Skip to main content
Log in

A Housing Supply Absorption Rate Equation

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

What is the optimal rate of new housing supply? We answer this question with a simple model of new housing supply where the choice variable is the rate of new housing lot sales. This model is informed by the cost-side assumptions of the static equilibrium model but allows for demand for home-buying to vary over time. It differs from static models of housing production equilibrium by assuming that landowners hold land assets that are sold in asset markets to create new supply. Landowners maximise the present value of their balance sheet by choosing a rate of new housing lot sales, accounting for the effect on asset price growth from their sales in a housing market of finite depth. The resulting absorption rate equation has radically different parameter effects compared to the popular static housing density model. Constraints on density, for example, increase the optimal rate of supply by reducing the return to delaying development. Interest rates, land value tax rates, and demand growth, positively relate to the optimal rate of supply. The policy lessons are (1) the relationship between demand growth and the optimal supply rate limits the ability for market supply to reduce prices, and (2) increasing the cost to delaying housing development is the primary way to increase the market rate of housing supply.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Over two decades ago (DiPasquale 1999) noted that

    Virtually every paper written on housing supply begins with some version of the same sentence: while there is an extensive literature on the demand for housing, far less has been written about housing supply. Although this statement is clearly true, at this point, there have actually been a considerable number of papers on housing supply. However, the empirical evidence on the supply of housing is far less convincing than that on the demand for housing. (p.9)

    Little has changed. Indeed, the cost-based approach to housing supply, such as used in Glaeser and Gyourko (2018), remains dominant despite being repeatedly discredited (Murray 2020b; Somerville 2005; O’Flaherty 2003).

  2. The academic debate surrounding the effect of planning changes on the rate of housing supply and prices remains hotly contested (Manville 2019, 2020; Rodríguez-Pose and Storper 2020; Cowan 2019; Monkkonen 2019; Wiener 2020; Wegmann 2019). Despite this, the pop-culture position seems to be that planning has extremely large effects on housing affordability (see, for example, Cowan (2019) and Yglesias 2012), and has resulted in many planning reform proposals (MHCLG 2020; Wiener 2020; Hansen 2020).

  3. As described in the studies of housing supply studies of Murray (2020c) and Letwin (2018). The absorption rate puzzle applies to any single subdivision and also across the set of feasible and allowable development sites in a region.

  4. For example, this is the result of the canonical Alonso-Muth-Mills model of a mono-centric city, which is widely used and forms the theoretical backbone of most analysis of housing supply (Kendall and Tulip 2018; Gyourko and Molloy 2015; Paciorek 2013; Quigley and Rosenthal 2005; Glaeser et al. 2005; Brueckner et al. 1987)

  5. For example (Lange and Teulings (2018); Murphy (2018); Jou and Lee (2007); Capozza and Li(2002, 1994); Tse (1998); Titman (1985)).

  6. As Pines (1989) notes, the static approach “is useless in explaining many stylized facts regarding the urban structure and its evolution through time. In the static analysis... land is continuously utilized within the city boundaries and the city boundaries are continuously extended with income and population size...The reason for the failure of the static model in explaining these ’irregularities’ is that the housing stock is assumed to be perfectly malleable, which, of course, is highly unrealistic.”

  7. There is often confusion in the housing supply literature between the rental price of a dwelling and the capital value of a dwelling. A divergence between these prices cannot be attributed to supply-side effects; they must be due to asset-pricing factors, such as low interest rates or growth expectations.

  8. Some examples of land and housing supply research adopting this real options approach are (Bulan et al. 2009/5//; Yang and Wu 2019; Tse 1998; Titman 1985).

  9. To check second order conditions of a maximisation, take the second derivative with respect to qt to get − 2aωp.

References

  • Ball, M, Meen, G, & Nygaard, C. (2010). Housing supply price elasticities revisited: Evidence from international, national, local and company data. Journal of Housing Economics, 19(4), 255–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentick, BL. (1979). The impact of taxation and valuation practices on the timing and efficiency of land use. Journal of Political Economy, 87(4), 859–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner, JK, & et al. (1987). The structure of urban equilibria: A unified treatment of the Muth-Mills model. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, 2(20), 821–845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulan, L, Mayer, C, & Somerville, CT. (2009/5//). Irreversible investment, real options, and competition: Evidence from real estate development. Journal of Urban Economics, 65(3), 237–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capozza, D, & Li, Y. (1994). The intensity and timing of investment: The case of land. The American Economic Review, 84(4), 889–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Capozza, DR, & Li, Y. (2002). Optimal land development decisions. Journal of Urban Economics, 51(1), 123–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cont, R, Kukanov, A, & Stoikov, S. (2013). The Price Impact of Order Book Events. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 12(1), 47–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, J. (2019). Should California get rid of single-family zoning? New York Times.

  • DiPasquale, D. (1999). Why don’t we know more about housing supply?. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 18(1), 9–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gatheral, J, & Schied, A. (2013). Dynamical models of market impact and algorithms for order execution. In Fouque, J.-P., & Langsam, J.A. (Eds.) Handbook On Systemic Risk (pp. 579–599).

  • Glaeser, EL, Gyourko, J, & Saks, R. (2005). Why is manhattan so expensive? Regulation and the rise in housing prices. The Journal of Law and Economics, 48(2), 331–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E, & Gyourko, J. (2018). The economic implications of housing supply. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(1), 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gyourko, J, & Molloy, R. (2015). Regulation and housing supply. In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, (Vol. 5 pp. 1289–1337): Elsevier.

  • Hansen, M. (2020). Adopt the missing middle housing act and provide zoning regulation requirements for certain cities. Technical report, Nebraska 106th Legislature.

  • Huck, S, Normann, HT, & Oechssler, J. (2003). Zero-knowledge cooperation in dilemma games. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 220(1), 47–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S, Normann, HT, & Oechssler, J. (2004). Through trial and error to collusion. International Economic Review, 45(1), 205–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jou, JB, & Lee, T. (2007). Do tighter restrictions on density retard development?. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34(2), 225–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, R, & Tulip, P. (2018). The effect of zoning on housing prices: Research Discussion Paper 2018-03. Reserve Bank of Australia.

  • Kulish, M, Richards, A, & Gillitzer, C. (2012). Urban structure and housing prices: Some evidence from Australian cities. Economic Record, 88(282), 303–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, R-J, & Teulings, C N. (2018). The option value of vacant land and the optimal timing of city extensions. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP12847.

  • Lees, K. (2018). Quantifying the costs of land use regulation: Evidence from New Zealand. New Zealand Economic Papers, 1–25.

  • Lendlease. (2019). Annual report 2018-19. Technical report.

  • Letwin, O. (2018). Independent review of build out rates - annexes: Ministry of Housing, Communities and Local Government.

  • Lewis, S A. (2017). Reconciling australian planning, development and housing outcomes. Ph.D. Thesis, Faculty of Architecture, Design and Planning. University of Sydney.

  • Manville, P L M. (2019). It’s time to end single-family zoning. Journal of the American Planning Association, 1–7.

  • Manville, M, Lens, M, & Monkkonen, P. (2020). Zoning and affordability: A reply to Rodríguez-Pose and Storper. Urban Studies, 0042098020910330.

  • MHCLG. (2020). Planning for the future: White paper: Ministry of Housing, Communities and Local Government.

  • Mills, DE. (1981). The non-neutrality of land value taxation. National Tax Journal, 34(1), 125–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monkkonen, P. (2019). The elephant in the zoning code: Single family zoning in the housing supply discussion. Housing Policy Debate, 29(1), 41–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, A. (2018). A dynamic model of housing supply. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10(4), 243–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray, CK. (2018). Developers pay developer charges. Cities, 74, 1–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray, CK. (2020a). The Australian housing supply myth. Open Science Foundation.

  • Murray, CK. (2020b). Marginal and average prices of land lots should not be equal: A critique of Glaeser and Gyourko’s method for identifying residential price effects of town planning regulations. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space, 0308518X20942874.

  • Murray, CK. (2020c). Time is money: How landbanking constrains housing supply. Journal of Housing Economics, 49, 101708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Flaherty, B. (2003). Commentary (on Glaeser and Gyourko). Federal Reserve Bank of New York Policy Review, 9(2), 41–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paciorek, A. (2013). Supply constraints and housing market dynamics. Journal of Urban Economics, 77, 11–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pines, D. (1989). Handbook of regional and urban economics, volume 2: Urban economics,: edited by Edwin S. Mills (North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1987). Regional Science and Urban Economics, 19(4), 646–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quigley, JM, & Rosenthal, LA. (2005). The effects of land use regulation on the price of housing: What do we know? What can we learn? Cityscape, 69–137.

  • Rodríguez-Pose, A, & Storper, M. (2020). Dodging the burden of proof: A reply to Manville, Lens and Mönkkönen. Urban Studies, 0042098020948793.

  • Somerville, CT. (2005). Zoning and affordable housing: A critical review of Glaeser and Gyourko’s paper: Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation.

  • Titman, S. (1985). Urban land prices under uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 75(3), 505–514.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tse, R Y C. (1998). Housing price, land supply and revenue from land sales. Urban Studies, 35(8), 1377–1377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wegmann, J. (2019). Death to single-family zoning…and new life to the missing middle. Journal of the American Planning Association, 86(1), 113–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiener, S. (2020). Sb-50 planning and zoning: housing development: streamlined approval: incentives: California State Senate.

  • Woodcock, I, Dovey, K, Wollan, S, & Robertson, I. (2011). Speculation and resistance: constraints on compact city policy implementation in Melbourne. Urban Policy And Research, 29(4), 343–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Z, & Wu, S. (2019). Land acquisition outcome, developer risk attitude and land development timing. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 59(2), 233–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yglesias, M. (2012). The rent is too damn high: What to do about it, and why it matters more than you think: Simon and Schuster.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cameron K. Murray.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This project was funded by the Henry Halloran Trust. https://sydney.edu.au/henry-halloran-trust/Thanks to Thomas Aubrey, Troy Presley, Graeme Guthrie, Karl Fitzgerald, Peter Tulip, and Fergus Cumming for comments on early drafts.

Appendix: : Representative Housing Owner Absorption Rate

Appendix: : Representative Housing Owner Absorption Rate

A more general version of this absorption rate approach assumes the representative agent not only supplies new housing lots but owns all housing once developed. In this model environment the dynamic maximisation problem is as per (14).

$$ \max\limits_{q_{t}} {\int}_{0}^{\infty} e^{-i t} \text{Return}(Q_{t},q_{t}) dt. $$
(14)

Notably, the effect of land holding taxes is removed from the discounting process as the representative agent pays these taxes with or without housing on the site and it therefore does not enter the timing decision. Here, the housing stock, Qt, is the state variable that evolves subject to new dwelling supply, qt, and the dwelling value, Pt, is the capitalised value of the housing rent resulting from that housing stock at a fixed capitalisation rate, i.

The two economic returns of interest for solving this maximisation problem are for (1) converting a lot into housing, and (2) retaining a housing lot undeveloped. The return from converting a lot into housing is the rent minus the interest on development cost, plus the dwelling price growth (the capital gain), minus any land rents from lower value uses on the site that must be given up. We show this in the first term of Eq. 15 which shows the problem redefined as an optimisation of the instantaneous rate of new supply according to Bellman’s maximisation principle. The economic return from delaying converting a lot into housing is the capital gain of that land, which is the dwelling price gain scaled by ω.

$$ \text{Return}_{t} =\underbrace{q_{t}(p_{t} + \dot{P}_{t}-C_{FC} i - r_{L})}_{\text{Net dwelling return}} + \underbrace{q_{t}(\omega \dot{P}_{t}(q_{t}))}_{\text{Land capital gain}} $$
(15)

To determine housing rents we borrow directly from the static model where housing rents are determined by incomes, housing preferences, and housing stock, such that pt = αyt/Qt. Price growth forms part of the return to owning housing and in this setup is the capitalised time derivative of rents. The cost of development is scaled so that at the current optimal density CFC is the per dwelling average cost, meaning that in annual flow terms the development costs is CFCi. The forgone rents from lower value uses are rL. The return to delay is represented by the capital gains that occur on land in the absence of development, which in this case is the capitalised change in rent (the capital gain) of the dwelling scaled by the diseconomies of density relationship ω to capture the change in optimal density with price. The complete problem setup is in Eq. 16.

