Elsevier

Applied Energy

Volume 167, 1 April 2016, Pages 34-43
Applied Energy

Modeling environmental policy with and without abatement substitution: A tradeoff between economics and environment?

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.01.031Get rights and content

Highlights

  • A set of optimal emissions taxes are computed and their implications are tested.

  • Emissions taxes reduce environmental damages by nearly 50% in all regions.

  • Emissions taxes lead to welfare gains in all regions except low-income countries.

  • Production in rich countries is more adversely affected due to carbon taxes.

  • There is a tradeoff between economics and environment due to carbon taxes.

Abstract

This study proposes a set of optimal emission taxes that could be used to fully internalize environmental externalities. Carbon fees are computed for low-income economies, lower-middle-income economies, upper-middle-income economies, high-income economies, China and the United States. Subsequently, the implementation of these emission taxes is evaluated under two different scenarios; one assuming abatement substitution and the other relaxing this assumption. Estimated damages and abatement from various sectors lie between 0.0003 to 0.021 and 0.001 to 0.012 lb per dollar output respectively. Optimal pollution taxes per dollar output range as high as 2.8% for heavy manufacturing in the high income countries, and as low as 0.01% in the service sectors of the low income countries. On the impacts of these taxes, the study produces evidence that, whether abatement substitution is present or not, production in low-income economies would be less adversely affected due to carbon taxes relative to high-income countries. In addition, the emissions taxes reduce environmental damages by nearly 50% in all regions. Worldwide welfare gains from internalizing negative externalities when no abatement substitution is present is about three times the welfare gains in the presence of abatement substitution. Although these results imply a sort of tradeoff between the economics of production and environment, improved environmental benefits due to carbon taxes seem to outweigh the deterioration in economic activities; and as such, welfare improves in general.

Introduction

A number of environmental policies have been instigated following the Kyoto Protocol and the UNFCCC [1], [2]. One of such topics in the debate relates to the mechanism for GHG abatement. Even though the issue of mitigating climate change by means of reduction in GHG emissions has been generally accepted, controversy still hangs over the specific abatement mechanism. For instance, the literature has produced three popular mechanisms for abatement, namely: price-based, quantity-based and command-and-control mechanisms [3], [4], [5], [6], [7].

According to Nordhaus [4], the command-and-control mechanism is inefficient and therefore not recommended as the government uses this mechanism as a tool for applying force and utilizing administrative means to reduce GHG. On the other hand, the quantity-based mechanism, or cap-and-trade system, is a way of granting various stakeholders or participants a limitation on emission permits and allowing for the trading of such permits in the market [8], [9], [10]. The main advantage of the cap-and-control system, as pointed out by Zhu and Wei [11], is the possibility of directly controlling reduction levels in the face of uncertain carbon prices. Because participants have the choice of freely buying and selling, it is possible for them to achieve the lowest possible cost, and hence, a lower cost for the broader society. This implies that participants would sell excess permits if it is cheaper for them to reduce emissions. On the contrary, participants would buy permits and avoid reductions where the cost of reductions is higher. The resulting effect is for total emissions to equal the amount of permits, thus, only reductions of the lowest cost will be undertaken. The third and perhaps most popular mechanism, the price-based mechanism or carbon tax as it is usually called, is one in which a fixed payment per unit CO2 emissions is made [12]. With a carbon tax, the level of emissions reduction is determined indirectly by means of directly controlling the carbon price. Like the cap-and-trade system, the carbon tax is also cost-effective since emitters would only choose to reduce emissions if the cost of doing so falls below the carbon tax.

Even though political concerns would favor the use of a quantity-based approach to abatement, a lot of researchers, especially those applying cost-benefit analyses, have documented carbon tax as more efficient.1 Indeed, a couple of studies have shown that the welfare gains from implementing an optimal carbon tax is at least five times higher than expected gains from an optimal cap-and-trade policy [4], [6], [7]. Moreover, estimates by Sokolov et al. [13] show the possibility of a 50% rise in global temperature by 2100 compared with the 20th century levels if mitigation measures, driven by carbon taxes are not implemented. Therefore, a study of this nature which focuses specifically on carbon taxes is relevant for developing more realistic climate policies and for providing insights on the connections between energy prices and carbon mitigation solutions in terms of carbon capture and storage (see [14]. Moreover, such an analysis would serve as a valuable platform for evaluating the options value to renewable energy development [15], [16], [17] and for evaluating the effectiveness of renewable energy as a substitute for nonrenewable energy [18], [19].

