voting Games Without a Core.” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 33, No. 2, 427454 (with Scott Feld, Guillermo Owen, and Bernard Grofman).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1992. “A Corollary to the Third Axiom of General Semantics.” Journal of Theoretical Politics, Vol. 4, No. 2 (April), 238240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1993. “The Political Economy of the Automobile: Four Approaches.” Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5 No 3 (July), 409412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuffle, A. 1997. “Why Democrats Shouldn't Vote and Probably Shouldn't Register Either (with acknowledgments to R. Erikson),” Journal of Theoretical Politics, Forthcoming (with Christian Collet).CrossRefGoogle Scholar