1 Introduction

A target price is an analyst’s explicit forecast of where a firm’s stock price will be in 12 months’ time and is a key part of their report. While it is well documented that analysts’ target prices contain information about future stock returns (Brav and Lehavy 2003; Asquith et al. 2005; Da and Schumberg 2011; Gleason et al. 2013; Dechow and You 2020), less attention has been put on investigating the mispricing versus risk-related components of this predictive power. This paper aims to isolate and study the mispricing component using the target prices and costs of equity disclosed by US and international analysts, controlling for the risk-related component.

While analysts face strong incentives to provide information that investors can use to earn abnormal returns in general (Irvine 2004; Mikhail et al. 2007), we hypothesize that target prices indicating analyst-claimed undervaluation are more predictive of future stock returns than those indicating analyst-claimed overvaluation. We propose that this asymmetry arises because of the asymmetry in the incentives that managers face to supply value-relevant information to analysts, combined with asymmetry in how analysts convert this information into target prices.

The first asymmetry we highlight is that managers face compensation-based incentives that asymmetrically orient them toward revealing good news rather than bad news (Kothari et al. 2009; Feng and McVay 2010). That is, firms are more likely to supply analysts with information that is relevant to when their equity is undervalued than when it is overvalued. This asymmetry is important for analysts’ target prices because managers are an important information source for analysts (Green et al. 2014; Soltes 2014). While managers also supply value-relevant information to investors at large via public disclosures (Francis et al. 1997), managers may guide analysts to better understand the firm’s performance in their private interactions (Brown et al. 2015; Francis et al. 1997; Soltes 2014), leading to analysts’ outputs that predict market price adjustments (Gleason and Lee 2003). The combination of manager incentives toward revealing good news and analysts being the channel for such revelation leads us to hypothesize that managers will be more likely to supply analysts with information that is relevant to their firm being undervalued rather than to being overvalued, and thus that analysts’ target prices will be more likely to embed value-relevant information provided by managers when analysts’ target prices signal that the stock is undervalued than overvalued.

Reinforcing the first asymmetry above is a second asymmetry—namely, that managers may be more willing to provide private information to analysts with optimistic views of the company (Lin and McNichols 1998; Chen and Matsumoto 2006). This asymmetry is important because analysts who claim undervaluation are more likely to have access to private information from managers. However, the higher information content of analysts’ claimed undervaluation may be offset by optimistic target prices or an excess weighting of managers’ guidance (Francis and Philbrick 1993; Feng and McVay 2010). Combined, these two asymmetries lead us to our main hypothesis that analyst-claimed undervaluation will be more predictive of future stock returns than will analyst-claimed overvaluation.

We also expand beyond our main hypothesis by exploring four supplemental hypotheses. First, because target prices are inherently noisy predictors of returns (Dechow and You 2020), analysts often issue ‘bold’ or ‘strategically magnified’ price targets to better highlight to investors that they have value-relevant information (Clement and Tse 2005). In addition, because analysts’ signals of overvaluation may be optimistically biased to gain access to managers, signals that a stock may be undervalued may be optimistic. We therefore predict that analyst-claimed undervaluation will map into future returns in a less than dollar-for-dollar manner.

Second, if the information in analysts’ target prices is obtained from private interactions with managers about publicly available information (Brown et al. 2015; Francis et al. 1997; Soltes 2014), we expect the information content of analysts’ target prices to be short lived. This reasoning comes from the evidence that mispricing is corrected over time (Bernard and Thomas 1989; Lee et al. 1999). We therefore predict that analyst-claimed undervaluation will be less predictive of future stock returns the further the returns are beyond the analyst’s report date.

Third, stronger recent declines in a firm’s stock price put more pressure on managers to communicate with investors and correct undervaluation (Bushee and Miller 2012; Sletten 2012). Price declines also create stronger incentives for analysts to build into their target prices manager-supplied information that is relevant to undervaluation (Cunningham 2021; Graham and Zweig 2006; Keshk and Wang 2018). Accordingly, we predict that the mapping of analyst-claimed undervaluation into future returns will be negatively associated with prior-period returns.

Lastly, prior research suggests that analysts’ ability to identify mispricing is weaker and managers supply less value-relevant information when macro uncertainty is high (Amiram et al. 2018; Hope and Kang 2005; Kim et al. 2016). In combination with macroeconomic uncertainty, analysts acquire less private information when earnings volatility is high (Altschuler et al. 2015). The link between uncertainty and analysts’ access to private information leads to our prediction that the mapping of analyst-claimed undervaluation into future returns will be negatively related to macro-driven valuation uncertainty.

