Skip to main content
Log in

Transportation costs of vehicle recycling under Hotelling’s Duopoly competition

  • Published:
Journal of Industrial and Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We explore the spatial features of end-of-life product recyclers. Our motivation for this analysis comes from real-world data, which look very different because the change in the marginal transportation cost to distance seems negative. To tackle this question, a theoretical consideration is provided. The result derived from our analysis remains largely the same as that reported in conventional location theory. We utilize this puzzling data set to prove our analytical result, which has positive marginal transportation costs after proper empirical treatment. Combining the theoretical and empirical analyses that support agglomeration due to market competition, we conclude that it is important to prepare a place for recycling firms to foster the industry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Japan Automobile Recycling Promotion Center (the same data are summarized in Table 1 below.)

Fig. 2

Source: Automobile Inspection and Registration Information Association (https://www.airia.or.jp/publish/statistics/number.html) for automobile ownership and Japan Automobile Recycling Promotion Center (https://www.jarc.or.jp/) for the generation of ELVs

Fig. 3

Source: Data provided by the Japan Automobile Recycling Promotion Center

Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In most cases, a quadratic transportation cost function is applied.

  2. This is because our model is capped by the expected cost of illegal dumping.

  3. Following the seminal paper by Fullerton and Kinnaman (1995), many theoretical papers address end-of-life products or waste. However, most of these models are general equilibrium models and rarely consider spatial issues. Ichinose et al. (2015) explain spatial relationships in their empirical analysis. For recent developments in the economics of waste, see, for example, Shinkuma and Managi (2011).

  4. We assume that k is very high such that each consumer has inelastic demand for the service, but illegal dumping is much ‘cheaper’.

  5. See d’Aspremont et al. (1979) for details.

  6. The source is the same as Fig. 1.

  7. Note that eliminating the outlier at the top-right in Fig. 1 does not change the qualitative feature of Table 2. For example, the coefficient on \(\ln\) (distance) shifts to 0.2815 from 0.2803 in Table 2.

  8. Further information is available at the website of the Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry (METI). See http://www.meti.go.jp/policy/recycle/main/3r_policy/policy/pdf/ecotown/ecotown_casebook/english.pdf.

  9. Note that \(X_{a}<X_{b}\) does not ensure that \(D_{a}<D_{b}\) because \(D_{i}\) contains \(z_{i}\).

References

  • Bouckaert, J. (2000). Monopolistic competition with mail order business. Economics Letters, 66, 303–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, K. (2005). Price competition and product differentiation when consumers care for the environment. Environmental and Resource Economics, 31, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J., & Thisse, J. (1979). On Hotelling’s stability in competition. Econometrica, 47, 1145–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. (1984). Minimal and maximal product differentiation in Hotelling’s Duopoly. Economics Letters, 21, 67–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. (1986). The principle of minimum differentiation revisited. European Economic Review, 24, 345–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faccio, M., Persona, A., Sgarbossa, F., & Zanin, G. (2014). Sustainable S through the complete reprocessing of end-of-life product by manufacturers: A traditonal versus social responsibility company perspective. European Journal of Operation Research, 233, 359–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleischmann, M., Bloemhof-Ruwaard, J. M., Dekker, R., van der Laan, E., van Nunen, Jo A. E. E., & van Wassenhove, L. N. (1997). Quantitative models for reverse logistics: A review. European Journal of Operational Research, 103, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, D., & Kinnaman, T. (1995). Garbage, recycling, and illicit burning or dumping. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29, 78–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Govindana, K., Soleimanib, H., & Devika Kannan, D. (2015). Reverse logistics and closed-loop supply chain: A comprehensive review to explore the future. European Journal of Operation Research, 240, 603–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 36, 535–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ichinose, D., Yamamoto, M., & Yoshida, Y. (2015). The decoupling of affluence and waste discharge under spatial correlation: Do richer communities discharge more waste? Environment and Development Economics, 20, 161–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanan, G., Sasikumar, P., & Devika, K. (2010). A genetic algorithm approach for solving closed loop supply chain model: A case of battery recycling. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 34, 655–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kats, A. (1995). More on Hotelling’s stability in competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 89–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai, F., & Tsai, J. (2004). Duopoly locations and optimal zoning in a small open city. Journal of Urban Economics, 55, 614–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura, T. (2003). Consumer-benefiting exclusive territories. Canadian Journal of Economics, 36, 1007–1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niknejad, A., & Petrovic, D. (2014). Optimisation of integrated reverse logistics networks with different product recovery routes. European Journal of Operation Research, 238, 143–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pokharek, S., & Mutha, A. (2009). Perspectives in reverse logistics: A review. Resources, Conservation and Recyling, 53, 175–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shinkuma, Takayoshi, & Managi, Shunsuke. (2011). Waste and Recycling: Theory and Empirics (Routledge Studies in Ecological Economics). London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful for the financial support by Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (16K03617), Japanese Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology (Strategic Research Foundation at Private Universities, 2014–2018), and Japanese Ministry of Environment (The 4th Research on Environmental Economics and Policy).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masashi Yamamoto.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Proof of Proposition 1

Eliminating \(p_{a}\) and \(p_{b}\) from (3) by using \(p_{a}^{m}\) and \(p_{b}^{m}\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} h({\hat{x}},a,b) \equiv \gamma \left( 2{\hat{x}}+z_{b}-z_{a}-1\right) \left( |{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -1}+|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -1}\right) +|{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma }-|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma }=0. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

In our definition, \(h({\hat{x}}, a,b)=0\) holds for all \({\hat{x}}\) that correspond to (\(p_{a}^{m}, p_{b}^{m}\)), the Nash equilibrium prices in the second stage. Now, the profit functions in the first stage for firm i, \({\hat{\pi }}_{i}^{m}\), become

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{\pi }}_{a}^{m}&=p_{a}^{m} \left( {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})-z_{a}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(13)
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{\pi }}_{b}^{m}&=p_{b}^{m}\left( 1-{\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})-z_{b}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(14)

and each firm attempts to maximize its profit by changing its location on the line. Differentiating the above equations, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\hat{\pi }}_{a}^{m}}{\partial a}&=\frac{\partial p_{a}^{m}}{\partial a}\left( {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})-z_{a}\right) +\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial a}p_{a}^{m} \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\hat{\pi }}_{b}^{m}}{\partial b}&=\frac{\partial p_{b}^{m}}{\partial b}\left( 1-{\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})-z_{b}\right) -\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{b}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial b}p_{b}^{m}. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

If (15) is negative and (16) is positive, we have the usual maximal differentiation theorem with our remote market model for an end-of-life product. However, if we observe that (15) is positive and (16) is negative, a result â la Hotelling emerges.

To examine the above relationship, we first differentiate \(p_{a}^{m}\) and \(p_{b}^{m}\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{a}^{m}}{\partial a}&=-\gamma (\gamma -1)({\hat{x}}-z_{a})|{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -2} \end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p_{b}^{m}}{\partial b}&=\gamma (\gamma -1)(1-{\hat{x}}-z_{b})|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -2} \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Because we exclude the trivial case in which the nonresidential area exceeds each firm’s demand, the signs of (17) and (18) depend on the curvature of the transportation cost function.

Proof of Proposition 2

The first step to determine the signs of (15) and (16) is to differentiate \({\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m}, p_{b}^{m})\) with respect to a and b, which can be derived by applying the implicit function theorem to (12),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial a}&= -\frac{-\gamma (\gamma -1)\left( 2 {\hat{x}}+z_{b}-z_{a}-1\right) |{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -2}-\gamma |{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -1}}{3\gamma \left( |{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -1}+|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -1}\right) +\gamma (\gamma -1)\left( |{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -2}-|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -2}\right) \left( 2{\hat{x}}+z_{b}-z_{a}-1\right) } \nonumber \\&= \frac{(\gamma -1)(D_{a}-D_{b})X_{a}^{\gamma -2}+X_{a}^{\gamma -1}}{(\gamma -1)(D_{a}-D_{b})(X_{a}^{\gamma -2}-X_{b}^{\gamma -2})+3(X_{a}^{\gamma -1}+X_{b}^{\gamma -1})}, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial b}&= -\frac{\gamma (\gamma -1)(2 {\hat{x}}+z_{b}-z_{a}-1)|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -2}-\gamma |b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -1}}{3\gamma (|{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -1}+|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -1})+\gamma (\gamma -1)(|{\hat{x}}-a|^{\gamma -2}-|b-{\hat{x}}|^{\gamma -2})(2{\hat{x}}+z_{b}-z_{a}-1)} \nonumber \\&= \frac{-(\gamma -1)(D_{a}-D_{b})X_{b}^{\gamma -2}+X_{b}^{\gamma -1}}{(\gamma -1)(D_{a}-D_{b})(X_{a}^{\gamma -2}-X_{b}^{\gamma -2})+3(X_{a}^{\gamma -1}+X_{b}^{\gamma -1})}, \end{aligned}$$
(20)

where \(D_{a} \equiv {\hat{x}}-z_{a}\) and \(D_{b} \equiv 1-{\hat{x}}-z_{b}\), which denote the demand of each firm, and \(X_{a} \equiv |{\hat{x}}-a|\) and \(X_{b} \equiv |b-{\hat{x}}|\), respectively. These four are positive by definition.

Suppose that \(\gamma >1\). Then, (19) is negative if \(D_{a}<D_{b}\). Because \(X_{b}\) is a part of \(D_{b}\), we can state that \(X_{a}<X_{b}\).Footnote 9 Therefore, the denominator of (19) is positive. \(\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial a}\) becomes negative only when either the real demand of firm B, \(D_{b}\), or the curvature of the transportation cost is large enough to make the numerator of (19) negative. If \(D_{a}<D_{b}\), we automatically obtain that \(\frac{\partial {\hat{x}}(p_{a}^{m},p_{b}^{m})}{\partial b}>0\). In summary, we can state Proposition 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hosoda, E.B., Yamamoto, M. Transportation costs of vehicle recycling under Hotelling’s Duopoly competition. J. Ind. Bus. Econ. 48, 77–91 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-020-00148-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-020-00148-9

Keywords

JEL Classifcation

Navigation