Elsevier

Economics of Transportation

Volume 13, March 2018, Pages 36-47
Economics of Transportation

Decentralization and spillovers: A new role for transportation infrastructure

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecotra.2017.09.002Get rights and content

Abstract

Inter-regional spillovers of local public goods are the main cause of decentralization failure. Assuming that the quality of transportation infrastructure policy affects the strength of inter-regional spillovers, we compare a one-step scheduling design, in which all policies are chosen simultaneously, with a two-step scheduling design, in which transportation infrastructure policy is used to influence local public goods policies. We show that decentralization failure could be partially solved with scheduling design. When regional governments correctly schedule their policies, citizens benefit from the same level of public goods but with lower taxes. Moreover, the two-step scheduling design results in a lower quality of transportation infrastructure and a higher intensity of local public goods. However, the overproduction of local public goods with positive externalities cannot be excluded.

Introduction

The regional economic literature has extensively discussed the link between the quality of transportation infrastructure and welfare (Krugman, 1991, Fujita et al., 1999). Despite different views and opinions, scholars have both theoretically and empirically demonstrated that the quality of transportation infrastructure has a positive impact on both inter-regional trade and regional growth (Martin and Rogers, 1995, Martin and Ottaviano, 1999, Melo et al., 2013). However, less attention has been paid to the impact of transportation infrastructure on inter-regional spillovers, especially those related to the provision of local public goods. In this paper we describe the impact of transportation infrastructure on inter-regional spillovers of local public goods.

Since institutional design affects both the intensity of local public goods and the quality of transportation infrastructure (Qian and Roland, 1998, Lizzeri and Persico, 2001, Boadway and Shah, 2009, Proost et al., 2011), it is important to study both policies within the same framework, and within the current debate on decentralization. The understanding that decentralization is optimal only in the absence of inter-regional spillovers is a milestone in the literature on public economics (Oates, 1972, Besley and Coate, 2003). Decentralization fails when regional governments only consider the local effects of internal policies in their own region, and several scholars have shown that the centralization of power is able to solve the problem of inter-regional spillovers efficiently.1

In this paper we assume a set of public transportation infrastructure that links two (homogeneous) regions. People living in one region can use the transportation infrastructure to benefit from the local public good of the other region. This implies that there are inter-regional spillovers of local public good, but that the strength of the spillovers is affected by the quality of the transportation infrastructure. We assume that welfare has a private and a public component, as will become clear below. To improve welfare, regional governments could invest in either their own local public good or the quality of transportation infrastructure.

We principally compare one- and two-step scheduling designs. In the former, the quality of the transportation infrastructure and the provision of local public goods are determined simultaneously. In the latter, the quality of the transportation infrastructure is determined in the first step, and the provision of local public goods in the second step.

By comparing the two scheduling designs both a lower quality of transportation infrastructure and a higher intensity of local public goods emerge in the two-step scheduling design. Moreover, we show that the scheduling design does not affect the public component of welfare but only impacts on the private component of welfare. Finally, assuming positive externalities, overproduction cannot be excluded when the quality of the transportation infrastructure affects the inter-regional spillovers of local public goods.

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature. Section 3 develops the model and derives the public-sector decisions for various institutional designs. Section 4 shows the main results on efficiency and provides a numerical illustration of the policy mix. Some extensions of the model are presented in section 5, and conclusions are drawn in section 6.

Section snippets

Literature

This paper adds to the literature on transportation infrastructure and decentralization (for a survey, see De Borger and Proost, 2012a, De Borger and Proost, 2012b, De Borger and Proost, 2015). Scholars focus on transportation infrastructure mainly because it has specific features and various kinds of spillovers (e.g. traffic congestion and smog) that are unlike other goods.2

The model

We consider a country composed of two identical regions, i=1,2, in which regional governments define both the intensity of the local public goods (one in each region) and the quality of transportation infrastructure (between the regions). Let gi>0 be the intensity of the local public good in region i; ti>0 the quality of inter-regional transportation infrastructure in region i; and S>0 the strength of positive inter-regional spillovers of the local public good.4

Discussion

In this section, we analyze the implications of one- and two-step scheduling decision-making on the quality of transport infrastructure, the intensity of local public goods, and the level of the components of welfare. Proposition 4 describes the impact on the transportation infrastructure, t:

Proposition 4

The two-step scheduling design has the lowest quality of transportation infrastructure.

Proof

From the first equation in the systems (8) and (17), we show that ugB,tB<ugD,tD. Using ug,t<0, we find that ugD,tD

Extensions

In this section, we describe three additional institutional designs. First, we assume a two-step scheduling design where the governments negotiate between them and use inter-regional transfers to achieve horizontal coordination. Second, we assume asymmetry between the regions’ institutional designs, i.e. one region adopts the one-step scheduling design and the other region adopts the two-step scheduling design. Finally, we study a two-step scheduling design where the timing of policies is

Conclusions

The public goods offered by governments generally have spillovers. Local public goods are public goods that can be used either by the residents of a local community or by the mobility of the non-residents.13

References (94)

  • B. De Borger et al.

    Congestion and tax competition in a parallel network

    Eur. Econ. Rev.

    (2005)
  • B. De Borger et al.

    Strategic investment and pricing decisions in a congested transport corridor

    J. Urban Econ.

    (2007)
  • D. Epple et al.

    Competition between private and public schools: testing stratification and pricing predictions

    J. Public Econ.

    (2004)
  • C.M. Fung et al.

    Can we decentralize transport taxes and infrastructure supply

    Econ. Transp.

