Elsevier

Research Policy

Volume 36, Issue 2, March 2007, Pages 157-171
Research Policy

Open source software development—Just another case of collective invention?

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2006.10.004Get rights and content

Abstract

Do open source software (OSS) projects represent a new innovation model? Under what conditions can it be employed in other contexts? “Collective invention” regimes usually ended when a dominant design emerged. This is not the case with OSS. Firstly, the OSS community developed the institutional innovation of OSS licenses enabling OSS software to survive as a common property. Secondly, these licenses are mainly enforced by pro-socially motivated contributors. We characterize the conditions under which OSS communities develop and sustain pro-social commitments. We point out the vulnerability of these conditions to developments in patent legislation.

Introduction

Open source software projects are examples of an innovation model, which relies neither on the price system nor on formal hierarchies nor on alliance agreements. Does the production of open source software (OSS) represent a new model, and under what conditions can it be used in other contexts? OSS is a term for software published under licenses that do not give any private intellectual property rights to the developers. To a large extent, contributions to these projects are made by voluntary, non-paid members of the OSS community. These members invest their own private resources into a public good.

A look at history shows that OSS production seems to be similar to other examples in the past and present that can be summarized by the term “collective invention” (Allen, 1983). In the second half of the 19th century, iron-making companies in Britain's Cleveland district willingly shared their innovations in blast furnace design. Other examples include the enhancement of steam engine design after 1800 (Nuvolari, 2002) and the search for a dominant design in the flat panel display industry (Spencer, 2003). According to Von Hippel and von Krogh (2003), OSS represents a novel innovation model, which they call the “private-collective” model. It shares many similarities with the “collective invention” model. However, most collective invention regimes did not survive after the development of a dominant design (e.g. Meyer, 2002), while OSS is still alive and well in such a phase of the innovation process.

This paper addresses two research questions: (1) Why did “collective invention” usually not survive after the development of a dominant design? (2) What are the conditions that enabled the OSS collective invention to do just that? Answering these questions can help determine under what conditions “collective invention” or the “private-collective” innovation model can exist and be employed in other contexts than OSS (see e.g. Benkler, 2002, Benkler, 2004, Von Hippel and von Krogh, 2003).

In Section 2, we give a short overview of the main characteristics of OSS. In Section 3, we present three other examples of collective invention. In Section 4, we explore what the different examples have in common. We discuss why collective invention normally does not survive the whole innovation process. In Section 5, we compare these findings with the OSS innovation process. We argue that OSS licenses, which are copyright-based, enable the collective invention mode to survive in a copyrighted world. In order to gain a better understanding of how OSS licenses can help with obtaining that goal, we describe the mixture of selective benefits that coexist in OSS compared to other collective invention cases in Section 6. We then ask what conditions exist preventing OSS making the changeover from a “private-collective” innovation model to a “private investment” model. We argue that the characteristics of OSS that are often identified as crucial, namely to be (a) an information product, (b) a user innovation that is (c) the product of a highly modular design, cannot fully explain the continued survival of the collective invention model. But they enable what we call a low-cost situation, which facilitates contributions to public goods. We argue that only the interplay of low-cost situations, OSS licenses and conditions that foster and maintain pro-social intrinsic motivation can explain the success of the OSS innovation model. We conclude with some remarks concerning the vulnerability of this model to developments in patent legislation.

Section snippets

Characteristics of ‘open source’

OSS is an example of a continued survival of the collective invention model that challenges conventional economic views that innovation is best supported by strong private intellectual property rights (e.g. Demsetz, 1967, North, 1981).3

Examples of collective invention

In the following, we will briefly present three earlier cases of “collective invention” that are similar to the “private-collective” model. We will compare them to the OSS case. The first case analyzed by Allen (1983) took place in the second half of the 19th century. It deals with the development of blast furnace design between iron-making companies in Britain's Cleveland district. The two other, more recent examples include the Homebrew computer club (Meyer, 2002) and the search for a

In search of common ground for the three examples of collective invention

In all three of these cases of collective invention, the actors involved were faced with a radical innovation, which is a time of high technological uncertainty and experimental learning processes.

A radical innovation is a technological development whose potential is not yet fully understood. While incremental innovations introduce relatively minor changes to existing products, exploiting the potential of the established design, radical innovations are based on a different set of engineering

Is open source simply another case of collective invention?

OSS development is often described as the most global and successful case of collective invention (Meyer, 2003, Nuvolari, 2002) or the “private-collective” model (Von Hippel and von Krogh, 2003). However, most OSS projects do not fit into the conditions analyzed that make a collective invention regime likely: once a technology enters the exploitation phase, sharing knowledge promises less potential for acquiring new knowledge and for influencing the environment. Rather, the negative impacts of

Motivations to contribute to open source software

There is a whole range of different motives that act as selective incentives for contribution. If the contribution to OSS is self-rewarding, the social dilemma situation of knowledge-sharing is transformed into a coordination game, where defection is no longer the dominant solution. This is the case when the benefits exceed the costs. In Section 6.1, the co-existence of different selective benefits in OSS is described. In Section 6.2, we ask what differences there might be between motivations

Conclusion

Open source software production is a highly successful innovation model, which represents a special case of what Allen (1983) calls “collective invention” and Von Hippel and von Krogh (2003) call “private-collective model of innovation”. The most important distinction is that, in contrast to the other examples of collective invention, the OSS model survives the emergence of a dominant design, and thus shows a promising way to a new innovation model, which goes beyond traditional forms of

References (89)

  • W.J. Abernathy et al.

    Innovation: mapping the winds of creative destruction

    Research Policy

    (1985)
  • W.J. Abernathy et al.

    Patterns of industrial innovation

    Technology Review

    (1978)
  • R.C. Allen

    Collective invention

    Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation

    (1983)
  • T.M. Amabile

    Creativity in Context: Update to the Social Psychology of Creativity

    (1996)
  • P. Anderson et al.

    Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: a cyclical model of technological change

    Administrative Science Quarterly

    (1990)
  • Baldwin, C.Y., Clark, K.B., 2003. Does Code Architecture Mitigate Free Riding in the Open Source Development Model?...
  • Y. Benkler

    Coase's penguin, or linux and the nature of the firm

    The Yale Law Journal

    (2002)
  • Y. Benkler

    Sharing nicely: on shareable goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production

    The Yale Law Journal

    (2004)
  • J. Bessen

    What good is free software?

  • Bessen, J., 2005. Open source software: Free provision of complex public goods....
  • Bessen, J., Maskin, E., 2000. Sequential innovation, patents and imitation. MIT Economics Department Working Paper,...
  • A. Bonaccorsi et al.

    Hybrid business models in the open source software industry

    Management Science

    (2006)
  • F.P. Brooks

    The Mythical Man-Month. Essays on Software Engineering

    (1975)
  • K.B. Clark

    The interaction of design hierarchies and market concepts in technological evolution

    Research Policy

    (1985)
  • M. Csikszentmihalyi

    Beyond Boredom and Anxiety

    (1975)
  • E.L. Deci et al.

    Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior

    (1985)
  • E.L. Deci et al.

    The “what” and “why” of goal pursuits: human needs and the self-determination of behavior

    Psychological Inquiry

    (2000)
  • H. Demsetz

    Towards a theory of property rights

    American Economic Review

    (1967)
  • G.G. Dess et al.

    Dimension of organizational task environments

    Administrative Science Quarterly

    (1984)
  • G. Dosi et al.

    Technical Change and Economic Theory

    (1988)
  • Elster, J., 1989. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order, New York,...
  • J. Ethira et al.

    Modularity and innovation in complex systems

    Management Science

    (2004)
  • Faraj, S., Wasko, M.M., 2001. The web of knowledge: An investigation of knowledge exchange in networks of practice,...
  • E. Fehr et al.

    The nature of human altruism

    Nature

    (2003)
  • U. Fischbacher et al.

    Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from public good experiments

    Economic Letters

    (2001)
  • E. Franck et al.

    Reconciling investors and donators—the governance structure of open source

    Journal of Management and Governance

    (2003)
  • Franke, N., von Hippel, E., 2003. Satisfying heterogeneous user needs via innovation toolkits: the case of apache...
  • B.S. Frey

    Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation

    (1997)
  • B.S. Frey et al.

    Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical evidence

    Journal of Economic Surveys

    (2001)
  • B.S. Frey et al.

    Pro-social behavior in a natural setting

    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization

    (2004)
  • B.S. Frey et al.

    Successful Management by Motivation. Balancing Intrinsic and Extrinsic Incentives

    (2002)
  • Ghosh, R.A., Glott, R., Krieger, B., Robles, B., 2002. Floss final report—Part 4: Survey of developers....
  • Gosh, R., Glogg, R., Krieger B., Robles G., 2002. Free/Libre and Open Source Software: Survey and Study. International...
  • H.B. Hansmann

    The role of nonprofit enterprise

    Yale Law Journal

    (1980)
  • Harhoff, D., Henkel, J., von Hippel, E., 2003. Profiting from voluntary information spillovers: How users benefit from...
  • A. Hars et al.

    Working for free? Motivations for participating in open source projects

    International Journal of Electronic Commerce

    (2002)
  • R.M. Henderson et al.

    Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms

    Administrative Science Quarterly

    (1990)
  • Henkel, J., 2004. Patterns of free revealing – balancing code sharing and protection in commercial open source...
  • G. Hertel et al.

    Motivation of software developers in open source projects: an internet based survey of contributors to the Linux kernel

    Research Policy

    (2003)
  • P. Himanen

    The Hacker Ethic

    (2001)
  • G. Kirchgässner

    Toward a theory of low-cost-decision

    European Journal of Political Economy

    (1992)
  • H. Kliemt

    The veil of insignificance

    European Journal of Political Economy

    (1986)
  • Kogut, B., Metiu, A., 2000. The emergence of E-Innovation: insights from open source software development. Reginald H....
  • B. Kogut et al.

    Open source software development and distributed innovation

    Oxford Review of Economic Policy

    (2001)
  • Cited by (0)

    1

    Margit Osterloh is Professor of Business Administration and Organization Theory at the Institute for Organization and Administrative Science, University of Zurich.

    2

    Sandra Rota is a Research Assistant at the chair of Margit Osterloh at the Institute for Organization and Administrative Science, University of Zurich. Tel.: +41 1 634 29 39; fax: +41 1 634 49 42.

    View full text