We center the empirical tests of our hypotheses on analyst-claimed mispricing, MIS, defined as the ex-dividend predicted return implied by the analyst’s target price, IRET, less the analyst’s estimate of the firm’s cost of equity, COE. We then isolate analyst-claimed undervaluation from overvaluation by defining UNDERVAL as MIS > 0 and OVERVAL as MIS ≤ 0. We use analysts’ target prices and costs of equity from US and international company analyst reports in Thomson ONE’s Investext database that contain the text string “cost of equity.” From each report, we extract COE as well as the one-year-ahead target price, the firm’s ticker, and other items. After matching to realized stock return and annual financial statement data, we arrive at a panel dataset of 9,781 US and 64,285 international analyst-firm-report observations over the years 2001–2017.

To test our main hypothesis that analyst-claimed undervaluation will better predict stock returns than will analyst-claimed overvaluation, we regress realized one-year-ahead ex-dividend stock returns, FRET, on COE, UNDERVAL, and OVERVAL. We increase the power of our regressions by controlling for firm characteristics commonly seen as capturing priced risk exposures (Fama and French 2015) and by including company, issuer, and year fixed effects. We find that the target prices of US and international analysts reliably predict stock returns when analysts claim undervaluation, but not when they claim overvaluation.

Next, consistent with our first supplemental hypothesis, we document that analyst-claimed undervaluation maps into future returns in a way that is reliably less than dollar-for-dollar—just 18 cents per dollar for US analysts and 16 cents per dollar for international analysts. Consistent with our second supplemental hypothesis, we show that analyst-claimed undervaluation is reliably positively related to future returns one- and two-quarters ahead, but not beyond the second quarter. Lastly, consistent with our third and fourth supplemental hypotheses, we observe that the mapping of analyst-claimed undervaluation into future returns is reliably negatively related to prior-period firm-returns and to macro-driven valuation uncertainty as proxied by the standard deviation of the returns implied by analysts’ target prices, measured at the country level over the year prior to analysts’ report dates.

We see our study as contributing to the literature on analyst target prices in several ways. By means of analysts’ COE estimates, we introduce an economically grounded way of isolating the mispricing-claimed component of analysts’ target prices and then separating that mispricing into analyst-claimed undervaluation versus overvaluation. We document a strong new asymmetry, that analysts’ target prices contain information about undervaluation but not overvaluation, and at a rate that is substantially less than dollar-for-dollar. We also corroborate the work of Dechow and You (2020), who propose that analyst target prices contain predictable errors from analysts’ misinterpreting the return implications of common risk factors, in that we show that controlling for common risk factors increases the power of the predictive properties of analyst-claimed mispricing. Further, we reconcile Dechow and You’s (2020) finding that analysts’ target prices include noisy expected return information with Balakrishnan et al. (2021) result that analysts’ cost of equity estimates are unbiased predictors of future returns. While COE may be unbiased, other firm characteristics are incremental to analyst’s cost of equity for explaining returns such that COE is not a sufficient measure of the firm’s expected 12-month ahead return. Finally, we add to recent research that has found that analysts incorrectly weight the information in public anomaly signals (Engelberg et al. 2020). Our results indicate that, despite Engelberg et al.’s (2020) results, which indicate that the returns implied by analysts’ target prices move in the opposite direction to public anomaly signals, analysts’ target prices do contain information about mispricing—only asymmetrically so.

The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes our data, key variables, and descriptive statistics. Section 3 presents our empirical tests, results of the tests of our main and supplemental hypotheses, and associated robustness analyses. Section 4 discusses caveats, and Section 5 concludes.