Indeed, the role of optimal carbon pricing cannot be overemphasized. However, because it is difficult to find a single database which consists of various carbon costs; and factoring in the fact that climate damages are difficult to measure, most carbon taxes are usually less than optimal [20], [21], [22], [23]. This implies that further evidence on the modeling of economically appropriate carbon taxes and the impacts of their implementation is necessary and would bring more insights and clarity to the literature. In addition, the limitation of relevant data has compelled many researchers to rely on theoretical and simulated tax rates, which may or may not be realistic in terms of context conditions. As a result, this could point policy makers in the wrong direction. Furthermore, as we discuss in Section 2, the literature seems to produce mixed evidences. While some authors argue that the implementation of carbon taxes can provide economic and environmental gains, other studies argue otherwise. Giving the uncertainties surrounding the economic appropriateness of the kind of carbon taxes used in the vast majority of these studies, further insights into research of this kind becomes a necessity. Another feature of the present study that distinguishes it from previous work in the literature is the fact that we have modeled environmental policy while allowing for a more realistic abatement possibility. The study also allows for comparison with a scenario in which no abatement substitution is possible, thus, increasing the richness of the analysis.

Finally, unlike bulk of the literature which considers country- or region-specific scenarios,2 this study aims at providing a more global perspective on environmental policy modeling. Since the willingness to pay for improvement in environmental quality and the level of income are correlated, our analysis breaks out the world’s two largest economies, China and the United States; grouping all other world regions in accordance with the World Bank (2012)3 list of countries, such as: low-income, lower-middle income, upper-middle income and high-income countries. Employing output and expenditure data from the GTAP database as well as abatement and emissions data from industries in the United States, optimal emissions fees are first computed for China and the United States, and then for the four different income categorizations (i.e., low-income, lower-middle-income, upper-middle-income and high-income). Subsequently, the economic and environmental impacts of implementing the constructed carbon fees are assessed.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 provides a review of the relevant literature. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 explains the various methods. Section 5 presents the results and discussions. Section 6 concludes.

Section snippets

Relevant literature

In order to control emissions, carbon tax policies or related measures have been carried out in a number of countries especially European countries and Australia. North and South America, Asia and even African countries are beginning to show deep interest in instigating carbon pricing measures. There is a vast literature so far, ranging from studies which compare the performance of carbon taxes with other abatement mechanisms to studies which discuss the trends in carbon taxes and then to

The data

The present study utilizes data on toxic emissions, abatement cost, sectoral output, government expenditures by sector, and private expenditures by sector. In this study, government expenditures are calculated as government imports and domestic purchases at agents’ prices. Similarly, private expenditures are calculated as household imports and domestic purchases at agents’ prices. Data on linearly risk weighted emissions per million dollars of output, taken form Lucas et al. [79], are based on

Methodologies

In this section, the various methods employed in our study are documented; beginning with the computation of optimal emissions fees, shocks that mimic change in emission taxes, welfare changes, and environmental quality. The procedures are based on Hertel [24].

Results and discussion

This section reports the main results from the study. It begins with the estimated damages and abatement per unit output and then presents a set of constructed emission taxes. Finally, the implications of implementing the constructed emission fees are evaluated in terms of impacts on production, welfare, and environmental quality.

Conclusions

The present study utilizes relevant data to compute a set of emissions fees that could be used to reduce the damages caused by industrial pollution. The approach we use allows for the setting of pollution taxes (which differ between sectors due to differences in carbon intensities) at their economically appropriate level. Correlation between the willingness to pay for improvement in environmental quality and the level of income necessitated breaking out China and the United States; and grouping

Acknowledgement

The paper is supported by Newhuadu Business School Research Fund, the Grant for Collaborative Innovation Center for Energy Economics and Energy Policy (No: 1260-Z0210011), Xiamen University Flourish Plan Special Funding (No:1260-Y07200), and Ministry of Education(Grant No. 10JBG013).

References (81)

  • P.K. Wesseh et al.

