Skip to main content
Log in

Business cycles and the internal dynamics of firms

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Most business cycle theories originate from a paradigmatic vision with a two fold simplicity. The first of which is that firms are bound through simple relations in which they influence each other anonymously via prices but not directly through non-price rivalrous competition. And the second is that firms have immutable and transparent cores. These presumptions yield an economy whose natural state is one of stability. Macroeconomic dynamics, or change more generally, is brought about by exogenous shocks. This paper develops an alternate vision for understanding business cycle dynamics. We consider the dynamics that emerge from micro changes that originate from deep within firms. Each firm is surprised by externally visible innovations of other firms because they cannot observe each others’ high dimensional interiors. Innovations can cascade because of the complex microeconomic interrelations between the plans of firms. The interaction between external-observable attributes and internal-unobservable active cores of firms is capable of generating change without exogenous shocks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. While older literature used aggregate shocks, modern work argues that idiosyncratic firm level shocks can generate volatility when firms are related to each other on a network (Acemoglu et al. 2012). This modern literature uses networks as a mere amplification mechanism within an equilibrium-setting (Veetil Forthcoming, Sections 4.2 and 4.3). Networks are limited to serving as a loud speaker if you will to dampen the averaging out of millions of firm innovations in a large economy (Kirman 2016, p. 14).

  2. Nor did Darwin. As DeVries put it in the Species and Varieties: Their Origin by Mutation, “Natural selection may explain the survival of the fittest, but it cannot explain the arrival of the fittest”.

  3. The problem is peculiar to a production economy with inter-temporal decision-making, it may be entirely absent in an endowment economy. The Edgeworth barter process for instance describes a setting without a local-global consistency problem. Consider an endowment economy with m agents and n goods. Suppose the initial distribution of endowments is not Pareto optimal. Edgeworth studied a process of successive bartering until a point is reached where no barter was possible to make individuals better off (Uzawa 1962). Note that in the Edgeworth barter process an exhaustion of gains from trade between two individuals necessarily exhausts some of the gains from trade in the system as a whole. In other words, an increase in the coordination between any two agents generates an increase in systemic coordination.

  4. This is reminiscent of the Library of Babel as described by Borges (1962). The library contains all the books that can be written using 22 letters of the alphabet, comma, period, and space. Most books contains meaningless words strung together into meaningless sentences. Some books have a handful of meaningful words or some sensible sentences. Though the library contains large numbers of novels and scientific treatise, perhaps its own catalogue too, the vast majority of books are meaningless assortment of letters. In fact sensible books are lost among a super-astronomical number of senseless documents.

  5. Put differently, the knowledge acquired through the market process generates creative responses that can be miscoordinating. Hayek (1937, pp. 50-51) was quite right in asserting the any equilibrating tendency of the market depends on structures of interactions that dampen miscoordinating creative dynamics.

  6. Within an economy in which the coordination problem arises not from micro interdependence but from the presence of macro variables in micro choice functions (as in Keynesian models), one cannot meaningfully construe cascades of innovations that emerge from one firm responding to another’s changes. The ability of one firm to influence another firm by independently altering the macro variables which affect all firms is likely to be small. After all, firms no matter how large are small relative to the economy as a whole.

  7. Schumpeter (1928, p. 382) says that the dynamics of the macro economy cannot be looked up as a “continuous process” which irons out at the discontinuous changes at the firm level. Similarly, Schumpeter (1935, p. 10) says “the phenomenon of the cycle cannot be defined and understood as a sort of average between independent changes in individual industries”.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Carvalho, V.M., Ozdaglar, A., & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. (2012). The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 80(5), 1977–2016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axtell, R., Guerrero, O., & López, E. (2019). Frictional unemployment on labor flow networks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 160, 184–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakhtin, M.M. (1981). The dialogical imagination: Four essays. Austin: University of Texas Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, L.A. (1989). Economics and hermeneutics. Economics and Philosophy, 5(2), 209–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjelland, M., Fallick, B., Haltiwanger, J., & McEntarfer, E. (2011). Employer-to-employer flows in the united states: estimates using linked employer-employee data. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 29 (4), 493–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borges, G.L. (1962). The library of babel. Translated by james E Irby. Originally published in 1941.

  • Buchanan, J.M., & Vanberg, V.J. (1991). The market as a creative process. Economics & Philosophy, E7(2), 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeCanio, S.J., & Watkins, W.E. (1998). Information processing and organizational structure. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 36(3), 275–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P.A. (1982). Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy, 90(5), 881–894.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2010). Schumpeter meeting Keynes: A policy-friendly model of endogenous growth and business cycles. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34(9), 1748–1767.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elias, N. (1991). A Society of Individuals. Continuum.

