Elsevier

Economic Modelling

Volume 25, Issue 3, May 2008, Pages 485-498
Economic Modelling

Population ageing and intertemporal consumption: Representative agent versus social planner

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2007.07.007Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper examines the optimal path of consumption over time in the context of population ageing. Older age groups are considered to have relatively greater ‘needs’, resulting for example from additional health costs. These differences give rise to the concept of the ‘equivalent number of persons’, as distinct from the population size. Emphasis is given to the difference between a framework involving a representative agent and one in which plans are made by a social planner. The precise conditions under which consumption growth paths are the same under the representative agent and the social planner are established. This equivalence is found to hold only in the case where the social planner's value judgements are such that individuals are considered to be the appropriate unit of analysis. An alternative assumption, in which equivalent persons are regarded as the appropriate units, is found to give rise to a different optimal consumption path. Numerical examples demonstrate the relative orders of magnitude for a range of parameter values. The differences are found to be potentially important. The choice of appropriate consumption units – individuals or equivalent persons – is far from arbitrary since it involves possibly conflicting value judgements. This choice has implications for policies designed to influence the optimal saving rate, such as superannuation policy and the fiscal balance.

Introduction

The aim of this paper is to examine the optimal path of aggregate consumption in the context of population ageing, where older age groups are considered to have relatively greater ‘needs’, resulting for example from additional health costs. These differences give rise to the concept of the ‘equivalent number of persons’, as distinct from the population size. Many models in this context employ the concept of a hypothetical representative agent who is assumed to be infinitely lived and who has the characteristics (that is, the ‘needs’) of an average person in the population in each year. The present paper compares the representative agent approach with an alternative in which the optimal aggregate consumption stream is determined by a social planner who is considered to maximise a social welfare, or evaluation, function defined over the same time horizon. The value judgements of the social planner are made explicit in the form of the welfare function.

Using an individualistic and additive welfare function, total consumption per equivalent person contributes to social welfare in each period. In this preliminary investigation, individuals are considered to differ only by age and hence the planner is not concerned with inequality. One important issue relates to the choice of consumption unit in weighting the consumption per equivalent person in each period. Two cases are examined here — the use of individuals and of equivalent persons. Each of these cases has sensible, but possibly inconsistent, welfare rationales.

The analysis is motivated by the extensive debate regarding the implications of population ageing, and the potential for tax smoothing to achieve an optimal time path of aggregate consumption. The idea that governments should smooth the tax burden over time was first advanced by Barro (1979), who showed that, in a deterministic setting, a flat path of the tax rate over time would minimize the distortions to behaviour arising from taxation. A key insight is that the tax rate must not distort intertemporal consumption choices and must therefore tax consumption at the same rate through time in the long run (Chamley, 1986).1 Therefore the path of the ratio of optimal income tax to GDP depends on the optimal path of consumption. Consumption smoothing implies a varying ratio of consumption to income and therefore a varying path of the optimal income tax to GDP ratio. In addition, because the optimal consumption path implies an optimal saving path, the analysis in the present paper has implications for policies designed to affect optimal saving such as superannuation policy and the fiscal balance. It is shown that these policy implications depend on value judgements in the evaluation of social welfare.2

The dominant framework for macroeconomic modelling is based on the behaviour of representative agents because the outcomes can be traced to microeconomic foundations. These agents can have either infinite lives, single period lives leading over time to a dynasty of individuals, or finite multi-period lives which imply a number of overlapping generations at a point in time. The origin of this framework was provided by Ramsey (1928) who assumed an infinitely lived individual. It is widely used in modelling economic growth and macroeconomic aggregates. Seminal expositions of a range of these models include, for example, Barro and Sala-I-Martin (1995) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996). All large scale multi-sector, multi-region models (computable general equilibrium models) used to model national and world economies are based on the behaviour of representative agents. Examples include the OECD's MINILINK model, the IMF's MULTIMOD model and the European Commission's QUEST model.3 A common feature of these models is that the agents optimise intertemporally and this feature is the focus of attention below.

However, the representative agent framework has been subject to a number of strong criticisms; see, for example, Kirman (1992). Also, it has limitations in social welfare analysis of public policies such as fiscal policy where it is useful to know the socially optimal outcome. This is because the representative agent model generates Pareto optimal aggregate outcomes only under strict assumptions; see, for example, Lewbel (1989). For this reason it is sometimes assumed that the economy is run by a benevolent social planner or decision maker.

This paper contributes to the literature by identifying a source of difference between the representative agent and social planner paradigms in the particular context of population ageing. The difference turns out to depend on whether the social planner is concerned with individuals or equivalent persons in evaluating social welfare.