    Output and substitution elasticities of energy and implications for renewable energy expansion in the ECOWAS region

    Energy Policy

    (2016)
  • H.-B. Duan et al.

    Optimal carbon taxes in carbon-constrained China: a logistic-induced energy economic hybrid model

    Energy

    (2014)
  • B.C.C. Van der Zwaan et al.

    Endogenous technological change in climate change modeling

    Energy Econ

    (2002)
  • A. Manne et al.

    MERGE: a model for evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies

    Energy Policy

    (1995)
  • A. Zakeri et al.

    Carbon pricing versus emissions trading: a supply chain planning perspective

    Int J Prod Econ

    (2015)
  • M. Hoel et al.

    Depletion of fossil fuels and the impact of global warming

    Resour Energy Econ

    (1996)
  • V. Bosetti et al.

    What should we expect from innovation? A model-based assessment of the environmental and mitigation cost implications of climate-related R&D

    Energy Econ

    (2011)
  • T. Alton et al.

    Introducing carbon taxes in South Africa

    Appl Energy

    (2014)
  • Z.X. Zhang

    Macroeconomic effect of CO2 emission limits: a computable general equilibrium analysis for China

    J Policy Model

    (1998)
  • A.Y. Al-Abdullah

    The Carbon-tax debate

    Appl Energy

    (1999)
  • T. Tezuka et al.

    Carbon tax for subsidizing photovoltaic power generation systems and its effect on carbon dioxide emissions

    Appl Energy

    (2002)
  • M. Wier et al.

    Are CO2 taxes regressive? Evidence from the Danish experience

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2005)
  • D. Fullerton et al.

    The general equilibrium incidence of environmental taxes

    J Public Econ

    (2007)
  • Q.M. Liang et al.

    Carbon taxation policy in China: how to protect energy- and trade-intensive sectors?

    J Policy

    (2007)
  • C.Y. Lu et al.

    A CGE analysis to study the impacts of energy investment on economic growth and carbon dioxide emission: a case study of Shaanxi province in western China

    Energy

    (2010)
  • Q.M. Liang et al.

    Distributional impacts of taxing carbon in China: results from the CEEPA model

    Appl Energy

    (2012)
  • G. Fang et al.

    The impacts of carbon tax on energy intensity and economic growth – a dynamic evolution analysis on the case of China

    Appl Energy

    (2013)
  • Y. Dissou et al.

    Can carbon taxes be progressive?

    Energy Econ

    (2014)
  • Y. Liu et al.

    The Economic impact of different carbon tax revenue recycling schemes in China: a model-based scenario analysis

    Appl Energy

    (2015)
  • Z.-M. Chen et al.

    Environmental externality of coal use in China: Welfare effect and tax regulation

    Appl Energy

    (2015)
  • W. Li et al.

    The research on setting a unified interval of carbon price benchmark in the national carbon trading market of China

    Appl ‘Energy

    (2015)
  • P.K. Wesseh et al.

    Causal independence between energy consumption and economic growth in Liberia: evidence from a non-parametric bootstrapped causality test

    Energy Policy

    (2012)
  • B. Lin et al.

    Energy consumption and economic growth in South Africa reexamined: A nonparametric testing approach

    Renew Sustain Energy Rev

    (2014)
  • B. Lin et al.

    What causes price volatility and regime shifts in the natural gas market

    Energy

    (2013)
  • B. Lin et al.

    Oil price fluctuation, volatility spillover and the Ghanaian equity market: Implication for portfolio management and hedging effectiveness

    Energy Econ

    (2014)
  • T. Roughgarden et al.

    Climate change policy: quantifying uncertain- ties for damages and optimal carbon taxes

    Energy Policy

    (1999)
  • R. Brannlund et al.

    Carbon tax simulations using a household demand model

    Eur Econ Rev

    (2004)
  • K. Van’t Veld et al.

    Carbon sequestration or abatement? The effect of rising carbon prices on the optimal portfolio of greenhouse-gas mitigation strategies

    J Environ Econ Manage

    (2005)
  • R.S.J. Tol

    Welfare specifications and optimal control of climate change:an application of fund

    Energy Econ

    (2002)
  • T.A. Persson et al.

    Allocation of CO2 emission permits: economic incentives for emission reductions in developing countries

    Energy Policy

    (2006)
  • Cited by (0)

    View full text