  • Eliasson, G. (1991). Modeling the experimentally organized economy: Complex dynamics in an empirical micro-macro model of endogenous economic growth. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 16(1-2), 153–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana, W., & Buss, L.W. (1994). The arrival of the fittest: Toward a theory of biological organization. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology, 56(1), 1–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. (1933). Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics. In Essays in Honour of Gustav Cassel (pp. 171–205): Allen & Unwin.

  • Gualdi, S., & Mandel, A. (2016). On the emergence of scale-free production networks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 73, 61–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica, 4 (13), 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. (1968). Competition as a discovery procedure. The Quarterly Review of Austrian Economics 2002, Translated by Marcellus S. Snow, 5 (3), 9–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • High, J. (2011). Dr. Anderson and the Austrians: Price formation as a cumulative process. Review of Austrian Economics, 24, 199–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howitt, P. (2001). Coordination failures. An encyclopedia of macroeconomics.

  • Kaufmann, S.A., & Johnsen, S. (1991). Coevolution to the edge of chaos: Coupled fitness landscapes, poised states, and coevolutionary avalanches. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 149(4), 467–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirman, A. (2016). Networks: A paradigm shift for economics?. In The Oxford handbook of the economics of networks (pp. 13–46). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Koppl, R. (2002). Big players and the economic theory of expectations. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L.M. (1973). Macroeconomic thinking and the market economy: An essay on the neglect of micro-foundations and its consequences. The Institute of Economic Affairs.

  • Lavoie, D. (1985). Rivalry and central planning. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levit, G.S., Hossfeld, U., & Witt, U. (2011). Can Darwinism be “Generalized” and of what use would this be? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 21, 545–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovejoy, A. (1936). The great chain of being. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1935). Economic calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth. In Hayek, F.A. (Ed.) Collectivist economic planning (pp. 87–130): George Routledge and Sons.

  • Newman, M.E.J., & Roberts, B.W. (1995). Mass extinction: Evolution and the effects of external influences on unfit species. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London Series B: Biological Sciences, 260(1357), 31–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ouyang, M. (2009). The scarring effect of recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(2), 184–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, B.D., & Kirchhoff, B.A. (1989). Formation, growth and survival: Small firm dynamics in the US economy. Small Business Economics, 1(1), 65–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, K.L., & Wrase, J. (2006). Is Schumpeterian ’creative destruction’ a plausible source of endogenous real business cycle shocks? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(11), 1885–1913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pope, K.O., D’Hondt, S.L., & Marshall, C.R. (1998). Meteorite impact and the mass extinction of species at the Cretaceous/Tertiary boundary. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 95(19), 11028–11029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raup, D.M. (1986). Biological extinction in earth history. Science, 231(4745), 1528–1533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1928). The instability of capitalism. The Economic Journal, 38(151), 361–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1935). The analysis of economic change. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 17(4), 2–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1939). Business cycles: A theoretical, historical, and statistical analysis of the capitalist process Vol. 1. New York: McGraw-Hill. Reprinted in 2005 by Bartleby’s Books (Chevy Chase, MD) and Martino Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1947). The creative response in economic history. The Journal of Economic History, 7(2), 149–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (2005). Development. Journal of Economic Literature, 63, 108–120. Written in 1932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A. (1962). The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106(6), 467–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J.H., & Watson, M.W. (2002). Has the business cycle changed and why? NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 17, 159–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1997). The economic theory of bureaucracy. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa, H. (1962). On the stability of Edgeworth’s barter process. International Economic Review, 3(2), 218–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veetil, V.P. (Forthcoming). Schumpeter’s Business Cycle Theory and the diversification argument. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review.

  • Wagner, A. (2014). The Arrival of the Fittest: Solving Evolutions Greatest Puzzle. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R.E. (1999). Austrian cycle theory: saving the wheat while discarding the chaff. The Review of Austrian Economics, 12(1), 65–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R.E. (2012). A macro economy as an ecology of plans. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82(2), 433–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, RE. (2020). Macroeconomics as Systems Theory: Transcending the micro-macro dichotomy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (1992). Evolutionary concepts in economics. Eastern Economic Journal, 18(4), 405–419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (1997). The Hayekian Puzzle: Spontaneous order and the business cycle. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 44(1), 44–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (2009). Propositions about novelty. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(1-2), 311–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vipin P. Veetil.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Reddy, K.K., Veetil, V.P. Business cycles and the internal dynamics of firms. Rev Austrian Econ 36, 43–60 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-020-00538-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-020-00538-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation