Skip to main content
Log in

Who should bear the administrative costs of an emissions tax?

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

All environmental policies involve costs of implementation and management that are distinct from pollution sources’ abatement costs. In practice, regulators and sources usually share these administrative costs. We examine theoretically an optimal policy consisting of an emissions tax and the distribution of administrative costs between the government and regulated sources of pollution. Our focus is on the optimal distribution of administrative costs between polluters and the government and the optimal level of the emissions tax in relation to marginal pollution damage. We demonstrate how the policy variables affect aggregate equilibrium administrative costs and show that these effects are generally indeterminate, as is the effect of the distribution of administrative costs on aggregate emissions. Consequently, the optimal sharing of administrative costs and whether the optimal emissions tax is higher or lower than marginal damage depend on specific contexts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Others have investigated how administrative costs can affect the relative efficiency of taxes and other policy instruments. For example, Kampas and White (2004) provide an empirical analysis of the relative efficiency of several different policies for the control of an agricultural nonpoint pollutant. They find that the presence of administrative costs favors an input tax even though this instrument does not minimize aggregate abatement costs.

  2. See Tietenberg (2003) and Schrank et al. (2003) for examples of fees on fishing quota owners for recovering public management costs in several fisheries.

  3. These assumptions are also common in studies of emissions trading (Malik 1992; Stranlund 2007; Caffera and Chávez 2011), emissions standards (Arguedas 2008), as well as in the broader literature on the economic theory of law enforcement (Polinsky and Shavell 2000).

  4. Our model borrows from and extends the work of Polinsky and Shavell (1982) who examine how the structure and distribution of administrative costs affects the determination of an optimal emissions tax. There are several important differences between our effort and theirs, but the most important is that we look for the optimal sharing of administrative costs between regulated firms and the government, while they assume that the distribution is fixed and either the firms bear all administrative costs or the government does. We also allow for a difference in the costs of public funds and private funds and we incorporate an output market into the analysis, both of which turn out to have important impacts on the optimal distribution of administrative costs and the level of the emissions tax. Polinsky and Shavell (1982) do not include these features.

  5. We assume constant marginal damage to simplify the analysis. This assumption does not change our results.

  6. Recent work by Stranlund et al. (2009) suggests that there is a very limited set of circumstances under which it may be efficient to implement emissions taxes that are not fully enforced. Moreover, designing an enforcement strategy that induces full compliance is very simple, because it only requires that firms face an expected marginal penalty that exceeds the tax.

  7. The marginal cost of public funds is equal to one plus the marginal excess burden of taxation, where the latter is the efficiency loss of a higher tax per dollar of increased revenue. In their simulation study of the costs and distributional consequences of alternative policies to reduce U.S. \(\text{ CO }_{2}\) emissions, Parry and Williams (2010) set marginal excess burden equal to 25 cents. One may wonder why we model the difference between public and private costs when the government could use emissions tax receipts to finance its share of administrative costs. We do so because using the emissions tax revenue in this way would still involve an opportunity cost if that revenue could be used to help finance other government activities that would instead have been financed with other distortionary taxes.

  8. Note that the effects of the policy variables on industry output do not play a role in the determination of the optimal policy. This is due to the assumption of perfect competition in the output market, because firms choose efficient levels of output given the policy choice. In the conclusion we suggest that considering the optimal tax and distribution of administrative costs under imperfect competition is a worthwhile extension of this work.

  9. If public funds and private funds are equally costly (\(\mu =1\)) then we are in the situation specified in Proposition 1 and the distribution of administrative costs does not affect social welfare.

References

  • Arguedas, C. (2008). To comply or not to comply? Pollution standard setting under costly monitoring and sanctioning. Environmental and Resource Economics, 41(2), 155–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Evans, D. S. (1985). The economics of regulatory tiering. RAND Journal of Economics, 16(3), 398–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caffera, M., & Chávez, C. A. (2011). The cost-effective choice of policy instruments to cap aggregate emissions with costly enforcement. Environmental and Resource Economics, 50(4), 531–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., & Gahvari, F. (2002). Imperfect observability of emissions and second-best emission and output taxes. Journal of Public Economics, 85(3), 385–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, M. F., Gilpatric, S. M., & Liu, L. (2009). Regulation with direct benefits of information disclosure and imperfect monitoring. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 57(3), 284–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kampas, A., & White, B. (2004). Administrative costs and instrument choice for stochastic non-point source pollutants. Environmental and Resource Economics, 27, 109–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsoulacos, Y., & Xepapadeas, A. (1995). Environmental policy under oligopoly with endogenous market structure. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(3), 411–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler, I., & Perez-Castrillo, D. (2006). Optimal enforcement policy and firm’s emissions and compliance with environmental taxes. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 51(1), 110–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malik, A. (1992). Enforcement costs and the choice of policy instruments for controlling pollution. Economic Inquiry, 30(4), 714–721.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montero, J.-P. (2002). Prices versus quantities with incomplete enforcement. Journal of Public Economics, 85(3), 435–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry, I. W. H., & Williams, R. (2010). What are the costs of meeting distributional objectives for climate policy? NBER Working Paper No. 16486.