2 Data and descriptive statistics

2.1 Data sources and description

Given the global nature of capital markets and analysts, we gathered analysts’ target prices and cost of equity estimates for US and international observations by searching the text of all analysts’ reports in Thomson ONE’s Investext database.Footnote 1 Per Table 1 Panel A, we searched analyst reports issued between Jan. 1, 2001, and Dec. 31, 2017, for the case-insensitive text string “cost of equity” anywhere in the report. We retained only those reports contributed by brokers and for which the report type was company (not industries, geographic or investing/economic). This yielded 432,393 analyst reports: 80,081 US analyst reports (geography = United States) and 350,118 international analyst reports (geography = not United States). Our other data requirements are shown in Table 1 Panel B. To the analyst reports, we matched stock prices, returns, and dividends from CRSP and Datastream using versions of company names. We required stock prices for the year prior to and after the analysts’ report. We collected accounting information pertaining to risk factors from Compustat and Factset (Fama and French 2015), winsorizing accounting variables at the first and 99th percentiles of our panel dataset. From the Investext reports, we extracted several variables with textual algorithms. We provide the details of our extraction and matching techniques in the Appendix. We first extracted analysts’ cost of equity and then analysts’ target prices. We also extracted analysts’ recommendations, which we categorize as buy, sell, or hold/missing. These data requirements yielded a sample of 9,781 US and 64,285 analyst reports.

Table 1 Sample selection

In Table 2, we describe key aspects of these analysts’ reports. Panel A shows that, of the 96 non-US countries, the top 15 by the number of analysts-firm-report observations include Australia, China, United Kingdom, Taiwan, Germany, and Singapore. Also, while the number of US firm reports that satisfy our data requirements increased from 110 in 2001 to 817 in 2017, the number of international reports increased from 0 to 8,700 during the same period.Footnote 2 In panel B, we list the top 10 US and international issuers. Reflecting the dominance of global and US-focused investment banks, five investment banks appear in both lists (Morgan Stanley, UBS, Deutsche Bank, JP Morgan, and Credit Suisse), while five issuers appear in one list only (Barclays, Singular Research, Piper Jaffray, Citi, and Jefferies in the US; HSBC Global Research, Macquarie, Raiffeisen Centro Bank, ESN, and Unicredit Research outside the US).

Table 2 Sample distribution by country, year, and issuer

2.2 Key variables

The key variables in our panel datasets are the forecasted one-year-ahead returns implied by analysts’ target prices, IRET; realized one-year-ahead returns, FRET; analysts’ cost of equity estimates, COE; and analyst-claimed mispricing, MIS. We define IRET on an ex-dividend basis as:

$$IRET=\frac{{E}_{t}^{A}({P}_{t+1})}{{p}_{t}}-1,$$
(1)

where \({p}_{t}\) is the closing price on the day before the analysts’ report and \({E}_{t}^{A}\left({P}_{t+1}\right)\) is the analyst’s 12-month ahead target price, namely their expectation of the firm’s stock price in 12-months’ time. Along the same ex-dividend lines, we define FRET as:

$$FRET=\frac{{p}_{t+1}}{{p}_{t}}-1,$$
(2)

where \({p}_{t+1}\) is the firm’s realized closing stock price 12 months after the date of the analyst’s report.,Footnote 3Footnote 4 We then define our measure of analyst-claimed mispricing MIS as:

$$MIS\equiv IRET-COE,$$
(3)

where COE is the analyst’s cost of equity estimate disclosed in the same report as the target price. We subtract COE to isolate the part of IRET that analysts claim is mispricing because research has found that COE is an unbiased estimate of the firm’s annual expected return (Balakrishnan et al. 2021). However, to increase the power of our mispricing-focused tests, we also control for firm characteristics that may capture firms’ risk exposures beyond COE (Dechow and You 2020). To test the asymmetry proposition, we divide MIS into two parts: UNDERVAL = MIS if MIS > 0 and zero otherwise, and OVERVAL = MIS if MIS ≤ 0 and zero otherwise.

2.3 Descriptive statistics

In Table 3, we present descriptive statistics on FRET, IRET, COE, MIS, UNDERVAL, and OVERVAL. Per panels A and B, for US (international) analyst-report observations the mean FRET is 13% (9%), and the mean COE is 11% (11%). At one level, the closeness of the means of FRET and COE to each other suggests that analysts’ cost of equity capture realized returns well. However, as also reported in panels A and B, the spreads in FRET and COE are more than an order of magnitude different, with the standard deviation FRET being 46% (44%) as compared to just 3% (3%) for COE. Similarly, at 51% (32%) the standard deviation of IRET far exceeds the standard deviation of COE, and at 51% (32%), the standard deviation of MIS far exceeds the 3% (3%) standard deviation of COE. We posit that such large differences make it unlikely that COE measures expected future returns in a way that is fully responsive to time varying or across-company differences in firms’ expected returns. We therefore propose that, while COE will play a measurable role in the formation of analysts’ target prices, it will not explain as much variation in FRET as will MIS.

Table 3 Descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations

Panel C provides further insight into analysts’ COE by graphing the frequency distribution of COE in bins of one-half percent. The great majority of analyst COEs lie between 6 and 15%, but the distribution is clearly not smooth. Markedly greater frequencies are observed at whole and half percentages, implying that analysts commonly round their COE to the nearest 1%, and a measurable fraction of analyst COE are greater than 20%. Panel D then plots key percentiles of the pooled US + international distribution of MIS (in black) and COE (in red) by the calendar year of the report. We note that while the median MIS is close to zero, the first, fifth, 95th, and 99th percentiles of MIS have substantial spread, albeit narrowing over time. We also note that consistent with our asymmetry-based proposition that analyst-claimed undervaluation is more likely than analyst-claimed overvaluation, positive MIS tend to be further from the median at the same percentile than negative MIS. Per panels A and B, for US (International) observations MIS is positive 66% (52%) of the time.

In panel E, we compare our sample of Investext-based analyst reports and firms with those in IBES. After finding that 72% (56%) of our analyst reports for US (International) companies can be matched to IBES, we compare IRET and the natural log of the fiscal year-end US dollar (USD) market value of equity LnMV in our pooled US + international dataset versus in IBES. We observe that our pooled dataset IRET mean of 15% is much lower than the IBES mean IRET of 55%, one reason for which is that, to avoid picking up errors in analyst reports or our textual extraction methods, we only include Investext analyst reports where IRET lies between –90% and 300%. Supporting this concern about error-based outliers, at 12% and 18% the median values of IRET are much closer together than are the means. At the same time, we note that the firms in our sample are on average larger than the firms in IBES. Our results may therefore not generalize to the more numerous firms covered by IBES.

Lastly, panel F graphs the distributions of MIS by country for the 15 countries with the most reports in our dataset. Panel F shows that there is variation across countries in the median MIS and the spread in MIS across countries. US observations have a median MIS that is most above zero as well as one of the largest within-country spreads in MIS. India has the lowest median MIS. The interquartile range in MIS for Singapore, Malaysia, and Australia are comparatively small. In light of these cross-country differences, in our regressions we include country fixed effects.

3 Empirical analyses

3.1 Tests of our main hypothesis

Table 4 reports the results of regressions that test our main hypothesis that analyst-claimed undervaluation will be more predictive of future stock returns than analyst-claimed overvaluation, and our first supplemental hypothesis. The regressions fit within the following general structure.

$${FRET}_{it}=\mathrm{a}+{\alpha MIS}_{ijct}+ {{\beta }_{U} UNDERVAL}_{ijct}+{{\beta }_{O} OVERVAL}_{ijct}+{\gamma COE}_{ijct}+ \lambda CONTROLS+{\theta }_{c}+{\pi }_{j}+{\omega }_{y[t]}+{\vartheta }_{i}+{e}_{it},$$
(4)

where FRETit is the realized ex-dividend 365-calendar-day buy-and-hold stock return for firm i starting on the day of the analyst report t, COEijct is the COE in the analyst report for firm i issued by broker j in country c on day t, and MISijct = IRETijctCOEijct, where IRETijct is the forecasted one-year-ahead ex-dividend stock return implied by the analyst’s target price for firm i in the report issued by broker j in country c on day t. \(CONTROLS\) is a set of firm characteristics that seek to capture risk exposures and \(\lambda\) is a vector of associated risk parameters.Footnote 5 To increase statistical power and address inferential threats arising from time-invariant firm and issuer characteristics and systematic market-wide forces, we follow Balakrishnan et al. (2021) and include the potential for country\({\theta }_{c}\), issuer\({\pi }_{j}\), year \({\omega }_{y[t]}\) and firm \({\vartheta }_{i}\) fixed effects, denoted by subscripts c, j, y[t], and i, respectively. We cluster standard errors by firm and year. For US observations, country fixed effects are excluded. For UNDERVAL, OVERVAL, and COE, we report t-statistics on the null that their associated coefficient is zero and one in () and [], respectively.

Table 4 Regressions that project one-year-ahead realized stock returns onto analyst-claimed mispricing

The key results in Table 4 are those for US model (3) and international model (6) that separate MIS into its mutually exclusive UNDERVAL and OVERVAL components. The results for models (3) and (6) show that analyst-claimed undervaluation reliably predicts stock returns but analyst-claimed overvaluation does not. The estimated coefficients on UNDERVAL are 0.18 (t-statistic = 4.0) for US analysts and 0.16 (t-statistic = 5.3) for international analysts, whereas the estimated coefficients on OVERVAL are 0.10 (t-statistic = 1.3) for US analysts and 0.03 (t-statistic = 1.0) for international analysts.

We note three sub-results in Table 4. First, all six US and international models confirm Balakrishnan et al. (2021) finding that the estimated coefficient on COE is insignificantly different from one. Second, both US model (1) and international model (4) find a small but reliably positive coefficient on MIS. Thus, before separating MIS into its UNDERVAL and OVERVAL components, analyst-claimed mispricing on average reliably predicts one-year-ahead returns. Third, when in US model (2) and international model (5) we control for firm characteristics that seek to capture risk exposures, the coefficient on MIS doubles for US analysts (rising from 0.09 to 0.17) and triples for international analysts (rising from 0.04 to 0.12). This supports Dechow and You’s (2020) perspective that analyst target prices contain predictable errors arising from analysts’ misinterpreting the return implications of common risk factors, in that we find that controlling for common risk factors increases the predictive ability of analyst-claimed mispricing. Our results also reconcile Dechow and You’s (2020) finding that analysts’ target prices include noisy expected return information with Balakrishnan et al. (2021) result that analysts’ COE estimates are unbiased predictors of future returns, because, while analyst COEs are unbiased, the reliably positive estimated coefficients on MIS indicate that analysts’ COE estimates are not sufficient measures of a firm’s expected 12-month-ahead return.

3.2 Tests of our supplemental hypotheses

Our first supplemental hypothesis is that, because analysts may issue bold or strategically magnified price targets to emphasize to investors that they have value-relevant information, UNDERVAL will map into future returns in a less than dollar-for-dollar manner. The results in Table 4 for US model (3) and international model (6) strongly support this since the t-statistics (in []) testing the null hypothesis that the coefficients on UNDERVAL = 1 are −17.9 and −28.1, respectively. Thus the estimated coefficients on UNDERVAL of 0.18 for US analysts and 0.16 for international analysts indicate that analyst-claimed undervaluation maps into future returns at 18 cents per dollar for US analysts and 16 cents per dollar for international analysts.

Our second supplemental hypothesis is that mispricing identified through analyst-claimed undervaluation will be corrected over time. Table 5 presents evidence consistent with this being the case. In all four of models (1) and (2) for US analysts and models (5) and (6) for international analysts, the estimated coefficients on UNDERVAL are reliably positive, indicating that analyst-claimed undervaluation predicts returns in the first and the second quarters beyond the analyst report date. At the same time, in all of models (3) and (4) for US analysts and models (7) and (8) for international analysts, the estimated coefficients on UNDERVAL are insignificant, indicating that analyst-claimed undervaluation does not predict returns in the third and the fourth quarters beyond the analyst report date.Footnote 6 The weakening strength of analysts’ target price information is also apparent in the coefficient on COE, as the predictive information in analysts’ cost of equity also declines moving further away from the analysts’ report date. These findings together suggest that the information in target prices is short-lived, whether that information is about mispricing or about risk.

Table 5 Regressions that project first- through fourth-quarter-ahead realized stock returns onto analyst-claimed mispricing

Table 6 presents the results of regressions that test our third supplemental hypothesis that the mapping of UNDERVAL into future returns will be negatively related to prior-period returns, and our fourth supplemental hypothesis that the mapping will be negatively related to macro-driven valuation uncertainty. We measure prior-period returns using MOMENTUM (MOM), our 12-month-momentum control variable, and macro-driven valuation uncertainty using the standard deviation of the returns implied by analysts’ target prices at the country level over the year prior to analysts’ report dates sdlRET.Footnote 7 The results in Table 6 are consistent with our predictions. The coefficients on UNDERVAL * MOM are −0.14 (t-statistic = −3.0) for the US sample per model (1) and −0.16 (t-statistic = −2.45) for the international sample per model (2), while the coefficient on UNDERVAL * sdRET is −0.58 (t-statistic = −4.5) per model (3). It is also the case that there is some evidence for the information content of OVERVAL after controlling for the interactions with MOM and sdRET. After controlling for OVERVAL * sdlRET, the coefficient on OVERVAL is significantly positive, and the coefficient on OVERVAL*MOM for the international sample indicates that the coefficient on OVERVAL becomes stronger when recent returns have been higher.

Table 6 Return momentum and uncertainty as attenuation explanations

3.3 Robustness tests

3.3.1 The information in IRET

Model (5) in Table 5 and models (1) and (2) in Table 6 suggest that, under certain MOM conditions, analysts’ target prices contain information about overvaluation. Here we explore alternative ways in which analysts’ claims about undervaluation may forecast returns. Analysts’ IRETs can be high because analysts’ have updated their target prices to include positive news that the market has not yet priced. Alternatively, analysts’ IRETs can be high because market prices have declined and analysts’ have not updated their target prices or have not lowered their target prices to the same extent as the market price. In the first case, analysts are providing independent positive information that the market later learns and prices. In the second case, analysts take a contrarian view by not changing target prices when transitory fluctuations in market prices occur. In other words, in the second case, analysts’ weight their own private signal more than the market signal (Aharoni et al. 2017; Chen and Jiang 2006).

To distinguish between the two possibilities, we test whether analysts’ IRETs are contrarian when analysts provide high IRETs. If analysts’ claims of undervaluation are primarily driven by contrarian positions where they do not adjust target prices in response to transitory fluctuations in market prices, we expect a negative correlation between prior stock returns, MOM, and IRET when IRETs are high. As our focus is on the relations between IRET and MOM at different points in the conditional distribution of IRET, we test our hypothesis using quantile rather than standard linear regressions (Koenker and Bassett 1978).Footnote 8

Table 7 presents the results of estimating the quantile regressions, where the coefficients of interest are on positive momentum MOM + and negative momentum MOM-. MOM + is the firm’s 12-month-return MOM ending the day before the analyst’s report date when MOM > 0 and zero otherwise and MOM– is the 12-month return when MOM < 0 and zero otherwise.

Table 7 Quantile regressions on the determinants of the implied returns in analysts’ target priced when prior-period stock returns have been positive versus negative

Consistent with our earlier evidence that analyst undervaluation maps into future returns, Table 7 shows that analysts issue target prices that are boldest in terms of embedding the most positive IRET when prior 12-month-return MOM has been negative. The coefficient of −0.92 on MOM- in the 90th quantile IRET regression indicates that a 1% more negative MOM- is associated with an 0.92% higher IRET, almost an inverse one-to-one relation. In comparison, the coefficient of 0.03 on MOM + is just 1/30th as large. At the same time, however, it is also the case that the negative coefficient of −0.08 on MOM + in the 10th quantile IRET regression is reliably negative and implies that a 1% more positive MOM + associates with an 0.08% lower IRET. While the coefficient on MOM + in the 10th quantile IRET regression is an order of magnitude smaller than is the coefficient on MOM- in the 90th quantile IRET regression and only twice as large as the coefficient on MOM- in the 10th quantile regression, it is negative and reliably so.

This table suggests that an important determinant of analysts’ claimed undervaluation is transitory declines in market prices. In other words, UNDERVAL may forecast returns, in part, because analysts correctly identify when market declines are transitory.

3.3.2 IRET and measurement error in MIS

Prior research finds that analysts’ target prices include noise pertaining to risk information (Dechow and You 2020). Thus, despite being correlated with future returns, analysts’ COE are noisy reflections of risk with the implication that MIS may fail to properly separate mispricing information from risk-based information in analysts’ target prices. To assess this concern, we repeat our Table 4 main tests in Table 8 by replacing MIS with IRET and by decomposing IRET into UNDERVAL# and OVERVAL# based on IRET > 0 and IRET ≤ 0, respectively. For presentation purposes, we include but do not report parameter estimates on the control variables since they are nearly identical to those in Table 4. The key result in Table 8 is that the coefficient estimates on UNDERVAL# and OVERVAL# are very similar in magnitude and statistical significance to those seen for UNDERVAL and OVERVAL in Table 4.