    (2017)
  • S. Grahn-Voorneveld

    The effects of decentralized capacity decisions for congested self-financed roads

    Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract.

    (2013)
  • M. Joanis

    Shared accountability and partial decentralization in local public good provision

    J. Dev. Econ.

    (2014)
  • C.R. Kuehnhanss et al.

    Choice in politics: equivalency framing in economic policy decisions and the influence of expertise

    Eur. J. Polit. Econ.

    (2015)
  • O. Lorz et al.

    On the endogenous allocation of decision powers in federal structures

    J. Urban Econ.

    (2005)
  • Z.C. Li et al.

    Transit technology investment and selection under urban population volatility: a real option perspective

    Transp. Res. Part B Methodol.

    (2015)
  • S. Mandell et al.

    Why truck distance taxes are contagious and drive fuel taxes to the bottom

    J. Urban Econ.

    (2016)
  • P. Martin et al.

    Industrial location and public infrastructure

    J. Int. Econ.

    (1995)
  • P. Martin et al.

    Growing locations: Industry location in a model of endogenous growth

    Eur. Econ. Rev.

    (1999)
  • P.C. Melo et al.

    The productivity of transport infrastructure investment: a meta-analysis of empirical evidence

    Reg. Sci. Urban Econ.

    (2013)
  • S. Mun et al.

    Pricing and investment of cross-border transport infrastructure

    Reg. Sci. Urban Econ.

    (2010)
  • N. Piyatrapoomi et al.

    Framework for investment decision-making under risk and uncertainty for infrastructure asset management

    Res. Transp. Econ.

    (2004)
  • S. Proost et al.

    When are subsidies to trans-European network projects justified?

    Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract.

    (2011)
  • S. Proost et al.

    Urban transport pricing reform with two levels of government: a case study of Brussels

    Transp. Policy

    (2006)
  • M. Redoano et al.

    The political economy of policy centralization: direct versus representative democracy

    J. Public Econ.

    (2004)
  • A. Russo

    Voting on road congestion policy

    Reg. Sci. Urban Econ.

    (2013)
  • J.M. Saphores et al.

    Uncertainty and the timing of an urban congestion relief investment: the no-land case

    J. Urban Econ.

    (2006)
  • B. Ubbels et al.

    Governmental competition in road charging and capacity choice

    Reg. Sci. Urban Econ.

    (2008)
  • M. Wardman

    A review of the British evidence on time and service quality valuations

    Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev.

    (2001)
  • R. Welch

    Legitimacy of rural government in the new governance environment

    J. Rural Stud.

    (2002)
  • J. Westin et al.

    How to decide on regional infrastructure to achieve intra-regional acceptability and inter-regional consensus?

    Pap. Reg. Sci.

    (2012)
  • Y. Wu et al.

    An integrated programming model for storage management and vehicle scheduling at container terminals

    Res. Transp. Econ.

    (2013)
  • M. Alderighi et al.

    Political Competition, Power Allocation and Welfare in Unitary and Federal Systems

    (2014)
  • A. Alesina et al.

    Economic integration and political disintegration

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2000)
  • T.B. Bjørner

    Any need for coordination of policies towards transit traffic with a negative local externality?

    Environ. Resour. Econ.

    (1996)
  • R. Boadway et al.

    Fiscal Federalism: Principles and Practices of Multiorder Governance

    (2009)
  • E. Bond

    Transportation infrastructure investments and trade liberalization

    Jpn. Econ. Rev.

    (2006)
  • J.K. Brueckner

    Fiscal decentralization with distortionary taxation: Tiebout vs. tax competition

    Int. Tax Public Finance

    (2004)
  • J.K. Brueckner

    Decentralized road investment and pricing in a monocentric, multi-jurisdictional city: Efficiency with spillovers

    Natl. Tax J.

    (2015)
  • S. Christopherson et al.

    Regional resilience: theoretical and empirical perspectives

    Camb. J. Reg.

    (2010)
  • R.D. Congleton

    Asymmetric federalism and the political economy of decentralization

  • B. De Borger et al.

    Policies to Reduce Traffic Externalities in Cities, Center for Economic Studies - Discussion Papers ces12.10, Centrum Voor Economische Studiën

    (2012)
  • B. De Borger et al.

    The political economy of pricing and capacity decisions for congestible local public goods in a federal state

    Int. Tax Public Finance

    (2016)
  • J. Eliasson et al.

    Do cost-benefit analyses influence transport investment decisions?

    Transp. Rev.

    (2011)
  • Cited by (7)

    • Institutional design, political competition and spillovers

      2020, Regional Science and Urban Economics
    • Spatial structure convergence of China's transportation system

      2019, Research in Transportation Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Section 7 offers the conclusions, and section 8 proposes the discussion. Some of the related literature focuses on the spillover effect of transportation structure (Cohen, 2010; Feder, 2018; Wang & Chen, 2015). Laird, Nellthorp, and Mackie (2005) show that an optimized transportation structure can produce large transportation network effects, thus effectively improving economic efficiency.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    I thank Marco Alderighi, Jan K. Brueckner, Alberto Iozzi, Claudio Piga and Federico Revelli for their helpful discussions and useful suggestions. I am also grateful for comments from the participants who attended the XVII Conference of the Italian Association of Transport Economics and Logistics and the Regional Studies Association Annual Conference 2016. Moreover, I would like to thank both the anonymous reviewers for their helpful and constructive comments that greatly contributed to improving the final version of the paper and the Guest Editor Bruno De Borger for his generous comments and strong support during the review process. However, any shortcomings in the paper are entirely my responsibility.

    View full text