Skip to main content
Log in

Amenities, Housing Affordability, and Education Elites

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Education Elites (i.e., higher-educated people) with new ideas and technologies are widely acknowledged to be a source of innovation and the engine of regional economic growth. A city that can attract higher-educated people will ultimately become the winner of future. This paper examines whether city amenities attract higher-educated people. Using three different datasets from China, we find that people with college degree or above are much more likely to choose the best amenity cites, which in fact results in 68.4% increase in the concentration of these higher-educated people. In addition, we find that people with master degree or above education can enjoy 45.61 percent income premium in the best amenity cities, and people with four-year college education can also enjoy 30.68 percent income premium. Furthermore, we find that these higher-educated people have much higher satisfaction on income and job promotion opportunity. However, with prices soaring in the best amenity cities, housing becomes increasingly unaffordable. In fact, we find strong evidence that the attractiveness of the best amenity cities has declined over time. This finding suggests that policies that curb the rapid increase in housing prices in the best amenity cities are necessary for local governments in order for their cities continuing to be the winner of future.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 68.4% is obtained by calculating the ratio of 5.4% to 7.9%, i.e., 5.4%/7.9%=68.4%.

  2. We would like to thank Seow Eng Ong, K. W. Chau, X. H. Bao, Jing Wu and Chengdong Yi for their insightful comments on this issue.

  3. 67.09%=(13.2%-7.9%)/7.9%.

  4. Hukou refers to the household residential registration. Under the household registration (hukou) system, citizen with hukou are eligible for specific local benefits, including access to health care, free public education, housing, better access to job, which citizens without hukou are not (Au and Henderson, 2006).

  5. 1) 68.4% is obtained by calculating the ratio of 5.4% to 7.9%, i.e., 5.4%/7.9%=68.4%.

  6. Unfortunately, the households in UHS 2007-2009 are completely different from those in UHS 2002-2006.

References

  • Au, C.-C., & Henderson, V. (2006). Are chinese cities too small? Review of Economic Studies, 73(3), 549–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (2001). Human capital and growth. The American Economic Review, 91(2), 12–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner, J., Thisse, J.-F., & Zenou, Y. (1999). Why Is Central Paris Rich and Downtown Detroit Poor? European Economic Review, 43(1), 91–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camagni, R. (2002). On the concept of territorial competitiveness: sound or misleading? Urban Studies, 39(13), 2395–2411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D., & Cosgrove, J. (1991). Amenities versus labor market opportunities: choosing the optimal distance to move. Journal of Regional Science, 31(3), 311–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D., & Hunter, W. (1992). The impact of economic opportunity, amenities and fiscal factors on age-specific migration rates. Journal of Regional Science, 32(3), 349–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, T. N., Lloyd, R., Wong, K., & Jain, P. (2002). Amenities drive urban growth. Journal of Urban Affairs, 24(5), 493–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D., Herrin, W., Knapp, T., & White, N. (2003). Migration and implicit amenity markets: does incomplete compensation matter? Journal of Economic Geography, 3(3), 289–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehejia, R., & Wahba, S. (2002). Propensity score-matching methods for nonexperimental causal studies. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1), 151–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong, Y. (2016). A note on geographical constraints and housing markets in China. Journal of Housing Economics, 33, 15–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farber, S. (1983). Post-Migration Earnings Profiles: An Application of Human Capital and Job Search Models. Southern Economic Journal, 49(3), 693–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fields, G. (1979). Place-to-place migration: some new evidence. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 61(1), 21–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florida, R., Mellander, C., & Stolarick, K. (2008). Inside the black box of regional development - human capital, the creative class and tolerance. Journal of Economic Geography, 8(5), 615–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., Kolko, J., & Saiz, A. (2001). Consumer city. Journal of Economic Geography, 1(1), 27–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, M., & Hunt, G. (1989). Jobs versus amenities in the analysis of metropolitan migration. Journal of Urban Economics, 25(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, M., Hunt, G., & McDowell, J. (1986). Migration and employment change: empirical evidence on the spatial and temporal dimensions of the linkage. Journal of Regional Science, 26(2), 223–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gyourko, J., Mayer, C., & Sinai, T. (2013). Superstar cities, American Economic Journal. Economic Policy, 5(4), 167–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., Ichimura, H., & Todd, P. (1997). Matching as an econometric evaluation estimator: evidence from evaluating a job training programme. The Review of Economic Studies, 64(4), 605–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemeny, T., & Storper, M. (2012). The sources of urban development: wages, housing, and amenity gaps across american cities. Journal of Regional Science, 52(1), 85–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleibergen, F., & Paap, R. (2006). Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. Journal of Econometrics, 133(1), 97–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knapp, T., & Graves, P. (1989). On the role of amenities in models of migration and regional development. Journal of Regional Science, 29(1), 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka, D. (2009). Location-specific human capital, location choice and amenity demand. Journal of Regional Science, 49(5), 833–854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang, W., Lu, M., & Zhang, H. (2016). Housing prices raise wages: estimating the unexpected effects of land supply regulation in China. Journal of Housing Economics, 33, 70–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malecki, E. (2004). Jockeying for position: what it means and why it matters to regional development policy when places compete. Regional Studies, 38(9), 1101–1120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, A. (1996). Sticky places in slippery space: A typology of industrial districts. Economic Geography, 72(3), 293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueser, P., & Graves, P. (1995). Examining the role of economic opportunity and amenities in explaining population redistribution. Journal of Urban Economics, 37(2), 176–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Bureau of Statistics of China (2017), China Statistical Year book

  • Niedomysl, T. (2004). Evaluating the effects of place-marketing campaigns on interregional migration in sweden. Environment and Planning A, 36(11), 1991–2009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pack, J. R. (1973). Determinants of migration to central cities. Journal of Regional Science, 13(2), 249–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pholphirul, P., & Rukumnuaykit, P. (2010). Economic contribution of migrant workers to Thailand. International Migration, 48(5), 174–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. (1961). Investment in human capital. The American Economic Review, 51(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, J. (2006). Smart Cities: Quality of life, productivity, and the growth effects of human capital. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(2), 324–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjaastad, L. (1962). The costs and returns of human migration. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5, Part 2), 80–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In D. W. K. Andrews & J. H. Stock (Eds.), Identification and Inference for Econometric Models (pp. 80–108). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ullman, E. (1954). Amenities as a factor in regional growth. Geographical Review, 44(1), 119–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J., Gyourko, J., & Deng, Y. (2016). Evaluating the risk of chinese housing markets: what we know and what we need to know. China Economic Review, 39(1), 91–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yap, L. (1977). The attraction of cities: a review of the migration literature. Journal of Development Economics, 4(3), 239–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng, S., Cao, J., Kahn, M., & Sun, C. (2014). Real estate valuation and cross-boundary air pollution externalities: evidence from chinese cities. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 48(3), 398–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Mingzhi Hu acknowledges the supports from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (72104088 and 72074097), the Natural Science Foundation of Guangdong Province (2020A1515010359), the Key Project of Natural Science Foundation of Zhejiang Province (LZ20G030002), and the Major Research Project of Philosophy and Social Sciences of the Ministry of Education (18JZD033)

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhenguo Lin.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hu, M., Lin, Z. & Liu, Y. Amenities, Housing Affordability, and Education Elites. J Real Estate Finan Econ 66, 141–168 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-022-09896-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-022-09896-y

Keywords

JEL classification:

Navigation