Skip to main content
Log in

A Constant Gain Learning Explanation of U.S. Post War Inflation and Unemployment

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

An adaptive learning model, similar to Primiceri (Q J Econ 121(3):867–901, 2007) is built, where policymakers use constant gain learning algorithm to update their knowledge of the model every time period. This framework is used to study post war US inflation and unemployment. The model accurately explains the Great Inflation and gives us interesting results—while the rational expectations equilibrium is characterized by low inflation, learning leads to disequilibrium dynamics when initial knowledge of the model is incorrect. Specifically, policymakers in 1960s under estimated the natural rate, persistence of inflation and slope of Phillips Curve. Hence, policy was more expansionary than optimal, resulting in inflation. The convergence of beliefs to rational expectations equilibrium explains the subsequent disinflation in 1980s. This study differs from Primiceri (2007) in the following ways: (i) The results establish the presence of time inconsistency in policy between 1963–1979. Time inconsistency and the resulting inflation bias is explained as the rational, endogenous outcome of evolving beliefs. Hence, the possibility of a repetition of 70s cannot be eliminated in the future, for similar outcomes can be expected under similar beliefs. (ii) We find evidence against the narrative of ‘Volcker disinflation’, which credits the disinflation of 80s to the appointment of Volcker, an ‘inflation hawk’, as the chairman of Federal Reserve. (iii) Further, as an extension of Primiceri (2007), who provides point estimates, time varying estimates of persistence of inflation and slope of Phillips Curve are estimated to provide quantitative precision to the narrative proposed. This extension essentially arises from the Lucas critique. (iv) Time varying sacrifice ratio is calculated for the entire sample period, which, to our knowledge, is the first attempt for the US economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Throughout the paper, inflation is calculated as annualized quarterly growth rate of gdp deflator and unemployment is calculated as quarterly average of monthly civilian unemployment rate.

  2. Referred to as PC henceforth.

  3. Rogoff (1985) presents this solution.

  4. Dennis (2006) finds that the implicit target rate of inflation has fallen substantially since Volcker. He, however, does not find significant variation in Fed’s relative preference over inflation vis-a-vis output.

  5. This model can also be found in Primiceri (2007).

  6. Throughout the paper, beliefs of the policymaker about an unobservable is denoted by circumflex

  7. PLM is the policymaker’s idea/estimate, at any time period, about the relationship between the variables that underlie the economy. The next sub-section discusses percieved law of motion (PLM) and actual law of motion (ALM).

  8. In rest of the paper, the term ‘unobservables’ essentially constitutes of the natural rate of unemployment, persistence of inflation and slope of Phillips curve. Hence, \(\Omega _t=[\hat{u}^N_t\quad \hat{\alpha (L)}_t\quad \hat{\theta (L)}_t]'\).

  9. Evans and Honkapohja (2010) provides a technical and rigorous discussion on learning models in Macroeconomics.

  10. Discount rate is set \(\Delta = 1-1/120\).

  11. The evolution of policymaker’s beliefs across the sample is largely invariant to the method used to calculate initial beliefs. Initial beliefs calculated alternatively through Discounted Least Squares and moving average estimates do not alter the results in any significant manner.

  12. Further evidence of the same can be found in De Long (1997).

  13. In Fig. 4, the blue line plots the evolution of policymaker’s belief about the natural rate of unemployment while the red plots the evolution of the true value of the same.

  14. Belief about slope of Phillips Curve increases between 1965–70, but reduces back to zero by early 1970s.

  15. The corresponding sacrifice ratio in terms of output loss is obtained by multiplying the estimated sacrifice ratio by Okun’s ratio, which is approximately equal to 2.

  16. The sacrifice ratio (SR) is calculated as: \(SR_t=\frac{1-\alpha _t}{\rho \theta _t}, \rho =0.9\).

  17. Figure 6 tracks the ratio in terms of output loss.

  18. The correlation coefficient is calculated by considering the variables over 5 year periods.

  19. Real interest rate has been calculated as quartely effective federal funds rate minus inflation that quarter.

  20. In Eq. (12), there are no error terms since the prior belief that \(E_t\epsilon _{t+i}= E_t\eta _{t+i}=0 \forall i\in Z^+\)

  21. The inflation bias generated by ‘k’ in various model specifications can be seen in Barro and Gordon (1983), Gordon (1981) and Kydland and Prescott (1977).

References

  • Andersen, P.S., and W. Wascher. 1999. Sacrifice Ratios and the Conduct of Monetary Policy in Conditions of Low Inflation. BIS Working Paper, (82).

  • Ball, L. 1994. What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio ? Monetary Policy, University of Chicago Press (January):155–193.

  • Barro, R.J., and D.B. Gordon. 1983. A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy.

  • Chari, V.V., L.J. Christiano, and M. Eichenbaum. 1998. Expectation Traps and Discretion. Journal of Economic Theory.

  • Clarida, R., J. Galí, and M. Gertler. 2000. Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (1): 147–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogley, T., and T.J. Sargent. 2001. Evolving Post-World War II U.S. Inflation Dynamics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

  • Cogley, T., and T.J. Sargent. 2005. The conquest of US inflation: Learning and robustness to model uncertainty. Review of Economic Dynamics 8(2 SPEC. ISS.):528–563.

  • Crump, R.K., S. Eusepi, M. Giannoni, and A. Şahin. 2019. A Unified Approach to Measuring u. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 143–214. https://www.jstor.org/stable/26798819

  • Cukierman, A., and F. Lippi. 2005. Endogenous monetary policy with unobserved potential output. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29 (11): 1951–1983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long, B.J. 1997. America’s Only Peacetime Inflation: The 1970s. NBER Working Paper.

  • Dennis, R. 2006. The policy preferences of the US federal reserve. Journal of Applied Econometrics 21 (1): 55–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G.W. and S. Honkapohja. 2010. Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics.

  • Favero, C.A. and R. Rovelli. 2001. Macroeconomic Stability and the Preferences of the Fed. A Formal Analysis, 1961–98. SSRN Electronic Journal (July).

  • Gordon, R.J. 1981. Output Fluctuations and Gradual Price Adjustment. Journal of Economic Literature 19(2): 493–530. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2724154

    Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, P.N. 1999. Does the time-consistency problem explain the behavior of inflation in the United States? Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2): 279–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E., and E.C. Prescott. 1977. Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans. Journal of Political Economy 85 (3): 473–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubik, T.A. and F. Schorfheide. 2004. Testing for indeterminacy: An application to U.S. Monetary policy. American Economic Review.

  • Lucas, R.E. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: A critique, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol 1

  • Mankiw, N.G., Ball, L., and D. Romer. 1988. The New Keynesian Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade-Off. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A.H. 2003. A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol 2, Book 2, 1970–1986

  • Mitra, P., D. Biswas, and A. Sanyal. 2015. Estimating Sacrifice Ratio for Indian Economy—A Time Varying Perspective. RBI WORKING PAPER SERIES (June).

  • Orphanides, A. 2002. Monetary-policy Rules and the Great Inflation. American Economic Review 92 (2): 115–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ozlale, U. 2003. Price stability vs. output stability: Tales of federal reserve administrations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (9): 1595–1610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Primiceri, G.E. 2005. Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy. Review of Economic Studies.

  • Primiceri, G.E. 2007. Why Inflation Rose and Fell: Policy-Makers ’ Beliefs and U.S. Postwar Stabilization Policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (3): 867–901.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 1169–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C.D. and D. Romer. 2002. the Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy. NBER Working Paper 53(9):1689–1699.

  • Sims, A.C. and T. Zha. 2005. Were There Regime Switches in U.S. Monetary Policy ? CEPS Working Paper No. 110 (110).

  • Staiger, D., Stock, J.H. and M.W. Watson. Prices, Wages and the U.S. NAIRU in the 1990s (2001). NBER Working Paper No. w8320, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=272682

  • Zhang, L.H. 2001. Sacrifice Ratios with Long-Lived Effects. Working Paper, John Hopkins University (446).

Download references

Acknowledgements

No funding was received for the conduct of this study. The author declares that there is no conflict of interest.The author would like to thank Naveen Srinivasan (Madras School of Economics) and Rakesh Nigam (Madras School of Economics) for their inputs. The author thanks Giorgio E. Primiceri (Northwestern University) for some of the codes used in this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Venkata Raamasrinivas Mangapuram.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

In this section, simpler version of the model considered in this study is solved to theoretically establish the role of ‘k’ in determining the optimal policy every period and hence future path of inflation and unemployment. Assume that policymakers choose the optimal value of the policy variable (\(V_t\)) every time period, by minimizing the following loss function:

$$\begin{aligned} min L_t(V_t,k)= {E}_t[(\pi _{t+2}-\pi ^*)^2+\lambda (u_{t+1}-ku^N_{t+1})^2, \end{aligned}$$
(8)

subject to the following constraints:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _t&= \alpha \pi _{t-1}-\theta (u_{t-1}-u^N_{t-1}) + \epsilon _t,\end{aligned}$$
(9a)
$$\begin{aligned} (u_{t}-{u}^N_{t})&=\rho (u_{t-1}-{u}^N_{t-1})+ V_{t-1}+ \eta _s. \end{aligned}$$
(9b)

where the variables are defined as in the rest of the paper. In Eq. (8), loss this period depends on the expected deviation of unemployment from the natural rate one period ahead while deviation of inflation from its target two periods ahead affects loss this period. The loss function has been defined this way to throw light on the relative impact of inflation and unemployment on the optimal policy reaction, since policy at time ‘t’ affects unemployment at time ‘\(t+1\)’ and inflation at time ‘\(t+2\)’ in the New Keynesian model described in “The learning model”. Further, this simplified loss function does not contain discount rate and a policy smoothing term since the results of the analysis explored here is indifferent to these additional complexities. Proceeding to solve the model to obtain the optimal policy reaction, Eq. (9b) becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} u_{t}&= u^N_{t}+\rho (u_{t-1}-{u}^N_{t-1})+ V_{t-1}+ \eta _t \end{aligned}$$
(10a)
$$\begin{aligned} \Rightarrow (u_{t+1}-ku^N_{t+1})&= (1-k)u^N_{t+1} + \rho (u_{t}-{u}^N_{t})+ V_{t}+ \eta _{t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(10b)

Equation (9a) becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{t+2} - \pi ^*&= \alpha \pi _{t+1}-\theta (u_{t+1}-u^N_{t+1})-\pi ^* + \epsilon _{t+2}\end{aligned}$$
(11a)
$$\begin{aligned} \Rightarrow \pi _{t+2} - \pi ^*&= \alpha \pi _{t+1}-\theta [\rho (u_t-u^N_t)+ V_t]-\pi ^* + \epsilon _{t+2} \end{aligned}$$
(11b)

Substituting Eqs. (10b) and (11b) in (8)Footnote 20,

$$\begin{aligned} L_t= E_t[(\alpha \pi _{t+1}-\theta \rho (u_t-u^N_t)-\theta V_t-\pi ^*)^2+\lambda [(1-k)u^N_{t+1} + \rho (u_{t}-{u}^N_{t})+ V_{t}]^2], \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Minimizing (12) wrt \(V_t\),

$$\begin{aligned} 0&= \frac{dL_t}{dV_t}= E_t[ 2\lambda [(1-k)u^N_{t+1} + \rho (u_{t}-{u}^N_{t})+ V_{t}]-2\theta (\alpha \pi _{t+1}-\theta \rho (u_t-u^N_t)-\theta V_t-\pi ^*)]\end{aligned}$$
(13a)
$$\begin{aligned} 0&= E_t[ u^N_{t+1}[2\lambda (1-k)] + (u_t-u^N_t)[2\lambda \rho +2\theta ^2\rho ]+V_t(2\lambda + 2\theta ^2) - 2\theta \alpha \pi _{t+1}]+ 2\theta \pi ^* \end{aligned}$$
(13b)

Rearranging the terms,

$$\begin{aligned} \boxed {V_t = \frac{\theta }{\lambda + \theta ^2}(\alpha E_t \pi _{t+1}-\pi ^*) - \rho (u_t-u^N_t)- \frac{\lambda (1-k)}{\lambda + \theta ^2} E_t u^N_{t+1}} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Equation (14) is the best response function of the policymaker. The last term in RHS tends to zero as \(k \rightarrow 1\). Intuitively, as ‘k’ tends towards zero, the target rate of unemployment (\(ku^N_t\)) also tends to zero. For a given unemployment rate and natural rate, a fall in the target rate of unemployment(\(ku^N_t\)) generates expansionary policy and inflation subsequently. From Eq. (14),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V_t}{\partial k}= \left(\frac{\lambda }{\lambda + \theta ^2}\right){u^N_{t+1}} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Note that k lies between 0 and 1. As k falls, policy becomes more expansionary (\(V_t\) falls) and accomodative of inflation. Hence, the sign of the partial effect of ‘k’ on ‘\(V_t\)’ is positive in Eq. (15). Policy every period follows the rule specified in Eq. (14). When \(k=1\), the last term on RHS disappears which implies that the average level of policy is lower whenever \(0 \le k < 1\) in comparison to when \(k=1\). To see this, let the economy be in equilibrium at time t. In equilibrium, current and expected future values of unemployment is equal to the natural rate. The equilibrium conditions translate to:

$$\begin{aligned} u_t= u^N_t, \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} E_t u_{t+1}= E_t u^N_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$

Equilibrium in real economy implies that \(E_t\pi _{t+2}= \alpha E_t \pi _{t+1}\). Then, the best response of policymaker in equilibrium becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \boxed {V^e_t= \frac{\theta }{\lambda + \theta ^2}(\alpha E_t \pi _{t+2}-\pi ^*)- \frac{\lambda (1-k)}{\lambda + \theta ^2} E_t u^N_{t+1}}, \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where ‘\(V^e_t\)’ is the policy reaction in equilibrium. Note that, in equilibrium, if ‘\(k=1\)’, optimal policy response is higher, implying tighter monetary policy. If ‘\(k<1\)’, optimal policy in equilibrium gets relatively more accomodative of inflation as ‘\(k \rightarrow 0\)’. This increases the mean inflation—optimal policy response in equilibrium has an inflation bias. In the long run, inflation equals expectations and hence unemployment equals its natural rate. However, the long run inflation is higher as ‘k’ tends to zero.Footnote 21

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mangapuram, V.R. A Constant Gain Learning Explanation of U.S. Post War Inflation and Unemployment. J. Quant. Econ. 20, 701–721 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-022-00315-w

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-022-00315-w

Keywords

Navigation