Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T08:07:27.977Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Game Theory, Political Economy, and the Evolving Study of War and Peace

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 November 2006

BRUCE BUENO DE MESQUITA
Affiliation:
New York University and Hoover Institution, Stanford University

Abstract

James Russell and Quincy Wright suggested in the Review in 1933 that the danger of conflict could be diminished by looking within states to discern what contributes to the risk of war. Revolutions in game theory technology and political economy modeling are helping to advance those goals. The combination of non-cooperative game theory as an analytic tool and the assumptions of political economy models about leaders' domestic interests and incentives offer a different explanation of international relations from that suggested by realist theories and other state-centric viewpoints. Together with more macro-level theorizing we gain insights into what makes some polities more prone to international conflict than others. By adding the micro-level, game theoretic investigation of domestic factors to the analytic repertoire we have now supplemented the aspects of received wisdom that are consistent with the record of history with explanations for puzzling facts about conflict that no longer seem anomalous.

Type
“THE EVOLUTION OF POLITICAL SCIENCE” ESSAYS
Copyright
© 2006 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “Inefficient Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 95 (September): 64561.Google Scholar
Babst Dean V. 1964. “Elective Government—A Force for Peace.” Wisconsin Sociologist 3 (1): 914.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, and George W. Downs. 2005. “The Rise of Sustainable Autocracy.” Foreign Affairs, 84 (September/October): 7786.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, and George W. Downs. 2006. “Intervention and Democracy.” International Organization 60 (July): 627649.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, James D. Morrow, Randolph M. Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 1999. “An Institutional Explanation of the Democratic Peace.” American Political Science Review 93 (December): 791807.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, James D. Morrow, Randolph M. Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 2004. “Testing Novel Implications from the Selectorate Theory of War.” World Politics 56 (April): 36388.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce, and David Lalman. 1992. War and Reason: Domestic and International Imperatives. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Chiozza Giacomo, and Hein E. Goemans. 2003. “Peace Through Insecurity: Tenure and International Conflict.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 47 (August): 44367.Google Scholar
Chiozza Giacomo, and Hein E. Goemans. 2004. “International Conflict and the Tenure of Leaders: Is War Still Ex Post Inefficient?American Journal of Political Science 48 (July): 60419.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville Alexis. 2000. Democracy in America. Trans. and ed. Harvey C. Mansfield and Delba Winthrop. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Dixon William. 1994. “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict.” American Political Science Review 88 (March): 1432.Google Scholar
Downs George W., and David M. Rocke. 1994. “Conflict, Agency, and Gambling for Resurrection.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (May): 36280.Google Scholar
Drezner Daniel W. 2004. “The Outsourcing Bogeyman.” Foreign Affairs 83 (May/June): 2234.Google Scholar
Easterly William. 2001. “Think Again: Debt ReliefForeign Policy 127 (November/December): 2026.Google Scholar
Easterly William. 2002. “The Cartel of Good Intentions.” Foreign Policy 131 (July/August): 4049.Google Scholar
Fearon James D. 1994. “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes.” American Political Science Review 88 (September): 57792.Google Scholar
Fearon James D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49 (Summer): 379414.Google Scholar
Fordham Benjamin. 1998a. “The Politics of Threat Perception and the Use of Force: A Political Economy Model of U.S. Uses of Force, 1949–1994.” International Studies Quarterly 42 (September): 56790.Google Scholar
Fordham Benjamin. 1998b. “Partisanship, Macroeconomic Policy, and U.S. Uses of Force, 1949–1994.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (October): 41839.Google Scholar
Gaddis John Lewis. 1992. “International Relations Theory and the End of the Cold War.” International Security 17 (Winter): 558.Google Scholar
Gaubatz Kurt Taylor. 1991. “Election Cycles and War.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35 (June): 212244.Google Scholar