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (1982). Pigouvian taxation with administrative costs. Journal of Public Economics, 19, 385–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (2000). The economic theory of public enforcement of law. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(1), 45–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate, T. (2007). Environmental policy under imperfect competition. In T. Tietenberg & H. Folmer (Eds.), The international yearbook of environmental and resource economics 2006/2007: A survey of current issues (pp. 120–207). Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmutzler, A., & Goulder, L. H. (1997). The choice between emission taxes and output taxes under imperfect monitoring. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, 51–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schrank, W. E., Arnason, R., & Hannesson, R. (2003). The cost of fisheries management. Burlington, VT: Ashgate Publishing.

  • Smulders, S., & Vollebergh, H. R. J. (2001). Green taxes and administrative costs: The case of carbon taxation. In C. Carraro & G. E. Metcalf (Eds.), Behavioral and distributional effects of environmental policy (pp. 91–130). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund, J. K. (2007). The regulatory choice of noncompliance in emissions trading programs. Environmental and Resource Economics, 38(1), 99–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund, J. K., Chávez, C. A., & Villena, M. G. (2009). The optimal pricing of pollution when enforcement is costly. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 58(2), 183–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg, T. (2003). The tradable-permits approach to protecting the commons: Lessons for climate change. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 19(3), 400–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research has been supported by a grant from Conicyt-Chile, under project Fondecyt No. 1110073, and Fondecyt International Cooperation. Additional funding for this research was provided by the Cooperative State Research Extension, Education Service, U. S. Department of Agriculture, Massachusetts Agricultural Experiment Station under Project No. MAS00965. We would like to thank an anonymous referee of this journal for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John K. Stranlund.

Appendix

Appendix

Derivations of the results in Table 2. Use (2) and (3) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} S\left[ \begin{array}{l} q_{t}\\ x_{t} \end{array}\right] =\left[ \begin{array}{l} 0\\ 1+(1-\alpha )m_{xt} \end{array}\right] ,\; S\left[ \begin{array}{l} q_{\alpha }\\ x_{\alpha } \end{array}\right] =\left[ \begin{array}{c} 0\\ -m_{xt} \end{array}\right] ,\; \mathrm{and}\,\quad S\left[ \begin{array}{l} q_{p}\\ x_{p} \end{array}\right] =\left[ \begin{array}{l} -1\\ 0 \end{array}\right] ,\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(27)

where

$$\begin{aligned} S=\left[ \begin{array}{lc} -c_{qq} &{} -c_{qx}\\ -c_{xq} &{} -c_{xx}-(1-\alpha )m_{xx} \end{array}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Let \(|S|=c_{qq}\left( c_{xx}+(1-\alpha )m_{xx}\right) -\left( c_{qx}\right) ^{2}\) denote the determinant of the Hessian matrix of the firm’s total cost function (production cost plus the fraction of the administrative costs it bears). \(|S|>0\) is required for concavity of the firm’s profit function. In the usual manner find the following comparative statics:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{t}&\!= c_{qx}(c_{xx}\!+\!(1\!-\!\alpha )m_{xx})/|S|<0,\quad \, q_{\alpha }\!=\!-c_{qx}m_{x}/|S|\ge 0,\quad \mathrm{and}\nonumber \\&\,\,q_{p}\!=\!(c_{xx}\!+\!(1\!-\!\alpha )m_{xx})/|S|>0; \end{aligned}$$
(28)
$$\begin{aligned} x_{t}&\!= -c_{qq}(1\!+\!(1\!-\!\alpha )m_{xt})/|S|<0,\quad \, x_{\alpha }\!=\!c_{qq}m_{x}/|S|\ge 0,\quad \mathrm{and}\quad \nonumber \\&x_{p}\!=\!c_{xx}/|S|>0; \end{aligned}$$
(29)

To determine the direct effects of \(t,\, \alpha \), and \(p\) on the size of the industry substitute (5) into (4) to obtain \(\pi (t,\alpha ,p,\lambda ^{m})\equiv 0\) and:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{t}^{m}=(x+(1-\alpha )m_{t})/\pi _{\lambda }>0,\quad \lambda _{\alpha }^{m}=-m/\pi _{\lambda }\le 0,\quad \mathrm{and}\quad \lambda _{p}^{m}=-q/\pi _{\lambda }<0.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(30)

To determine the effects of \(t, \, \alpha \), and \(p\) on the supply function of the regulated industry, first define:

$$\begin{aligned} q^{m}=q(t,\alpha ,p,\lambda ^{m}) \quad \mathrm{and}\quad x^{m}=x(t,\alpha ,p,\lambda ^{m}) \end{aligned}$$
(31)

as the output and emissions of the cut-off firm in the industry. Then:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{p}^{S}(t,\alpha ,p)=\int _{\lambda ^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}q_{p}d\lambda -\lambda _{p}^{m}q^{m}>0; \end{aligned}$$
(32)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_{t}^{S}(t,\alpha ,p)=\int _{\lambda ^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}q_{t}d\lambda -\lambda _{t}^{m}q^{m}<0; \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_{\alpha }^{S}(t,\alpha ,p)=\int _{\lambda ^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}q_{\alpha }d\lambda -\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}q^{m}\ge 0; \end{aligned}$$
(34)

From the market-clearing condition \(Q^{S}(t,\alpha ,p)=Q^{D}(p)\) obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{p}_{t}=-Q_{t}^{S}/(Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D})>0\quad \,\mathrm{and}\quad \;\hat{p}_{\alpha }=-Q_{a}^{S}/(Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D})\le 0. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

The sign of \(\hat{p}_{t}\) follows from \(Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}>0\) and (33). The sign of \(\hat{p}_{\alpha }\) follows from \(Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}>0\) and (34), noting the sign of \(q_{\alpha }\) from (28).

The signs of \(\hat{x}_{t}\) and \(\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\) in Table 2 are by assumption as noted in section 2.3. The sign of \(\hat{x}_{\alpha }\) is demonstrated in the main text.

To show the results for \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}\), recall from (12) that \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}+\lambda _{p}^{m}\hat{p}_{\alpha }\). From Table 2, \(\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}=m_{x}=0\) imply \(\hat{p}_{\alpha }=0\), and \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=0\). Moreover, \(m_{x}>0\) and \(\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}=0\) imply \(\hat{p}_{\alpha }<0\). Then, since \(\lambda _{p}^{m}\hat{p}_{\alpha }>0, \, m_{x}>0\) and \(\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}=0\) imply \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}>0\). To show \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}<0\) when \(\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}<0\) and \(m_{x}=0\) use (35) and (34) to rewrite \(\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}+\lambda _{p}^{m}\hat{p}_{\alpha }\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}-\lambda _{p}^{m}\left\{ \frac{\int _{\lambda ^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}q_{\alpha }d\lambda -\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}q^{m}}{Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(m_{x}=0\) implies \(q_{\alpha }=0\) (see (28)):

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}\left\{ \frac{Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}+\lambda _{p}^{m}q^{m}}{Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

Substitute in for \(Q_{p}^{S}\) using (32) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}=\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}\left\{ \frac{\int _{\lambda ^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}q_{p}d\lambda -Q_{p}^{D}}{Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$

which is strictly negative when \(\lambda _{\alpha }^{m}<0\), because \(q_{p}>0,\, Q_{p}^{D}<0\), and \(Q_{p}^{S}-Q_{p}^{D}>0\).

Derivation of first order conditions (20) and (21). From (19) the first order condition for a strictly positive tax can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{t}(t,\alpha )&= p(\hat{Q})\left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{q_{t}}d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\hat{q}^{m}\right) \nonumber \\&-\left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}(c_{q}\hat{q}_{t}+c_{x}\hat{x}_{t})d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right) \nonumber \\&-\delta \left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{x}_{t}d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\hat{x}^{m}\right) \nonumber \\&-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )\left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}(m_{t}+m_{x}\hat{x}_{t})d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}m(t,\hat{x},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right) =0,\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(36)

where \(\hat{q}^{m}=q(t,\alpha ,\hat{p},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\) is the equilibrium output of the cut-off firm in the industry. From a firm’s first order conditions for its optimal choices of output and emissions (2), substitute \(p(\hat{Q})=c_{q}\) and \(t=-c_{x}-(1-\alpha )m_{x}\) into (36) and rearrange terms to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{t}(t,\alpha )&= \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\left( (t-\delta )\hat{x}_{t}-\alpha \mu m_{x}\hat{x}_{t}-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )m_{t}\right) d\lambda \nonumber \\&-\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\left( p(\hat{Q})\hat{q}^{m}-c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right. \nonumber \\&\left. -\delta \hat{x}^{m}-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right) =0. \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Substitute equilibrium values of the cut-off firm into (4) to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi (t,\alpha ,\hat{\lambda }^{m})=p\hat{q}^{m}-c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})-t\hat{x}^{m}-(1-\alpha )m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\equiv 0. \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Subtract \(\delta \hat{x}^{m}\) and \(\alpha \mu m(t,\hat{x}^{m})\) from both sides of (38) and rearrange terms to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&p\hat{q}^{m}-c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})-\delta \hat{x}^{m}-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m}) \nonumber \\&=(t-\delta )\hat{x}^{m}-\alpha \mu m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m}). \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Substitute (39) into (37) and rearrange terms to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{t}(t,\alpha )&= (t-\delta )\left\{ \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{x}_{t}d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\hat{x}^{m}\right\} \nonumber \\&-\alpha \mu \left\{ \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}(m_{t}+m_{x}\hat{x}_{t})d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right\} \nonumber \\&-(1-\alpha )\int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m_{t}d\lambda =0. \end{aligned}$$
(40)

Substitute (15) into (40) to obtain the desired result (20).

Now turn to the first order condition for \(\alpha \), which from (19) is:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{\alpha }(t,\alpha )&= p(\hat{Q})\left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{q}_{\alpha }d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}\hat{q}^{m}\right) \nonumber \\&-\left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}(c_{q}\hat{q}_{t}+c_{x}\hat{x}_{t})d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right) \nonumber \\&-\delta \left( \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{x}_{t}d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{t}^{m}\hat{x}^{m}\right) \nonumber \\&-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )\left\{ \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m_{x}\hat{x}_{\alpha }d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right\} \nonumber \\&-(\mu -1)\int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m(t,\hat{x},\lambda )d\lambda \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \le 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,<0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =0\\ \,\ge 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,>0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =1. \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
(41)

Substitute \(p(\hat{Q})=c_{q}\) and \(t=-c_{x}-(1-\alpha )m_{x}\) into (41) and rearrange terms to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{\alpha }(t,\alpha )&= \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\left( (t-\delta )\hat{x}_{\alpha }-\alpha \mu m_{x}\hat{x}_{\alpha }\right) d\lambda \nonumber \\&-\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}\left( p(\hat{Q})\hat{q}^{m}-c(\hat{q}^{m},\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})-\delta \hat{x}^{m}-(1-\alpha +\alpha \mu )m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right) \nonumber \\&-(\mu -1)\int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m(t,\hat{x},\lambda )d\lambda \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \le 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,<0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =0\\ \,\ge 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,>0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =1. \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Substitute (39) into (42) and rearrange terms to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{\alpha }(t,\alpha )&= (t-\delta )\left\{ \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}\hat{x}_{\alpha }d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}\hat{x}^{m}\right\} \nonumber \\&-\alpha \mu \left\{ \int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m_{x}\hat{x}_{\alpha }d\lambda -\hat{\lambda }_{\alpha }^{m}m(t,\hat{x}^{m},\hat{\lambda }^{m})\right\} \nonumber \\&-(\mu -1)\int _{\hat{\lambda }^{m}}^{\bar{\lambda }}m(t,\hat{x},\lambda )d\lambda \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \le 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,<0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =0\\ \,\ge 0,\quad \,\mathrm{if}\,>0,\quad \,\mathrm{then}\quad \,\alpha =1. \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Substitute (16) into (43) to obtain (21). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Stranlund, J.K., Chávez, C.A. Who should bear the administrative costs of an emissions tax?. J Regul Econ 44, 53–79 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-013-9216-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-013-9216-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation