Abstract
Macroeconomic interactions between agriculture and non-agricultural sectors of a developing economy are irreducibly linked to corporate encroachment in agriculture. In this paper we discuss some short run aspects of macroeconomic interaction between the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors of a developing economy like India with implicit and explicit policy support to the process of corporate encroachment in agriculture. We then set out a simple mathematical model to evaluate the macroeconomic consequences of policy support to the process of corporate encroachment in agriculture. An important component of inter-sectoral relationships in India has been the institution of a system of public procurement of agricultural commodities and its disbursal through a public distribution system. Policy support to corporate encroachment in agriculture has involved both these components for instance an attenuation of public procurement and a diminution of the public distribution system due to targeting. Though the Three Farm Laws have been repealed, the threat of further corporate encroachment into agriculture, through other means, remains.


Similar content being viewed by others
Data availability
Not applicable.
Notes
(FAO, 2018) noted the importance of public procurement in increasing viability of small-holder cultivators, improve nutrition outcomes and hence food security by promoting dietary diversity of the vulnerable sections of the population and promoting ecological sustainability by focusing on (food) crops that often tend to (but not always) generate relatively lower greenhouse gas emissions.
The agrarian trajectory in India has been dominated by the rural elite (Ramachandran, 1990; Mohan Rao and Storm, 1998) As a result, a system of public procurement of some agricultural commodities was instituted. The government has also created a buffer stock of foodgrains and a PDS, that was subsequently shrunk by targeting (Saratchand, 2018). These measures have strengthened the quest of the working poor to try to remain above the level of consumption corresponding to subsistence. We try to formalize some of these features in the macroeconomic model of this section.
The moniker APMC mandis prevails in North India.
Milk is another food item that is widely procured by cooperatives in India (Christie, 2020).
A critique of the policy response of the government of India to the Covid-19 pandemic is set out by (Ghosh, 2020).
It is arguable that the profit margin in the non-agricultural sector is an increasing function of the degree of capacity utilisation (Rowthorn, 1981) However, in the short run this link between changes in the degree of capacity utilisation and the profit margin is assumed away. We intend to reinstate this relation when we extend our short run macroeconomic model to the long run.
If the agricultural commodity is used as an input in the non-agricultural sector then either the profit margin in the non-agricultural sector or the nominal wage of workers will become endogenous. What is more plausible is that in the short run, the profit margin becomes endogenous while the nominal wage rate is exogenous. But in the long run, the profit margin attains some target level while real wages get squeezed due to the burgeoning reserve army of labour that characterises developing countries such as India.
In countries such as India, there were legal limits on stock-holding of agricultural produce by the private sector (before the Three Farm Laws that were imposed in 2020). We normalise that limit to zero to get the model of this section.
In particular we assume that there is no import or export of agricultural commodities. According to (DES, 2020) for the year 2018–2019, the share of wheat exports in total domestic production is 0.22%, the share of wheat imports in total domestic production is 0.003%, share of rice imports in total domestic production is 0.006% and share of rice exports in total domestic production is 10.4%. In case, India imported foodgrains then that would not only undermine domestic policy sovereignty but also increase these import prices since Indian imports would tend to be large relative to world trade in foodgrains.
(Patnaik, 1996) has argued that: “Experience has shown that larger investment in agriculture can call forth larger agricultural output (upon a socially narrow base of landlord capitalism), perhaps not indefinitely but certainly up to a point. What is essential is investment, and private investment here is complementary to public investment. More public irrigation for instance results not only in more private adoption of the seed-fertiliser technology, but also in more private irrigation”.
The concepts of surplus value and its realization and its decomposition into profit of enterprise, interest, rent etc. is discussed by (Marx, 2010[1867], (2010[1884], (2010[1894]).
Here we assume that different types of appropriators of realised surplus value among the rural elite save an identical fraction of their share of realised surplus value in the sector. Now \(p_a\) determines \(RS_A\) and \(p_a\) in turn is determined by Eq. (7). If there are two types of appropriators of \(RS_A\) who save different fractions of their share of \(RS_A\) then a redistribution of realised surplus value between these two will change the R.H.S of (7) and therefore \(p_a\) and consequently \(RS_A\).
In principle, any price could be the numeraire. However, since the demand and supply in the private market for the agricultural commodity is equated by price changes, since agricultural output is fixed in the short run, it is theoretically more appropriate, to posit the price of the non-agricultural commodity as the numeraire in the model of this paper.
Money is endogenous but implicit in the model. Since investment is given in the short run, the choice of capitalists between adding to fixed capital or hoarding money does not explicitly figure in the model.
Since the expression \((p_x^1-p_x^2)\) does not seem to have a definite sign we are unable to express the condition given by Eq. (18) more compactly.
A redistribution of realised surplus value between the rural elite and rural non-elite due to changes in the private procurement price will have a limited impact on \(RS_A\) as long as the share of the realised surplus that accrues to the rural non-elite is sufficiently small.
\(\sigma\) may be affected by a rise in \(p_a\). A fall in \(p_a\) will induce private procurers to sell more if they expect the future level of \(p_a\) to be lower than at present and vice versa. However, we have assumed in the paper that \(\sigma\) is a parameter for two reasons: first, it is a short run model with a given a level of expectations about the future trajectory of the private market price of agricultural produce (namely \(p_a\)); secondly, \(\sigma\) depends on both expectations about \(p_a\) and government policies regarding corporate encroachment; we sought to capture this policy process through the use of \(\sigma\) as a comparative statics parameter in the model of the paper. We postpone a discussion of this process to a long run extension of this model that we hope to undertake in the future.
It may be pointed out that the magnitude of private market sale of the agricultural commodity could also be expressed as \((1-\mu -\sigma )O_a\). But in this case, \(\sigma\) represents the share of total agricultural output that is added to the speculative stock of private procurers. Both definitions of \(\sigma\) are mathematically admissible.
A theoretical discussion of such issues is contained in (Saratchand, 2018).
Most developed economies have ensured adequate domestic food security through substantial subsidy based support to their agricultural sectors.
Reliance on food imports may have deleterious consequences on policy sovereignty.
A detailed survey of the literature on agricultural markets in India is undertaken in (Jan and Harriss-White, 2012).
After 1947, India traversed a dirigiste trajectory of accumulation of capital where the domestic big bourgeoisie has entered into a contradictory alliance with the landlords. It this contradictory alliance between the domestic big bourgeoisie and the landlords that had been put under some stress by the Three Farm Laws.
References
Balakrishnan, R. (2010). Corporate Entry into Agricultural Input and Output Markets and Its Impact on Small Producers and Consumers. Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65(1), 40–48.
Bhaduri, A., & Skarstein, R. (2003). Effective demand and the terms of trade in a dual economy: A Kaldorian perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27(4), 583–595.
Briones, Roehlano M., & Rakotoarisoa, Manitra A. (2013). Investigating the structures of agricultural trade industry in developing countries. FAO Commodity, Trade Policy Research Working Paper No. 38. Food, and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the United Nations.
Cáceres, D. M. (2015). Accumulation by Dispossession and Socio-Environmental Conflicts Caused by the Expansion of Agribusiness in Argentina. Journal of Agrarian Change, 15(1), 116–147.
Chakrabarti, S. (2014). The formal-informal dichotomy: Revisiting the debate on the agriculture-industry linkage. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 25(1), 154–178.
Christie, Neha. (2020). “Rethinking local institutional development in India: Theoretical perspectives and analysis of dairy cooperatives”. In Journal of Public Affairs. https://doi.org/10.1002/pa.2230. Paper not yet assigned to an issue of the journal. Link accessed on 31 December 2020.
Das, C. (1989). Food policy in a dual economy. In M. Rakshit (Ed.), Studies in the Macroeconomics of Developing Countries (pp. 66–93). Oxford University Press.
Das, Chandana. (1992). “Some aspects of interaction between industry and agriculture”. PhD thesis. Kolkata, India: University of Calcutta. https://shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/handle/10603/161802.
De Roy, S. (2017). Economic reforms and agricultural growth in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 52(9), 67–72.
DES. (2020). Agricultural statistics at a glance 2019. Tech. rep. Department of Agriculture, Cooperation and Farmers Welfare, Directorate of Economics and Statistics (DES). Government of India, Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare.
DFPD. (2020). Food Grain Bulletin 2020. Department of Food & Public Distribution (DFPD), Government of India.
FAO. (2003). “The Role of Transnational Corporations in Trade reforms and food security: conceptualizing the linkages”. In Trade Reforms And Food Security: Conceptualizing the Linkages. http://www.fao.org/3/y4671e/y4671e0e.htm#bm14. Link accessed on January 11, 2021. Commodity Policy et al.
FAO. (2018). Strengthening Sector Policies for Better Food Security and Nutrition Results: Public food procurement. Policy Guidance Note 11. http://www.fao.org/3/CA2281EN/ca2281en.pdf. Link accessed on December 23, 2020. Food and Agricultural Organisation.
Ghosh, J. (2020). A critique of the Indian government’s response to the COVID-19 pandemic. Journal of Industrial and Business Economics, 47(3), 519–530.
GOI. (2007). Report of the Working Group on Agricultural Marketing Infrastructure and Policy Required for Internal and External Trade for the XI Five Year Plan 2007-12. Planning Commission of India, Government of India (GOI).
GOI. (2011). Report of the Working Group on Agricultural Marketing Infrastructure and Policy Required for Internal and External Trade for the XII Five Year Plan 2012-17. Planning Commission of India, Government of India (GOI).
Gupta, Prankur, Khera, Reetika, & Narayanan, Sudha. (2021). “Minimum Support Prices in India: Distilling the Facts”. In Review of Agrarian Studies 11.1. http://ras.org.in/minimum_support_prices_in_india. Link accessed on December 5, 2021.
Hoda, A., & Gulati, A. (2008). WTO negotiations on agriculture and developing countries. The John Hopkins University Press and International Food Policy Research Institute.
Jan, Muhammad Ali, & Harriss-White, Barbara. (2012). “The three roles of agricultural markets: a review of ideas about agricultural commodity markets in India”. Economic and Political Weekly, pp. 39–52
Kalecki, M. (1993). Collected Works of Michal Kalecki. In J. Osiatynski (Ed.), Developing Economies. (Vol. V). Oxford University Press.
Luo, Qiangqiang, & Andreas, Joel. (2020). “Mobilizing compliance: How the state compels village households to transfer land to large farm operators in China”. The Journal of Peasant Studies, pp. 1–22.
Marx, Karl. (2010[1867]). “Capital: A Critique Of Political Economy Volume 1”. In Engels, Fredrick (ed.) Collected Works Of Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels. Vol. 35. Karl Marx - Capital Volume I. Originally published in 1867. Lawrence and Wishart.
Marx, Karl. (2010[1884]). “Capital: A Critique Of Political Economy Volume 2”. In Engels, Fredrick (ed), Collected Works Of Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels. Vol. 36. Karl Marx - Capital Volume II. Originally published in 1884. Lawrence and Wishart.
Marx, Karl. (2010[1894]). “Capital: A Critique Of Political Economy Volume 3”. In Engels, Fredrick (ed), Collected Works Of Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels. Vol. 37. Karl Marx - Capital Volume III. Originally published in 1894. Lawrence and Wishart.
McCombie, J. S. L., & Roberts, M. (2008). Effective-demand-constrained growth in a two-sector Kaldorian model. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 31(1), 57–78.
Mitra, Ashok. (1977). Terms of Trade and Class Relations: An Essay in Political Economy. Frank Cass.
Nayyar, D., & Sen, A. (1994). International trade and the agricultural sector in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 29(20), 1187–1203.
NSO. (2021). Situation Assessment of Agricultural Households and Land and Holdings of Households in Rural India, 2019. National Statistical Office (NSO), Government of India.
OECD. (2018). Agricultural Policies in India. https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/content/publication/9789264302334-en. Organisation for Economic Co-operation, Development (OECD), and Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264302334-en.
Patnaik, P. (1992). Terms of trade and the rate of inflation. In K. Basu & P. Nayak (Eds.), Development policy and economic theory (pp. 256–274). New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Patnaik, Prabhat. (ed.) (1995). Macroeconomics. Oxford in India Readings: Themes in Economics. Oxford University Press.
Patnaik, P. (1996). Trade as a mechanism of economic retrogression. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 24(1–2), 211–225.
Patnaik, P. (2011). On the Macroeconomics of a Colonial Economy. In P. Patnaik (Ed.), Excursus in History: Essays on Some Ideas of Irfan Habib (pp. 286–300). Tulika Books.
Patnaik, U., & Patnaik, P. (2021). Capital and Imperialism: Theory, History, and the Present. Columbia University Press.
Rakshit, M. (1982). The labour surplus economy: A neo-Keynesian approach. Macmillan.
Rakshit, Mihir. (ed.) (1989). Studies in the macroeconomics of developing countries. Oxford University Press.
Ramachandran, V. K. (1990). Wage labour and unfreedom in agriculture: an Indian case study. Clarendon Press.
Mohan Rao, J., & Storm, S. (1998). Distribution and growth in Indian agriculture. In T. J. Byres (Ed.), The Indian Economy: Major Debates Since Independence (pp. 192–248). Oxford University Press.
Rawal, Vikas, Patel, Suvidya, & Pais, Jesim. (2020). The Political Economy of Agricultural Market Reforms: An Analysis of the Farmers’ Produce Trade and Commerce (Promotion and Facilitation) Act, 2020. SSER Monograph 20/4. Society for Social and Economic Research.
Rowthorn, R. (1981). Demand, Real Wages and Economic Growth. Thames papers in political economy Autumn, 81(3), 1–39.
Sanyal, A., Mukherji, A., & Patnaik, P. (1989). Stocks, Credit and the Commodity Market: A Preliminary Exercise. In M. Rakshit (Ed.), Studies in the Macroeconomics of Developing Countries (pp. 111–128). Oxford University Press.
Saratchand, C. (2018). A preliminary theoretical examination of the targeted public distribution system in India. International Review of Applied Economics, 32(3), 331–347.
Shrimali, R. (2016). Accumulation by Dispossession or Accumulation without Dispossession: The case of contract farming in India. Human Geography, 9(3), 77–88.
Singh, S. (2002). Contracting out solutions: Political economy of contract farming in the Indian Punjab. World Development, 30(9), 1621–1638.
Skarstein, R. (1997). Development theory: A guide to some unfashionable perspectives. Oxford University Press.
Swaminathan, M. (2000). Weakening Welfare. LeftWord Books.
Taylor, L. (1983). Structuralist macroeconomics: Applicable models for the third world. Basic Books.
Taylor, L. (1991). Income distribution, inflation, and growth: lectures on structuralist macroeconomic theory. Mit Press.
Treat, Sharon Anglin. (2020). Revisiting Crisis by Design: Corporate concentration in agriculture. https://www.iatp.org/documents/revisiting-crisis-design-corporateconcentration-agriculture. Link accessed on January 11, 2021. Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, United States of America.
UNCTAD. (2009). World Investment Report: Transnational Corporations, Agricultural Production and Development. Tech. rep. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
Vergara-Camus, L., & Kay, C. (2017). The agrarian political economy of left-wing governments in Latin America: Agribusiness, peasants, and the limits of neodevelopmentalism. Journal of Agrarian Change, 17(2), 415–437.
Vicol, M. (2019). Potatoes, petty commodity producers and livelihoods: contract farming and agrarian change in Maharashtra, India. Journal of Agrarian Change, 19(1), 135–161.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Mathematical Appendix: Parameter Value Ranges
Mathematical Appendix: Parameter Value Ranges
All parameter values are positive. We set out below the ranges of those parameters which, in addition, have a positive upper bound.
Rights and permissions
Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.
About this article
Cite this article
De Roy, S., Saratchand, C. On the political economy of corporate encroachment in agriculture: short term macroeconomic concerns. Econ Polit 40, 869–897 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-023-00309-8
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-023-00309-8