Selective entry and auction design

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2015.03.004Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Reviews recent literature on auctions with endogenous entry.

  • Evaluates performance of different auction designs when entry is selective.

  • Shows non-standard designs can generate higher revenues and efficiencies.

  • Shows optimal bid preference in asymmetric auction depends on degree of selection.

Abstract

This article examines how different auction designs perform when entry is endogenous and selective, by which we mean that bidders with higher values are more likely to enter. In a model where potential bidders are symmetric, we show that three alternative designs can significantly outperform the ‘standard auction with simultaneous and free entry’ when entry is selective. When bidders are asymmetric, we show that level of bid preference that maximizes a seller’s revenues is significantly affected by the degree of selection. We also describe recent empirical and econometric work that shows that the degree of selection can be identified and estimated using standard types of auction data.

Introduction

This article examines the performance of different auction designs in a setting where bidders have independent private values but entry is endogenous and possibly selective. We will say that entry is selective when potential bidders with higher values are more likely to enter, as should happen when potential bidders have some information about their values prior to taking the entry decision. While it seems intuitive that entry should typically be selective, this has been ruled out by assumption in much of the theoretical and empirical auction literatures. In this article we will illustrate that allowing for selection can significantly affect the conclusions that a researcher would draw about the value of auction designs that differ from the standard auction with free entry, and that the exact degree of selection can also affect which design performs best. We also describe recent work that shows that the degree of selection is identified and can be estimated using types of data that are usually available in auction settings.

To develop our results, we consider an auction for a single unit of a good and assume that there is a well-defined set of risk-neutral potential bidders with independent private values. Throughout the article we will use the term ‘player’ to refer to a potential bidder, using ‘bidder’ to refer to a player that actually enters the auction and is able to submit a bid. The winning bidder is the one that is allocated the good at the end of the auction. We assume that it is costly for a player to enter the auction which she must do to submit a bid. We assume that a player learns her value of the object when she incurs the entry cost, so it is natural to interpret the entry cost as including the cost of doing research or ‘due diligence’ on the object being sold.1

As long as the entry cost is not too low or too high, entry will be endogenous in the sense that a player’s entry decision will depend on what it expects other players to do, as well as what it believes about its own value. We model a player’s belief about its value by assuming that, prior to taking the entry decision, it receives, for free, a signal that is positively correlated with its value. In equilibrium, players with signals above some threshold will enter, and the degree of correlation will, therefore, control the extent to which entry is selective. This provides us with a framework where we can examine how the degree of selection, determined by the informativeness of the signals, affects the absolute and relative performance of different mechanisms, measured either in terms of the seller’s revenues or total surplus. The common assumption of no selection would involve players receiving no signals or, equivalently, signals that are completely uninformative.

We use a particular parameterization of our model to compare the performance, both in terms of revenues and efficiency, of different auction designs. Our baseline design is a ‘standard auction with simultaneous and free (i.e., unrestricted) entry’ (SASFE), which is the usual way that real-world auctions with endogenous entry are modeled. As has been documented in the literature, one feature of this design that can be both inefficient and harmful for the seller is that entry decisions are not coordinated across players so that the realized number of bidders will be random. With symmetric players, we compare the SASFE with three designs that deal with this problem in different ways. In the ‘entry rights auction’ (ERA) of Ye (2007), the seller fixes the number of entrants in advance and conducts an initial auction for these entry ‘slots’ where players can bid based on their signals. We also consider two designs where players take entry decisions sequentially, which also allows for coordination, but also allows for the number of entrants to depend on the information that the players have and the seller does not. In one of these designs (a ‘sequential entry auction’), players decide to enter sequentially but the entrants bid simultaneously. In the other design, the ‘sequential bidding auction’ of Bulow and Klemperer (2009) (BK hereafter), players make entry decisions sequentially and entrants can submit bids when they enter in order to signal information about their values to players that are taking entry decisions later in the sequence.

When there is no selection, as is typically assumed in the literature, the SASFE generates higher expected revenues than either of the sequential designs and its revenues are quite close to those of the ERA. However, once selection is introduced into the model, both sequential designs, and especially the sequential bidding auction, generate substantially higher revenues than the SASFE and the revenue advantage of the ERA over the SASFE also increases. The identity of the mechanism that performs best depends on the exact degree of selection that is assumed. The alternative designs generate higher total surplus than the SASFE whatever is assumed about selection, but the size of their advantage over the SASFE also tends to increase when entry is more selective. In our comparisons, we draw on results developed in Roberts and Sweeting (2013), who compare the SASFE and the sequential bidding auction, and Bhattacharya et al. (2014), who compare a SASFE and an ERA in a procurement setting. The new results in the present article come from using a single set of parameters, so that the sequential bidding auction and the ERA can also be compared; adding the sequential entry auction to the consideration set; considering how absolute and relative performance changes when we move from no selection to partial selection (the earlier papers only consider different degrees of partially selective entry); and, examining in more detail why the alternative mechanisms are more efficient and generate higher revenue.

We also examine how the degree of selection in the entry process can affect the performance of bid preference programs, that are widely used by government agencies when selling assets or procuring services, in a model where bidders are asymmetric.2 These programs are partly motivated by wanting to increase the probability that bidders of a particular type will win, but also, following the logic of optimal auctions (Myerson, 1981), by a desire to raise auction revenues by increasing the competition that strong bidders face. We show that while very large bid preferences maximize revenues when there is little selection, much smaller preferences are optimal when the degree of selection is high. These results are also new, and an additional contribution is that we use our analysis to illustrate how changing the degree of selection changes the level of entry costs required to rationalize a given amount of entry by weak bidders.

Our paper contributes to the enormous theoretical literature on auction design, summarized in the surveys of Klemperer (2004), Krishna (2002) and Milgrom (2004). When the seller has a single unit, and there is a fixed number of risk-neutral and symmetric bidders with independent private values, it is well-known that the optimal mechanism is a standard auction with a reserve price or entry fee.3 Much of the theoretical auction literature has been concerned with exploring which mechanisms perform best when these assumptions are relaxed. We will focus on relaxing the assumption that the number of bidders is exogenous, and explore how particular assumptions about they way the entry process works affect the absolute and relative performance of different mechanisms. Milgrom (2004) uses endogenous entry as his leading illustration of why auctions need to be analyzed in their correct context, arguing that even auctions that are carefully designed can fail when too few bidders decide to participate (p. 209).4

We follow the existing literature in modeling the way that standard auctions work as a two-stage game, where, in the first stage, players simultaneously decide whether to enter, incurring a common entry cost, and, in the second stage, the entrants simultaneously submit bids. This is what we will label an SASFE. Entry decisions into an SASFE will be non-trivially endogenous when the entry cost is ‘moderate’ (Milgrom, p. 217) in the sense that it is low enough that, in equilibrium, some players may want to enter, while being high enough that some may not.

The cleanest set of theoretical results come from models in which players have no private information about their values until they have entered, so that entry is not selective. Assuming that players are symmetric, that the common entry cost is moderate and that the entry game is followed by a standard first price or second price auction (revenue equivalence holds in this context), Levin and Smith (1994) show that (i) the symmetric equilibrium involves players mixing over whether to enter, and making zero expected profits; (ii) the seller’s optimal reserve price is equal to its value of keeping hold of the object, with revenue-maximization requiring no reserve price and no entry fees (see also McAfee and McMillan, 1987); (iii) an increase in the number of potential entrants will reduce expected revenues; and, (iv) when the reserve price is equal to the seller’s value, equilibrium entry strategies are optimal in the sense that a social planner who also had to choose a symmetric entry rule would choose the same entry probability that the players themselves choose in equilibrium. In what follows, we will refer to the assumption that entry is not selective as “NS”.5 Of course, property (iv) does not imply that the mechanism is necessarily optimal when compared to mechanisms where the seller changes the entry process in some way, such as fixing the number of players that can enter or organizing players to move sequentially.

Assuming NS, BK compare outcomes in a SASFE with those in an alternative procedure where players take entry decisions and bid sequentially, which they argue is a stylized version of how corporations are often sold. They show that the alternative procedure raises total surplus but will almost always generate lower revenues for the seller, because of the ability of early movers to deter entry. We will show that their sequential bidding procedure can actually increase revenues quite significantly as soon as any degree of selection is introduced into the model.

