Well-posed Ky Fan’s point, quasi-variational inequality and Nash equilibrium problems

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.na.2005.10.018Get rights and content

Abstract

We give a unified approach to Hadamard well-posedness for some nonlinear problems such as those of Ky Fan’s point and quasi-variational inequality. As applications, we obtain some well-posed theorems for Nash equilibrium points.

Introduction

For well-posed optimization problems, there are concepts of two main types: Hadamard and Tykhonov well-posedness [1]. There are several surveys in [4] focused on the ideas of well-posedness and stability of problems in vector optimization, calculus of variations and other related fields. In 1995, Revalski gave a survey [7] on well-posedness of optimization problems, in which he presented various notions of well-posedness and some results concerning the relation between them. Similarly, there are two types of well-posedness in game theory, namely, Hadamard and Tykhonov well-posedness. Contrary to the case for optimization problems, there are few results on well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points (for short, NE). In 1995, a survey by Patrone [5] reviewed the ideas and some results of Tykhonov well-posedness for Nash equilibrium points. Of course, like for optimization problems, in addition to Tykhonov well-posedness, we may introduce other types of well-posedness for Nash equilibrium points. Recently, Pusillo Chicco [6] presented several open problems on well-posedness in the context of Nash equilibrium points, containing the problem of exploring the relationship between Tykhonov well-posedness and Hadamard well-posedness. In Section 7 of [6] Pusillo Chicco wrote: “Another problem that can be considered as ‘classical’ in the context of well-posedness in optimization is the connection between Tykhonov well-posedness and Hadamard well-posedness. It would be interesting to explore this relationship in the context of NE: given an approximate equilibrium, how to build a game ‘close’ to the original one for which it will become an equilibrium?”

Generally speaking, Hadamard types of well-posedness of a problem mean the continuous dependence of the solution on the data of such a problem. Tykhonov types of well-posedness such as Tykhonov and Levitin–Polyak well-posedness deal with the behavior of a prescribed class of sequences of approximate solutions. In this paper, we focus on various types of well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points of a noncooperative game in strategic form (briefly, a game). To be precise, for Hadamard well-posedness, one considers a family of payoff functions and/or a family of strategy sets, both of which are topologized. Given a game Γ parametrized by payoffs or by both payoffs and strategy sets, denote by F(Γ) the set of all Nash equilibrium points of Γ. Γ is said to be Hadamard well-posed (briefly, H-wp) if it has a unique Nash equilibrium x and for any sequence of games {Γn} converging to Γ, and any xnF(Γn),{xn} must converge to x. Γ is said to be generalized Hadamard well-posed (briefly, gH-wp) if it has at least one Nash equilibrium and for any sequence of games {Γn} converging to Γ, and any xnF(Γn),{xn} must have a subsequence converging to a Nash equilibrium of Γ. When one considers the Tykhonov type of well-posedness, one must give notions of approximate solutions for a game, i.e., approximate equilibrium points. For the sake of simplicity, consider a two-person game Γ=(X,Y,f,g). A sequence {(xn,yn)}X×Y is said to be an asymptotically Nash equilibrium (briefly, a-NE) if supxXf(x,yn)f(xn,yn)0,supyYg(xn,y)g(xn,yn)0. If X and Y are topological spaces, then the game Γ is said to be Tykhonov well-posed (briefly, T-wp) if Γ has a unique Nash equilibrium towards which every a-NE of Γ converges. Furthermore, by modifying the definition for an approximate solution, we could introduce Levitin–Polyak well-posedness. To do this, let X and Y be metric spaces and consider two subsets AX and BY. A sequence {(xn,yn)}X×Y is said to be closed to A×B if d((xn,yn),A×B)0, where d((x,y),A×B)inf{d((x,y),(x,y)):(x,y)A×B} denotes the metric function generated by A×B. Given a game (A,B,f,g), a sequence {(xn,yn)}X×Y is said to be a Levitin–Polyak asymptotically Nash equilibrium (briefly, LPa-NE) if d((xn,yn),A×B)0, and supxAf(x,yn)f(xn,yn)0,supyBg(xn,y)g(xn,yn)0. Then the game Γ is said to be Levitin–Polyak well-posed (LP-wp) if it has a unique Nash equilibrium towards which every LPa-NE of Γ converges. Also, if we consider generalizations of Tykhonov types of well-posedness, we only need the existence of Nash equilibrium points and require that every corresponding approximate sequence has a subsequence converging to a Nash equilibrium.

So far, results on well-posedness of Nash equilibrium have been obtained mainly for Tykhonov well-posedness. In this paper, we develop a new approach to well-posedness of Nash equilibrium in game theory. More precisely, we will establish the relation between different types of well-posedness of the Nash equilibrium. By applying set-valued analysis, we obtain some results on Hadamard well-posedness and then we can derive Tykhonov types of well-posedness from the relation. In particular, with our approach, it is effective to study Levitin–Polyak well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points. With our approach, it is also much easier to study generalizations of well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points.

This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, a unified theorem of generalized Hadamard and Hadamard well-posedness for some nonlinear problems will be given. From this unified theorem, in Section 3, we derive the gH-wp and H-wp theorems for Ky Fan’s points and the solutions of quasi-variational inequalities. In Section 4, as applications of the results in Section 3, we derive gH-wp and H-wp theorems of equilibrium points of noncooperative games for three models:

  • (A)

    games parametrized by payoffs;

  • (B)

    games parametrized by payoffs and by strategy spaces; and

  • (C)

    games parametrized by payoffs and by feasible strategy correspondences.

In Section 5, we give some results concerning the relation between different types of well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points and some results on the Tykhonov type of well-posedness. To be precise, given an approximate Nash equilibrium for models (A), (B) and (C), we will construct a game close to the original game such that the approximate Nash equilibrium becomes a Nash equilibrium of the approximate game. And under some stronger conditions for strategy spaces we obtain generic well-posedness of saddle point problems. Finally, in Section 6, we state briefly some results on generalized well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points.

Section snippets

Unified theorems of Hadamard well-posedness

First we recall some notions stated in the following definition; see [3].

Definition 2.1

Let X and Y be two Hausdorff topological spaces and F:Y2X be a set-valued map, where 2X denotes all nonempty subsets of X. Then F is said to be upper semicontinuous at yY if for each open set U in X with UF(y), there exists an open neighborhood O(y) of y such that UF(y) for each yO(y); F is said to be upper semicontinuous on Y if F is upper semicontinuous at every point yY; F is said to be an usco map if F is

H-wp of Ky Fan’s points in a compact setting

Let X be a nonempty compact subset of a Hausdorff topological space. Let M1 be the collection of all functions φ:X×XR such that (1) for each yX,xφ(x,y) is lower semicontinuous and (2) sup(x,y)X×X|φ(x,y)|<+.

For each φ,ψM1, define ρ(φ,ψ)=sup(x,y)X×X|φ(x,y)ψ(x,y)|.

Clearly, (M1,ρ) is a metric space.

Write M={φM1: there exists xX such that φ(x,y)0 for all yX}. Given φM, such an x is called a Ky Fan’s point of φ; see [9]. Denote by F(φ) the set of all Ky Fan’s points of φ; then, φF(φ)

Hadamard well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points

In this section, we study Hadamard well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points for three models: Model (A), Model (B) and Model (C); see [10].

We need the following lemma:

Lemma 4.1

Let X,Y and Z be three Hausdorff topological spaces and F:Y2X and G:Z2X be two set-valued maps. Suppose that F is an usco map and there exists a continuous map T:ZY such that G(z)=F(T(z)) for each zZ . Then G is an usco map.

Proof

For any zZ,y=T(z)Y, since G(z)=F(y) and F(y) is compact, so is G(z).

Let U be any open set in X with U

Relation between different types of well-posedness

In this section, we introduce concepts of other types of well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points, namely, Tykhonov and Levitin–Polyak well-posedness. We will study the relation between Hadamard well-posedness and these types of well-posedness. Also, by applying Theorem 2.1, we can derive from the relation some Levitin–Polyak well-posed and Tykhonov well-posed theorems for Nash equilibrium points. Speaking precisely, for Models (A), (B) and (C), we introduce notions of asymptotically Nash

Generalized Tykhonov and Levitin–Polyak well-posedness

In [7], Revalski gave the definitions of generalized well-posedness for minimization problems. Similarly, we may give generalizations of various types of well-posedness for Nash equilibrium points and relations similar to those in the previous section. Generalized well-posedness for Nash equilibrium points is more interesting since the uniqueness of Nash equilibrium is not a generic property, while it is true for minimization problems and saddle point problems (cf. [2] and [8]).

A game fL is

References (12)

There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (30)

  • Generalized well-posedness for parametric fuzzy generalized multiobjective games

    2023, Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics
    Citation Excerpt :

    The concept of generalized L.P. well-posedness for an optimization problem means that a solution exists and some subsequence of each minimizing sequence converges to the solution. Since then, a lot of papers on the well-posedness for optimization-related problems have been investigated by many authors in different ways and various topics such as, for optimization problems [4,5], for variational inequality problems [6–12], for equilibrium problems [13–15], for double phase implicit obstacle problems [16–18], for Nash equilibria [19–23] and the references therein. Motivated and inspired by the above, in this paper, we study the well-posedness for parametric fuzzy generalized multiobjective games (called also parametric well-posedness for fuzzy generalized multiobjective games).

  • Continuity properties of the Nash equilibrium correspondence in a discontinuous setting

    2019, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications
    Citation Excerpt :

    For the existence of Nash equilibria, let us refer to the seminal papers [11], [5] and [17], and the more recent ones [3,9,15,4,21,10,14,16,19]. The upper semicontinuity of the Nash equilibrium correspondence in the setting of discontinuous games have been investigated in [27] and [20], while the continuity of the correspondence (that means upper and lower semicontinuity) has been obtained in several classes of discontinuous games: see [26,7,21,8]. More precisely, we focus on the upper (and lower) semicontinuity when the Nash equilibrium correspondence is defined on metric spaces of discontinuous games where the existence of Nash equilibria is guaranteed, and the metric is given by the sup-norm.

  • Hadamard well-posedness of the α-core

    2017, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications
    Citation Excerpt :

    A solution of a game is essential if any perturbed game has a solution approximated to it. Yu et al. [27] studied the well-posedness of Nash equilibrium points in some classes of noncooperative games. Scalzo [17] proved that some classes of games with weaker conditions (i.e., better-reply security and pseudocontinuity) also have the H-wp property.

  • Variational preferences and equilibria in games under ambiguous belief correspondences

    2015, International Journal of Approximate Reasoning
    Citation Excerpt :

    The last section is devoted to the issue of stability of equilibria. The problem of the limit behavior of the equilibria in games has been extensively studied in the literature (see, for instance, [13] for the standard problem, [24,32] for recent results under relaxed or different assumptions and references). The question whether the limit property extends to the equilibrium concepts in ambiguous games has been studied in [9] for the equilibria in the Kajii and Ui model under variational preferences, in [10] for equilibria under ambiguous belief correspondences and maxmin preferences, in [29] for an equilibrium notion in ambiguous games which relies on the Beweley unanimity rule.

View all citing articles on Scopus
View full text