Elsevier

Energy Policy

Volume 38, Issue 8, August 2010, Pages 4355-4362
Energy Policy

Network investments and the integration of distributed generation: Regulatory recommendations for the Dutch electricity industry

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.03.063Get rights and content

Abstract

An increase in the distributed generation of electricity necessitates investments in the distribution network. The current tariff regulation in the Dutch electricity industry, with its ex post evaluation of the efficiency of investments, average benchmarking and a frontier shift in the x-factor, delays these investments. In the unbundled electricity industry, the investments in the network need to be coordinated with those in the distributed generation of electricity to enable the system operators to build enough network capacity. The current Dutch regulations do not provide for a sufficient information exchange between the generators and the system operators to coordinate the investments. This paper analyses these two effects of the Dutch regulations, and suggests improvements to the regulation of the network connection and transportation tariffs to allow for sufficient network capacity and coordination between the investments in the network and in the generation of electricity. These improvements include locally differentiated tariffs that increase with an increasing concentration of distributed generation.

Introduction

The 2009 EC directive on the promotion of renewable energy stimulates the increase in the distributed generation of electricity (DG). Distributed generators (DGs) are small firms and electricity consumers that produce electricity at the decentralized level and that send this electricity to the distribution network.1 They often produce green electricity with (micro-) wind turbines and solar panels. The expectation of the Dutch government is that the share of green electricity in the European Union will increase to forty per cent in 2050, and that this electricity will mainly be produced by DGs (Ministry of Economic Affairs, 2008, p. 11).

When the amount of DG increases, considerable investments in the distribution network are necessary that expand the capacity of the distribution lines and that transform the network into a smart grid2 (Pollitt and Bialek, 2007). Investments in smart distribution grids differ substantially from conventional network investments. Whereas the latter mainly expand the capacity of the distribution lines, investments in smart grids modernize the network with digital technology. They transform the passive distribution networks into networks that actively manage the supply and demand of electricity. The electricity meters in smart grids allow for the measurement of the electricity that DGs put on the network. To give an idea of how substantial these investments are, it is estimated that investments in smart meters in Europe will cost around 51 billion euro (The Brattle Group, 2009).

The distribution system operators (DSOs) need to plan the expansion of the distribution network. To make the right investment decisions, they need information on where and by how much the DG of electricity will increase. The DSOs will therefore want to coordinate their investment decisions with the investments of the DGs. The regulation of the European DSOs is, however, not explicitly focused on stimulating network investments, but instead on increasing the efficiency of the DSOs. In addition, the European electricity directives prescribe the vertical unbundling of the integrated energy firms, and the DSOs and generators therefore need to find new ways of coordinating their investments.

This paper analyses the impact of regulation on investments in the distribution network, and focuses on the case of the Dutch electricity industry. In particular, it analyses whether the current Dutch regulations stimulate investment in the network, and whether they permit the DSOs, in their investment decisions, to properly take into account the investments in DG, and thus the demand for network services by the DGs. The paper argues that the current Dutch regulations delay investment in the network, and that they are insufficient to coordinate the investments in DG with those in the distribution network. It suggests improvements to the regulation of the network connection and transportation tariffs to allow for the coordination of investments.

Studies on the DG of electricity, investment in the distribution network and changes in the regulation of the DSOs are beginning to emerge (Cossent et al., 2009, Scheepers et al., 2007). This paper contributes to this literature by assessing the Dutch network regulations and by suggesting regulatory improvements on the basis of theoretical studies that focus on the inter-temporal nature of regulating network connection and investment (Dobbs, 2004, Foreman, 1995, Guthrie, 2006). The focus on the inter-temporal nature is relevant, because the regulated tariffs are for short-run access to long-lived network capacity, and the investments in the network are largely irreversible (Dobbs, 2004, Guthrie, 2006). These studies inform the analysis of regulating the DSOs, because they show why system operators postpone investments in the network, and when regulation of the system operators will stimulate or further postpone these investments. They enable the suggestions on improving the regulation of DSOs. This paper thus also provides an empirical application of the theoretical findings of the studies by Dobbs (2004), Foreman (1995) and Guthrie (2006).

Section two reviews these studies that analyse the impact of tariff regulation on network investments, and applies the findings of these studies to the Dutch electricity industry. Section three illustrates that Dutch regulations do not prescribe coordination between the DSOs and the DGs on investments in the network and generation. Section four presents options for improving the regulation of the network connection and transportation tariffs to give the DSOs an incentive to invest in the network and to allow for an information exchange between the DGs and the DSOs. Section five concludes.

Section snippets

Impact of tariff regulation on network investment

The relationship between a regulator and DSOs can be summarized as a contractual relation, in which the regulator sets the tariffs that the DSOs may charge the network users (Goldberg, 1976, Williamson, 1976). Goldberg (1976) refers to these contracts between the regulator and the operators as administered contracts. Guthrie (2006) mentions several characteristics of these administered contracts, such as the amount of freedom the regulated firm has in changing prices (price flexibility) and the

Lack of investment coordination between DSOs and DGs

Before the liberalization of the electricity industries, the decisions on investments in the network and in the generation of electricity were often coordinated internally. The European directives on the unbundling of the electricity industries have, however, prohibited the vertical integration of the network and generation (EC, 1996, EC, 2003). The following subsections will show that very few regulations have provided an alternative to this vertical integration, to coordinate the investments

Improvements in regulating the coordination of investments

New regulations in the Dutch electricity industry will have to enable the coordination of investments in the network with those in the DG, to allow for sufficient network capacity in the future and the development of smart grids. These regulations must stimulate an information exchange between the DSOs and the DGs. Elaborate ex ante information disclosure mechanisms, in which the generators inform the DSOs on their future investments well in advance of construction, will not work well at this

Conclusions

The tariff regulation in the Dutch electricity industry has focused on increasing the efficiency of the system operators, which has led to lower tariffs for the electricity consumers. Currently, the regulator is investigating whether the regulation of the Dutch electricity industry should be altered, as it has observed that replacement investments in the network lag behind depreciation and that incentive regulation may reduce the quality of the network (Mulder, 2009).

This paper has argued that

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Rob Aalbers, Paul de Bijl, Albert Jolink, Viki Kocsis, Yannick Perez, and two anonymous referees for valuable comments on earlier versions of this paper.

References (30)

  • V. Goldberg

    Regulation and administered contracts

    The Bell Journal of Economics

    (1976)
  • G. Guthrie

    Regulating infrastructure: the impact on risk and investment

    Journal of Economic Literature

    (2006)
  • L. Gutiérrez

    The effect of endogenous regulation on telecommunications expansion and efficiency in Latin America

    Journal of Regulatory Economics

    (2003)
  • G. Harrison et al.

    Exploring the tradeoffs between incentives for distributed generation developers and DNOs

    IEEE Transactions on Power Systems

    (2007)
  • Hiroux, C., Saguan, M., Large-scale wind power in European electricity markets: time for revisiting support schemes and...
  • Cited by (21)

    • Principles regulation of electricity tariffs for the integrated generation of traditional and alternative energy sources

      2021, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews
      Citation Excerpt :

      Furthermore, due to the fact that, according to the proposed scheme, the solar system is connected in series with the soil collector, it is possible to accumulate the thermal energy received by the solar collector during the summer in the upper layers of the Earth and to increase the functionality of the system and its coefficient of performance [8]. Renewable or inexhaustible energy resources are energy flows that are constantly or periodically operating in the environment [9]. In general, all energy flows of renewable energy sources are divided into two main groups: direct energy of solar radiation; secondary manifestations of solar radiation energy in the form of wind energy, hydropower, environmental thermal energy, biomass energy.

    • Cooperatives, incumbency, or market hybridity: New alliances in the Dutch energy provision

      2020, Energy Research and Social Science
      Citation Excerpt :

      This debate essentially centred around the question whether the management of electricity distribution networks could be left to the global market, risking competition and market monopolies, or should remain a public, at least state-protected, task. The government eventually wanted to secure state responsibility of distribution networks by separating it from other parts of the energy chain, materialised in the 1998 Electricity Law [32]. The debate exemplified the wish to find institutional arrangements that would foster competition and efficiency but also keep neoliberalisation in check.

    • Network operators and the transition to decentralised electricity: An Australian socio-technical case study

      2017, Energy Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      This will require the incumbent generators to accept a reduction in demand (Stock, 2014), that regulations are amended to adopt a wider range of electricity industry processes (Wood and Carter, 2014), that infrastructure providers (particularly the solar industry) improve technologies’ and industries’ reliability and acceptability (Simpson and Clifton, 2015), and that retailers work with network operators to develop price packages that incentivise efficient use of the network and self-generated electricity (Khalilpour and Vassallo, 2015). At present in Western Australia, as in other parts of the world (Niesten, 2010), the lack of coordination between regime parties, in particular in relation to information supply, the institutional inertia around regulation changes and the cultural resistance within utilities, are likely to create barriers to increasing distributed generation that a comprehensive ‘vision’ would need to overcome. Furthermore, conflicting timeframes and government interests may create issues for the implementation of a regime-wide ‘vision’.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text