A more limited literature has considered endogenous entry with selection. Samuelson (1985) and Menezes and Monteiro (2000) assume that players know their values when deciding whether to enter. This is the most extreme form of selection that we will consider, and we will call this the fully selective, “FS” assumption. A feature of this model is that bidders with high values tend to make positive profits in equilibrium. In the SASFE under FS, revenues may increase or decrease when additional players are added, and the seller-optimal reserve may be greater than the seller’s value of holding onto the object (Menezes and Monteiro, 2000). Characterization of optimal policies tends to be specific to the value distributions considered, which is one reason why the NS assumption has been the focus of most analysis. Hubbard and Paarsch (2009) use a computational approach to consider the effects of bid preferences to some subset of symmetric players in first-price auctions under the FS assumption.6

Ye (2007), Bhattacharya et al. (2014), Roberts and Sweeting (2013), Marmer et al. (2013) and Gentry and Li (2014) consider models where players face a common entry cost but have noisy signals about their values before they enter, as we assume in this article.7Moreno and Wooders (2011), Cremer et al. (2009) and Lu and Ye (2013) consider a variant of the NS model where players have heterogeneous entry costs. We consider below whether this model has similar implications to one where entry is partially selective.

Most empirical work has also tended to make the NS assumption, partly because this assumption implies that the distribution of players’ values will be the same as the distribution of bidders’ values which is what can be inferred from the data. Athey et al. (2013) and Krasnokutskaya and Seim (2011) both consider the effects of bid preferences when entry is endogenous but bidders do not know their values when deciding whether to enter. In Section 6 we show that smaller bid preferences may be optimal for the seller when entry is selective. In Section 7, we describe recent results showing that selective entry models are identified, as well as noting recent empirical work, including Roberts and Sweeting (2013), Roberts and Sweeting (2015) (timber) and Bhattacharya et al. (2014) (highway procurement), that show that these models, including the degree of selection, can also be estimated in practice.

As models with endogenous and selective entry are not analytically tractable, our comparisons are computational. For ease of exposition, we focus on a single set of parameters for most of the analysis. While our results hold for a wide variety of parameters and value distributions that we have considered in our research, the reader should be clear that we are only claiming that selective entry can matter for the relative performance of different mechanisms, not that it must always do so. We do not compare the various mechanisms that we consider with optimal mechanisms, partly because when entry is partially selective, the generally optimal mechanism is unknown although, in very recent work, Lu and Ye (2014) have characterized the optimal design of a two-stage auction.8

The article is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the basic model, assuming that players are symmetric, and describes equilibrium strategies and the effects of selection when a standard auction with free entry is used. Section 3 describes the alternative mechanisms considered with symmetric bidders and their associated equilibrium strategies. 4 Efficiency comparisons, 5 Revenue comparisons contain the comparisons of expected total surplus (efficiency) and revenues. Section 6 considers bid preferences in a setting where players are asymmetric. Section 7 briefly describes recent work that shows that the degree of selection is non-parametrically identified and can be estimated using real world data. Section 8 concludes.

Section snippets

Model

In this section we outline the basic model that we will use to compare different auction designs and illustrate some of the properties of the equilibrium outcomes in the SASFE. For now, we will assume that players are symmetric, leaving all discussion of the asymmetric case to Section 6.

Alternative mechanisms

With symmetric bidders, we focus our discussion of mechanisms other than the SASFE on three relatively simple alternatives, two of which have been considered in the existing literature. Of course, these alternatives do not exhaust the spectrum of possible alternatives, but, to the extent that we find that alternatives outperform the SASFE, our conclusion would only be strengthened if we found other mechanisms that could do even better.

Efficiency comparisons

Having introduced the various mechanisms, we now compare their performance. The standard measures of performance are efficiency (i.e., total surplus, defined as the value of winner less total entry costs) and seller revenues. We begin by considering total surplus, and then turn to the question of how surplus is split between the seller and the potential buyers. Our analysis uses the set of parameters introduced previously. When considering efficiency, we assume that there is no reserve price in

Revenue comparisons

As already illustrated in the case of the SASFE (Table 1), selection affects the distribution of surplus between the seller and the potential buyers. For our mechanism comparison, Fig. 6 shows the seller’s expected revenue (panel (a)) and the expected total bidder payoffs (panel (b)). In each mechanism, selection reduces expected revenues (excepting the move from NS to α < 1 for the sequential bidding auction) and increases bidder payoffs, reflecting the fact that informative private signals

Asymmetric bidders, bid preferences and selection

In this section we examine how selective entry impacts how bid preference programs affect revenues and efficiency in a setting where players are asymmetric. Bid preferences are widely used, partly to meet distributional targets, such as allocating a certain proportion of contracts to small businesses or companies owned by minorities,42

Measuring selection

The previous results suggest that the degree of selection can significantly affect both the direction and the size of gains from changing an auction design. These results, however, would be of limited value if we cannot identify how selective the entry process is in different real-world contexts. Fortunately, there has been significant progress in the last few years when it comes to the identification and estimation of auction models with endogenous and selective entry. We highlight some of the

Conclusion

This article has argued that it is important to account for the selectivity, as well as the endogeneity, of entry when trying to evaluate different auction designs in real-world settings. In the particular example considered an increase in the degree of selection tends to increase both the efficiency and revenue gains from deviating from the ‘standard auction with simultaneous and free entry’ format, and it also tends to reduce the value, to the seller, of large bid preferences in settings

References (46)

  • P. Bajari et al.

    Identification and Estimation of a Discrete Game of Complete Information

    Econometrica

    (2010)
  • V. Bhattacharya et al.

    Regulating Bidder Participation in Auctions

    RAND J. Econ.

    (2014)
  • J. Bulow et al.

    Auctions Versus Negotiations

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1996)
  • J. Bulow et al.

    Why Do Sellers (Usually) Prefer Auctions?”

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2009)
  • I. Cho et al.

    Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria

    Q. J. Econ.

    (1987)
  • D. Coey et al.

    The Bidder Exclusion Effect

  • Congressional Budget Office

    Small Bidders in License Auctions for Personal Wireless Communications

  • J. Cremer et al.

    Symposium on Auction Theory: Auctions with Costly Information Acquisition

    Economic Theory

    (2009)
  • J. Denton

    Stacked Deck: Go-Shops and Auction Theory

    Stanf. Law Rev.

    (2008)
  • A. Eizenberg

    Upstream Innovation and Product Variety in the US Home PC Market

    Rev. Econ. Stud.

    (2014)
  • M. Gentry et al.

    Auctions with Selective Entry

  • M. Gentry et al.

    Identification in Auctions with Selective Entry”

    Econometrica

    (2014)
  • M. Gentzkow et al.

    Measuring the Sensitivity of Parameter Estimates to Sample Statistics

  • Cited by (15)

    • Dynamic games in empirical industrial organization

      2021, Handbook of Industrial Organization
    • Costly auction entry, royalty payments, and the optimality of asymmetric designs

      2020, Journal of Economic Theory
      Citation Excerpt :

      For cash auctions, Samuelson (1985) was the first to note that a seller can gain by restricting the potential number of bidders. Other cash auction papers that analyze the benefit of regulating entry include Ye (2007); Bhattacharya et al. (2014); Sweeting and Bhattacharya (2015); and Quint and Hendricks (2018). Stegeman (1996) studies ex-ante efficient cash mechanisms with entry costs.

    • Auctions with selective entry

      2017, Games and Economic Behavior
      Citation Excerpt :

      The AS model thus represents an ideal basis for a general analysis of auctions with entry. Motivated by these considerations, we extend the standard independent private values auction environment to accommodate endogenous and selective (AS) entry, focusing on a class of mechanisms we call standard auctions with simultaneous entry in the sense of Bhattacharya and Sweeting (2015).1 For this class of auctions, we establish the following three results.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We thank Diego Moreno, several other participants at the ‘Selling Mechanisms’ session of the 2014 EARIE conference in Milan, Heski Bar-Isaac and two referees for comments. We are grateful to Heski Bar-Isaac for inviting Andrew Sweeting to participate in the session. Much of this research was performed in collaboration with James Roberts, and it has been financially supported by NSF grant SES-1260876. All errors are our own.

    View full text