Table 8 Regressions that project one-year-ahead realized stock returns onto analyst-claimed mispricing but using IRET instead of MIS to define UNDERVAL# and OVERVAL#

3.3.3 Other robustness tests

We present the results of two more robustness tests in Table 9. First, Green et al. (2016) find that many analysts do not scale up the DCF-based valuations that often underlie their target prices to account for the time between the date of valuation in their DCF model and the date the target price date. Using pooled US and international observations, we therefore repeat our primary regressions using IRET scaled up to account for target prices that are for the end of year t target prices rather than the end of year t + 1 target prices. The results reported in columns (1) and (2) are highly similar to those in Tables 4 and 8. Second, we examine different methods of clustering in computing the standard errors of coefficient estimates. The results in columns (3)–(6) indicate no effects on the inferences that obtain in Tables 4 and 8 across clustering methods.

Table 9 Other tests using scaled forward IRET and different clustering

4 Caveats

While we show that US and international sell-side equity analysts identify undervaluation but not overvaluation in the stock prices of the firms they cover, our study comes with some caveats. First, we focus only on the first moment of the returns implied by analysts’ target prices. Joos et al. (2016) and Joos and Piotroski (2017) show that there is valuable information in the high/base/low multi-target price scenarios that some analysts provide, meaning there could be relations between such scenarios and the COE-based measures of analyst-claimed mispricing that we develop in our study. Second, because we require that an analyst’s report contain both a target price and a cost of equity figure, we cannot generalize our findings to analyst target prices that are not accompanied by a disclosed cost of equity—which is likely to be the great majority of target prices. Lastly, despite the large number of observations in our global dataset and the careful approach we take in identifying analysts’ COEs from their reports, there may be inadvertent biases in our data arising from the textual extraction methods we use.

5 Conclusion

Our goal is to study the predictive properties of analyst-claimed mispricing using the target prices and costs of equity disclosed by US and international analysts. We hypothesize that asymmetry in the incentives that managers face to supply value-relevant information to analysts combines with asymmetry in the incentives that analysts have to curry favor with and not contradict managers lead to analyst-claimed undervaluation being more predictive of future stock returns than analyst-claimed overvaluation.

We center the empirical tests of our hypotheses on analyst-claimed mispricing, MIS, defined as the ex-dividend predicted return implied by the analyst’s target price, IRET, less the analyst’s estimate of the firm’s cost of equity, COE. We isolate analyst-claimed undervaluation from overvaluation by defining UNDERVAL as MIS > 0 and OVERVAL as MIS ≤ 0 and use analysts’ target prices and costs of equity from US and international company analyst reports in Thomson ONE’s Investext database containing the text string “cost of equity.” When we regress within a fixed-effects structure realized one-year-ahead ex-dividend stock returns FRET on COE, UNDERVAL, and OVERVAL and controls for firms’ priced risk exposures, we find that the target prices of US and international analysts reliably predict stock returns when analysts claim undervaluation but not when they claim overvaluation.

We also expand beyond our main hypothesis by exploring four supplemental hypotheses and find support for each. Specifically, we find that analyst-claimed undervaluation maps into future returns in a manner that is less than dollar-for-dollar; analyst-claimed undervaluation is less predictive of future stock returns the further the returns are beyond the analyst’s report date; and the mapping of analyst-claimed undervaluation into future returns is negatively related to prior-period returns and to macro-driven valuation uncertainty.

Our study contributes to the literature on target prices in how it introduces an economically grounded way of isolating the mispricing-claimed component of analysts’ target prices and thus separating analyst-claimed undervaluation from analyst-claimed overvaluation. We also build on the work of Dechow and You (2020), who propose that, while consensus analyst target prices contain value-relevant information, they also contain predictable errors from analysts’ misinterpreting the return implications of common risk factors. We show that controlling for these common risk factors increases the power of measuring the predictive properties of analyst-claimed mispricing. Further, we reconcile the finding of Dechow and You (2020) that analysts’ target prices include noisy expected return information with the result of Balakrishnan et al. (2021) that analysts’ cost of equity estimates are unbiased predictors of annual returns. We show that, while an analyst’s cost of equity is unbiased, it is not a sufficient measure of expected returns because not only does it substantially understate the variation in realized returns but other risk factors, such as firm size and 12-month momentum, are incrementally predictive of returns.

Overall our study contributes new knowledge to the academic literature on analyst target prices, the cost of equity, and market efficiency. We also believe that our study’s findings can be readily brought into the classroom in the teaching and practice of financial statement analysis and valuation (Sommers and Easton 2019), and we encourage our readers to do so.