Elsevier

Review of Economic Dynamics

Volume 24, March 2017, Pages 79-94
Review of Economic Dynamics

Optimal inflation to reduce inequality

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2017.01.004Get rights and content

Abstract

A popular argument in favor of price stability is that the inflation-tax burden would disproportionately fall on the poor because wealth is unevenly distributed and portfolio composition of poorer households is skewed towards a larger share of money holdings. We reconsider the issue in a DSGE model characterized by limited participation to the market for interest bearing assets (LAMP). We show that a combination of higher inflation and lower income taxes reduces inequality. When we calibrate the share of constrained agents to fit the wealth Gini index for the US, the optimal inflation rate is above 4%. This result is robust to alternative foundations of money demand equations.

Introduction

Over the last 30 years income and wealth inequality have increased in developed economies and the issue of wealth ownership concentration has come to the forefront (Saez and Zucman, 2014). Concern has also grown for the distributive effects of monetary policies (Galbraith et al., 2007, Coibion et al., 2012) and for the apparently adverse effects of Central Banks actions on inequality.3

A widely popular argument in favor of price stability is the asymmetric incidence of the inflation tax when wealth is unevenly distributed and portfolio composition of poorer households is skewed towards a larger share of money holdings, so that the inflation tax burden would disproportionately fall on the poor (Erosa and Ventura, 2002, Boel and Camera, 2009, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2011a). In fact, this is the key justification for endorsing price stability as a contribution to reducing inequality and poverty.4

In the paper we reconsider the issue of inflation optimality in a model where distributional issues arise because wealth holdings are concentrated in the hands of few households. We modify a standard DSGE model by introducing Limited Asset Market Participation (LAMP henceforth), in the form of a distinction between holders of interest bearing assets (unconstrained agents) and agents who only own money (constrained agents), as in Coenen et al. (2008).

Heterogeneity in the access to the market for interest bearing assets is a salient feature of the data. While the majority of US households (92.5%) own transaction accounts (including checking, savings, money market deposit accounts and money market mutual funds), only a small minority hold other financial assets, such as stocks, bonds, investment funds and other managed assets (which are held by less than the 20% of households).5 The major long term saving vehicle for US households are retirement accounts, held by the 50.4% of families. Excluding such important differences in wealth holdings from macroeconomic models implies that the distributional effects of policies and shocks are also ignored.

Assuming wealth inequality is not sufficient to identify a potential role for monetary policy and inflation. In principle, a redistributive scheme taxing wealth returns to subsidize constrained households should make monetary policy redundant. To obtain non-trivial results, we assume that the policymaker set of fiscal tools is incomplete. Further, in line with previous contributions on Ramsey-optimal monetary and fiscal policies, we posit that firms monopoly profits are not taxed. In representative agent models such as Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004a) this assumption is made because distortionary taxation does not warrant an increase in the optimal inflation rate unless factor incomes are suboptimally taxed (see Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2011a; and references cited therein). Maintaining this assumption here seems appropriate for several reasons. First, anecdotal evidence suggests that large multinationals such as Apple and Google are subject to a negligible tax burden on their worldwide profits (Fuest et al., 2013). This has become a primary concern for international agencies (OECD, 2013a, OECD, 2013b and European Commission, 2012). Second, a large literature documents that tax evasion and tax avoidance are related to firms rents.6 Third, emphasys on firms ability to escape profit taxation is particularly relevant in our context, where concern for inequality motivates the government's decisions.

Optimal inflation analysis crucially depends on underlying assumptions concerning economic incentives to hold money balances. The classical approach assumes that real money balances are proportional to consumption, so that money holdings and consumption should be equally distributed among households (Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2004a).

Erosa and Ventura (2002) adopt instead a cash/credit-transaction approach, where a fraction of transactions are undertaken using a credit technology that exhibits economies of scale. In this case inflation increases inequality because poor households realize a larger percentage of cash transactions relative to rich households.