The basic framework of analysis, involving a difference between the number of people and the equivalent population size, is described in section 2. The optimal consumption path of a representative agent is examined in section 3. Section 4 turns to the optimal path determined by a social planner, where particular attention is given to the choice of the unit of analysis. Some comparisons are made in section 5, followed by numerical examples in section 6. Brief conclusions are in section 7.

Section snippets

The basic framework

This section outlines the basic framework of analysis, involving population growth arising from differential growth rates across age groups. The number of individuals aged i in year t is denoted Ni,t, so the total population in year t is Nt=iNi,t. Individuals of different ages are assumed to have different ‘basic needs’, reflected in an equivalence size, si. This is similar in some ways to the type of adult equivalence scale used in the measurement of poverty and inequality. A higher value of s

The representative agent

Over time, the average age of the population, and hence its average ‘equivalent size’, changes. Consider a ‘representative agent’, who in each period is regarded as having the average age of the population and hence an equivalent size equal to the average equivalent size of the population. This artificial representative person is assumed to maximise a utility function, specified over an infinite horizon, which has as arguments the level of consumption in each period, ct, expressed as a ratio of

The social planner

This section considers the optimal consumption path determined by a social planner whose aim is to maximise an additive social welfare function defined over an infinite horizon. As it has been assumed that individuals alive at any time differ only in their ages, the social planner has no concern for within-period inequalities. Section 4.1 discusses the basic form of the welfare function, and examines the precise conditions under which welfare can be regarded as a function of the ratio of

Some comparisons

The previous sections have derived alternative Euler equations governing the optimal consumption path of the economy. The form of the Euler equation for an infinitely lived representative agent, having in each period the average equivalent size of the population, was found to be the same as that for a social planner who regards the individual as the unit of analysis, or weight, in the social welfare function.11

Numerical examples

This section considers whether the difference between the two approaches – using individuals or equivalent persons as units – is important. Numerical examples are given, and sensitivity analyses are reported for alternative values of β and projections of p  n using Australian data for the period 2004–2050. Subsection 6.1 examines population growth and the associated changes in the equivalent population size, using a flexible specification for the variation in si with age. The sensitivity of the

Conclusions

This paper has examined the optimal path of consumption over time in the context of population ageing. Emphasis was given to the difference between a framework involving a representative agent and one in which plans are made by a social planner. The precise conditions under which consumption growth paths are the same under the representative agent and the social planner were established. This equivalence was found to hold only in the case where the social planner's value judgements are such

References (22)

  • A.B. Atkinson

    On the measurement of inequality

    Journal of Economic Theory

    (1970)
  • Australian Government
  • J. Banks et al.

    Equivalence scale relativities revisited

    Economic Journal

    (1994)
  • R. Barro

    On the determination of public debt

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1979)
  • R. Barro et al.

    Economic Growth

    (1995)
  • C. Chamley

    Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives

    Econometrica

    (1986)
  • J. Creedy

    Evaluating policy: welfare weights and value judgements

  • J. Creedy et al.

    Adult equivalence scales, inequality and poverty

    New Zealand Economic Papers

    (2005)
  • D.M. Cutler et al.

    Rising inequality? Changes in the distribution of income and consumption in the 1980s

    American Economic Review

    (1992)
  • A. Decoster et al.

    Weighting with individuals, equivalent individuals or not weighting at all: does it matter empirically?

  • U. Ebert

    Social welfare when needs differ: an axiomatic approach

    Economica

    (1997)
  • Cited by (7)

    • How does population aging affect household carbon emissions? Evidence from Chinese urban and rural areas

      2021, Energy Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      The increasing number of aging people in China, caused by increased life expectancy, causes more demand for products of aging industries, and therefore leads to an increase in household carbon emissions. In addition to the increase in residential income, residents are more likely to increase the proportion of enjoyable consumption and medical services expenditures, which increases urban household carbon emissions (Creedy and Guest, 2008; de Meijer et al., 2013). When urban population aging exceeds the threshold, with further increasing population aging, the population size stabilizes, and the increase in life expectancy becomes the main cause of population aging.

    • Accounting for household heterogeneity in general equilibrium economic growth models

      2012, Energy Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      In Section 2, we start with reviewing the conventional calibration of preference coefficients and labor supply to the benchmark data in a CGE model. Next this approach is extended to the case with possible time variations in household characteristics (see also the discussion in Creedy and Guest, 2008). The “expected” consumption shares and labor productivities are calculated based on the projected population values (for an alternative method of calculating time-varying consumption shares of the representative household, as a function of per capita income with regression-based coefficients, see Paltsev et al., 2005).

    • How does health status affect marginal utility of consumption? Evidence from China

      2020, International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health
    • The effect of population age structure on economic growth in Iran

      2011, International Research Journal of Finance and Economics
    • Tax and transfer tensions: Designing direct tax structures

      2011, Tax and transfer tensions: Designing direct tax structures
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text