Huth Paul K. 1996. Standing Your Ground: Territorial Disputes and International Conflict. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Kim Woosang, and James D. Morrow. 1992. “When Do Power Shifts Lead to War?American Journal of Political Science 36 (November): 896922.Google Scholar
Lake David, and Matthew A. Baum. 2001. “The Invisible Hand of Democracy: Political Control and the Provision of Public Services.” Comparative Political Studies 34 (August): 587621.Google Scholar
Lake David, and Matthew A. Baum. 2003. “The Political Economy of Growth: Democracy and Human Capital.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (April): 33347.Google Scholar
Maoz Zeev, and Bruce Russett. 1993. “Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace, 1946–1986.” American Political Science Review 87 (September): 62438.Google Scholar
McGuire Martin, and Mancur Olson 1996. “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule.” Journal of Economic Literature 34 (March): 7296.Google Scholar
Milner Helen V. 1998. “Rationalizing Politics: The Emerging Synthesis of International, American, and Comparative Politics.” International Organization 52 (Autumn): 75986.Google Scholar
Morgan T. Clifton, and Sally Campbell. 1991. “Domestic Structure, Decision Constraints and War: So Why Kant Democracies Fight?Journal of Conflict Resolution 35 (June): 187211.Google Scholar
Morgenthau Hans J. 1978. Politics among Nations, 5th ed. Revised. Boston: McGraw-Hill.
Morrow James D. 1991. “Electoral and Congressional Incentives and Arms Control.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35 (June): 24363.Google Scholar
Morrow James D., Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Randolph M. Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 2006. “Selection Institutions and War Aims.” Economics of Governance 7 (1): 3152.Google Scholar
Nincic Miroslav. 1997. “Loss Aversion and the Domestic Context of Military Intervention.” Political Research Quarterly 50 (March): 97120.Google Scholar
Niou Emerson, Peter Ordeshook, and Gregory Rose. 1989. The Balance of Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Niou Emerson, and Peter Ordeshook. 1990. “Stability in Anarchic International Systems.” American Political Science Review 84 (December): 120734.Google Scholar
Niskanen William A. 1997. “Autocratic, Democratic, and Optimal Government.” Economic Inquiry 35 (July): 46479.Google Scholar
Powell Robert. 1993. “Guns, Butter, and Anarchy.” American Political Science Review 87 (March): 11532.Google Scholar
Powell Robert. 1994. “Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate.” International Organization 48 (Spring): 31344.Google Scholar
Powell Robert. 1996. “Uncertainty, Shifting Power, and Appeasement.” American Political Science Review 90 (December): 74964.Google Scholar
Powell Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategy in International Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Reiter Dan, and Allan C. Stam III. 1998. “Democracy and Battlefield Military Effectiveness.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (June): 25977.Google Scholar
Reiter Dan, and Allan C. Stam III. 2002. Democracies at War. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Russell James T., and Quincy Wright. 1933. “National Attitudes on the Far Eastern Controversy.” American Political Science Review 27 (August): 55576.Google Scholar
Schultz Kenneth A. 1998. “Domestic Opposition and Signaling in International Crises.” American Political Science Review 92 (December): 829844.Google Scholar
Schultz Kenneth A. 2001. Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Smith Alastair. 1996. “Diversionary Foreign Policy in Democratic Systems.” International Studies Quarterly 40 (March): 13353.Google Scholar
Smith Alastair. 2004. Election Timing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Thucydides. 1959. History of the Peloponnesian War. 3 vols. Trans. T. Hobbes. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Vasquez John A. 1993. The War Puzzle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Vasquez John A. 1995. “Why Do Neighbors Fight? Territoriality, Proximity, or Interactions.” Journal of Peace Research 32 (August): 27793.Google Scholar
Vasquez John A. 1997. “The Realist Paradigm and Degenerative versus Progressive Research Programs: An Appraisal of Neotraditional Research on Waltz's Balancing Proposition.” American Political Science Review 91 (December): 899913.Google Scholar
Vasquez John A. 2000. What Do We Know about War? Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.
Waltz Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Werner Suzanne. 1996. “Absolute and Limited War: The Possibilities of Foreign Imposed Regime Change.” International Interactions 22 (January–March): 6788.Google Scholar
Wintrobe Ronald. 1990. “The Tinpot and the Totalitarian: An Economic Analysis of Dictatorship.” American Political Science Review 84 (September): 84972.Google Scholar
Wittman Donald. 1979. “How a War Ends: A Rational Model Approach.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 23 (December): 74363.Google Scholar