The classical approach implies that the distribution of money holdings replicates distribution of consumption levels, whereas the cash/credit-transaction approach implies that money holdings are more equally distributed than consumption because richer households consume more but hold less money balances. According to Ragot (2014), these results are in sharp contrast with empirical evidence in countries like the US and Italy, where the observed distribution of money across households is similar to the distribution of financial wealth, suggesting that the transaction motive for holding money plays a limited role relative to financial motives. In fact Ragot (2014) shows that the Gini indexes for money and financial wealth holdings are replicated in an heterogeneous agent model where consumption transactions are subject to a cash in advance constraint and financial transactions are subject to fixed costs à la Baumol–Tobin. We label this characterization of money demand as the infrequent trading approach. To assess the implications of the infrequent trading approach to money demand, we follow Alvarez et al. (2009), and assume that unconstrained agents can trade in financial markets only infrequently. Consistently with the facts discussed by Ragot (2014), this allows to obtain a distribution of money holding similar to that of financial wealth.

In our analysis, we compute the Ramsey steady state solution for our model. This adds to Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2004a) because the identification of the optimal financing mix (inflation and income tax) for a given level of public consumption takes into account the planner's concern for redistribution as a determinant of inflation. We take into account the alternative money demand specifications based on the consumption technologies discussed above, and account for unconstrained households' infrequent trading in the markets for interest-bearing assets.

We obtain the interesting result that, irrespective of the money demand specification adopted in the model, the planner chooses a steady state inflation rate which is higher than under the representative agent assumption. In fact we obtain optimal inflation rates which are always above 4%. In contrast with received wisdom, the fundamental reason underlying this result is that expected inflation shifts the fiscal burden towards asset holders. This happens because, even if inflation is a regressive tax that falls proportionally more on the wealth holdings of the poor, it allows to tax consumption out of monopoly profits by exploiting the fact that money holdings are larger for wealthier individuals, as implied by the Gini index for money holdings. Thus, shifting the financing mix towards higher inflation allows to shift the overall burden of taxation towards asset holders. For reasons explained in the text, our results are strengthened when we assume that the Planner can levy distinct labor and capital income taxes.

Our results are related to those of Jin (2009) that considers a growth model with inequality in both wealth and skill levels. Interestingly, that paper finds that inflation tends to reduce inequality when the latter depends on wealth inequality, a result compatible with ours. Another paper related to ours is Da Costa and Werning (2008), who analyse the optimality of the Friedman rule in a model in which agents have different private-knowledge labor productivities and the planner has access to non-linear labor income taxes. In that framework, zero inflation is always on the Pareto optimal frontier, which suggests that heterogeneity in non-labor incomes is necessary to introduce a role for inflation as a redistributive tool.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 defines the competitive equilibrium and the Ramsey optimal policy. Section 4 describes the results. Section 6 concludes.

Section snippets

The model

We consider an infinite-horizon production economy populated by a continuum of households i[0;1]. A mass θ[0,1] of agents (constrained agents, henceforth c) hold money balances but does not participate in the market for interest bearing assets, while a mass 1θ of agents (unconstrained agents, henceforth u) benefit from full participation to financial markets and own firms. As discussed in the introduction, we allow for the possibility that interest bearing assets are traded infrequently.

We

Competitive equilibrium

Definition 1

For a given policy plan {Rt,τt}t=0,18 the competitive equilibrium is a set of plans{ctu(p),ctc,ct,ltu,ltc,lt,λtu(p),λtc,mct,πt,wt,wtu,wtc,mtu(p),mtc,mt,yt,bt,Rt,kt,rtk,τt}t=0, that, given initial values {m1u(p),

Ramsey steady state

To understand steady state results one should bear in mind that in this model inflation has several effects: i) it redistributes wealth across households due to heterogeneity in money holdings, ii) it induces price and wage nominal adjustment costs, iii) it allows to reduce distortionary taxation for any given amount of public consumption. Our effort here is to clarify the relevance of each of these effects. To identify the importance of redistributive effects we benchmark our results against

Effects of a capital income tax

So far we have assumed that the Planner uses the same linear tax schedule for labor and capital income. This might be regarded as too strong an assumption, and we now consider the case where the Planner can levy distinct labor and capital income taxes.33

The literature on optimal dynamic taxation under perfectly competitive goods markets suggests that public

Conclusions

A relatively large body of empirical research has pointed out that inflation is particularly harmful for the poor (Easterly and Fischer, 2001) and high inflation and inequality are positively related (Albanesi, 2007). We show that this need not be the case when monetary and fiscal policies are optimally designed.

Untaxed monopoly profits generate a potential incentive to inflate in order to reduce income taxes. This incentive is unambiguously stronger when such profits are concentrated in the

References (40)

  • X. Ragot

    The case for a financial approach to money demand

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2014)
  • A. Sbordone

    Prices and unit labor costs: a new test of price stickiness

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2002)
  • S. Schmitt-Grohé et al.

    Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices

    Journal of Economic Theory

    (2004)
  • J. Slemrod et al.

    Tax avoidance, evasion and administration

  • F. Alvarez et al.

    Sluggish responses of prices and inflation to monetary shocks in an inventory model of money demand

    The Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2009)
  • A. Atkeson et al.

    Taxing capital income: a bad idea

    Quarterly Review - Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

    (1999)
  • R. Beetsma et al.

    Does inequality cause inflation? The political economy of inflation, taxation and government debt

    Public Choice

    (April 1996)
  • C. Chamley

    Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives

    Econometrica

    (1986)
  • O. Coibion et al.

    Innocent Bystanders? Monetary Policy and Inequality in the US

    (2012)
  • C.E. Da Costa et al.

    On the optimality of the Friedman rule with heterogeneous agents and nonlinear income taxation

    Journal of Political Economy

    (February 2008)
  • Cited by (33)

    • Revisiting the optimal inflation rate with downward nominal wage rigidity: The role of heterogeneity: Optimal inflation, with DNWR

      2022, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
      Citation Excerpt :

      The optimal inflation rate in a heterogeneous agent model is a relatively new research field. Previous studies address various dimensions of heterogeneity, including firms’ productivity growth (Adam and Weber, 2019), firms’ price setting (Blanco, 2021), and households’ asset holdings (Menna and Tirelli, 2017). For instance, Adam and Weber (2019) show that trend inflation affects the relative price among new and old firms whose productivity grows at different rates and estimate the optimal inflation rate for the U.S. economy between 1 to 3 percent per year.

    • Can innovation improve income inequality? Evidence from panel data

      2020, Economic Systems
      Citation Excerpt :

      Human capital is included in the specification because it has been found to reduce income inequality (Campos et al., 2016; Yang and Qiu, 2016). Inflation is included because greater inflation tends to increase the income–inequality gap (Menna and Tirelli, 2017; Nantob, 2015). Institutions are included because better institutions tend to reduce income inequality (Chong and Gradstein, 2007; Lin and Fu, 2016).

    • Inflation and income inequality in a Schumpeterian economy with menu costs

      2020, Economics Letters
      Citation Excerpt :

      Furthermore, in the general case of elastic labor supply, inflation generates more negative impacts on income inequality because the households’ value on leisure decreases wage income, causing a rise in the ratio of asset income relative to wage income.2 In addition to the existing studies in inflation and innovation (for example, Chu and Cozzi 2014 and Huang et al. 2017), and those in inflation and inequality (for example, Coibion et al. 2017 and Menna and Tirelli 2017), this study is most closely related to Chu et al. (2019), who explore a similar issue in inflation and income inequality. Specifically, by introducing money demand via CIA constraints into a Schumpeterian growth model with random quality improvement, Chu et al. (2019) find that inflation that leads to an inverted-U effect on economic growth generates the same effect on income inequality.

    • Monetary policy, heterogeneous population and inflation

      2019, Research in Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      In the first one, government uses both monetary and fiscal policy to achieve a desired outcome. Menna and Tirelli (2017) reconsider the received wisdom that the inflation tax burden falls largely on the poor. In an environment with an incomplete tax system they show that a combination of a lower income tax and higher inflation reduces inequality, with optimal inflation rate being well above the typical inflation targets in the developed economies.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We thank Roberta Cardani, Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Marco Maffezzoli, Alessandra Pelloni and Emiliano Santoro for useful comments and suggestions. We also thank participants to the XXII Symposium of the Society for Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics at the Baruch College in New York and seminar participants at Banco de Mexico and at the University of Milano-Bicocca. The paper is part of the RASTANEWS Project funded by the European Community's Seventh Framework Programme (FP7), Grant No. 320278.

    1

    The opinions expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily represent Banco de Mexico's or its board of governors' opinions.

    2

    Patrizio Tirelli gratefully acknowledges financial support from EC project 320278-RASTANEWS.

    View full text