$$ \text{Return}_{t} =\max\limits_{q_{t}} \left\{q_{t} \underbrace{\left( \frac{\alpha y_{t}}{Q_{t}} + \frac{\frac{\alpha \dot{y}_{t}}{Q_{t}}-\frac{\alpha y_{t} q_{t}}{{Q_{t}^{2}}}}{i}- C_{FC} i -r_{L}\right)}_{\text{Net rent plus cap. gain (now)}} + q_{t}\underbrace{\left( \omega \frac{\frac{\alpha \dot{y}_{t}}{Q_{t}}-\frac{\alpha y_{t} q_{t}}{{Q_{t}^{2}}}}{i}\right)}_{\text{Scaled cap. gain (later)}} \right\} $$
(16)

The problem is solved by taking the derivative of the return with respect to qt and setting to zero, giving

$$ \frac{\alpha y_{t}}{Q_{t}} - \frac{2 \alpha y_{t} q_{t}}{i {Q_{t}^{2}}} - C_{FC} - r_{L} + \frac{\omega \alpha \dot{y}_{t}}{i Q_{t}} - \frac{2 \omega \alpha y_{t} q_{t}}{i {Q_{t}^{2}}}=0 $$

then solving for qt. Second order conditions for a maximum are confirmed by the second derivative result of \(-\frac {(1+\omega ) 2 \alpha y_{t}}{i {Q_{t}^{2}}}\). Solving for qt and rearranging provides the solution for the equilibrium new housing supply in Eq. 17.

$$ q^{*}_{t} = \underbrace{Q}_{\text{Stock}} \frac{1}{2} \left( \underbrace{\frac{\dot{y}_{t}}{y_{t}}}_{\text{Income growth rate}} + \underbrace{\frac{i}{(1+\omega)}}_{\text{Intertemporal cost}} \left( \underbrace{1-\frac{Q(C_{FC}i+r_{L})}{\alpha y_{t}}}_{\text{Land rent share of gross rent}} \right) \right) $$
(17)

The first term in parentheses is the income growth rate. The second term is the product of the land rent share of gross dwelling rent (which is bound by 0 and 1 for profitable developments) and the intertemporal cost of earning that land rent which is the interest rate augmented by the efficiency of density, ω.

Substituting our optimal supply, \(q_{t}^{*}\) for q provides the following housing rental growth rate (and hence price growth rate when the capitalisation rate is fixed) with the equilibrium rate new supply.

$$ \frac{\dot{r}_{t}}{r_{t}} =g^{*}_{t} = \frac{1}{2} \left( \frac{\dot{y}_{t}}{y_{t}} + \frac{i}{(1+\omega)} \left( \frac{Q(C_{FC}i+r_{L})}{\alpha y_{t}}-1\right)\right) $$
(18)

We know that \(\frac {Q(C_{FC}i+r_{L})}{\alpha y_{t}}-1<0\) for any feasible development. Hence the rental growth rate will be less than half the rate of demand growth \(\frac {\dot y_{t}}{y_{t}}\) in this dynamic equilibrium.

How much less depends on a number of factors. An ability to increase density cheaper, or a higher ω, will increase the price growth rate, as well a higher ratio of development costs in flow terms compared to the housing rent. The effect of interest rates depends on the relative effect on the cost of borrowing for development (in the CFCi term) and its effect on inter-temporal optimisation (in the i/(1 + ω) term).

The main difference between the representative dwelling owner agent problem and the agent selling housing lots is the effect of the net land rent. In this formulation, the land rent from its use as housing is forgone when delaying development rather than the interest on land value. In this problem setup, reductions in the fixed cost of housing development increase net land rents from developing housing and accelerate supply. The same effect can be achieved by reducing rental income from lower value uses, or increasing holding costs in a way that reduces the net rental income while delaying housing development. In places where built-to-rent landlords dominate the housing market, these effects may be important.

Another difference is that the own-price effect from developing housing comes via the housing rental market rather than the housing asset market, i.e. α reflects the sensitivity of rent to new rental supply, while a represents the sensitivity of price to new housing lot sales. Lastly, the demand growth effect in this model comes via population and/or income growth, which translates into rental housing demand.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Murray, C.K. A Housing Supply Absorption Rate Equation. J Real Estate Finan Econ 64, 228–246 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-020-09815-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-020-09815-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation