Skip to main content
Log in

Why the structure of capital and the useful lives of its components matter: A test based on a model of Austrian descent

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper centers on the structure of capital and the useful lives of its components by considering an economy with two representative firms, one producing a necessity and another producing a luxury. This difference determines their reinvestment opportunities. Therefore, while the one applies replacement, the other adopts scrapping. However, as these capital policies lead to different service lives, the analysis confronts the issues raised by Miller (Review of Income and Wealth 29:284–296, 1982, Review of Income and Wealth 36:67–82, 1990) and deals with them by drawing on Haavelmo’s (A study in the theory of investment, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1960) suggestions regarding the aggregation of capital. Among other findings, it turns out that the simulation results are highly robust, thus demonstrating that real-world implications may be even stronger than strictly suggested by the model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These authors showed how the useful life of real assets might be computed under the assumption that technological advances proceed at a constant exogenous rate per unit of time. Admittedly, this is a strong assumption because technological progress can be observed only ex post, whereas entrepreneurial planning occurs always ex ante. However, relaxing this assumption would be a major undertaking, if it were at all possible, in the confines of the present model. For this reason, apart from citing the recent efforts by Bitros (2007), to trace the effects of uncertainty about the rate of embodied technological change, and by Schmitz (2004), to establish the link between uncertainty of future returns and the time structure of capital, in this paper, technological progress is modeled as if its rate is constant and exogenous.

  2. Due to the significance of the contributions by Mises (1966) and Hayek (1967), this theory was mentioned initially as the Mises-Hayek theory of the business cycle. Then, for some time, and perhaps because of the influence of such leading authors as Hicks (1967), Machlup (1976), and Haberler (1986), the theory was associated more with Hayek. However, since the publication by Mises et al (1983), professional opinion has moved beyond names and credits and refers now to the Austrian theory of business cycles.

  3. For an insightful analysis of the dynamics of investment from the Austrian perspective of the business cycle, see Montgomery (2006).

  4. The difficulties of aggregating heterogeneous capital goods into a homogeneous “capital-in-general” quantity have long been known and go back to the great “Cambridge vs. Cambridge” debates in the 1950s and 1960s regarding the role of capital as a factor of production. In the light of these debates, the difficulties arise because the various types of aggregated durables cannot be transformed into durables of some standard durability. However, since under market incentives, capital goods are always utilized where they have the highest expected marginal revenue, the concept of multiple specificity introduced by Lachmann (1956) to characterize the flexibility of putting the same capital goods in different uses does not present additional difficulties because multiple specificity is a special case of the heterogeneity modeled in this paper.

  5. Even though telephone companies, electric utilities, and other network industries construct a good deal of their capital internally, this conceptualization is quite removed from the actual economy. However, it is adopted to avoid the opening of a third sector, which would complicate the analysis significantly without adding much to the explanatory power of the model.

  6. At this point, the choice of capital policy may appear to be imposed on the two firms exogenously. However, it is not because in an earlier stage, the two firms solve the problem posed by Bitros and Flytzanis (2005), where the horizon of reinvestment is determined endogenously. In other words, here, it is assumed that if the firms solved this problem in the light of the differences in the nature of and the demand for their products, firm X would apply replacement and firm Y scrapping.

  7. The production of electricity is presumed to take place by combining one unit of capital with one unit of labor, whereas electricity-generating capacity is built within the firm solely by means of labor. Hence, the addition of an employment equation would turn the model into one of general equilibrium in labor and capital. However, as the ensuing analysis would not be affected, the employment of the labor sector of the model is ignored.

  8. Regarding the impact of technological change, there are two possibilities. Technological change may affect the capital–output coefficient either positively or negatively. Normally, new production techniques take the form of innovations that reduce the capital–output coefficient. However, one cannot preclude isolated episodes of technological regression or of some heavily capital-intensive innovation, which for some period may increase the capital–output coefficient above its downward trend. In this paper, I focus only on the innovations that as a rule and on the average reduce the capital–output coefficient.

  9. If there were no other features linking the model under consideration to the Austrian tradition, this equation alone would be sufficient to place it squarely in that lineage. The basis for this claim is none other than the fundamental idea that comes from the Austrian theory of capital according to which building more roundabout and hence more productive capital goods requires more labor relative to the ones they displace. Stated in the words of Hicks (1970, p. 273): “The crucial condition is that the new machines should be expensive in labor, relative to those they displace, and that, in spite of that, they should (of course) be more profitable.” The nice attribute in the adopted specification of this equation is that γ < −1. This imposes an upper limit on the amount of roundaboutness that can be built into the new capital goods, since the unit cost in terms of the minimum labor requirements increases more than in proportion.

  10. To be sure, given that the demand for electricity is actually stochastic, in reality, firm X will need to keep adequate slack capacity to avoid blackouts. Assuming that electric utilities have developed a rule by which they determine the percentage of stand-by capacity they must have to meet peak loads, the analysis is not affected because the optimal capacity may be defined to include this percentage of spare capacity.

  11. This policy is one of many that can possibly result when solving for the optimal reinvestment horizon. Tightening a bit further the assumption introduced in footnote 6, I assume for reasons of simplicity that if firm X solved for the horizon of reinvestments, the optimal capital policy would turn out to be one of infinite replacements at equal time distances.

  12. The detailed derivations of the first-order conditions from the objective functions 8 and 13 are available on request by the author.

  13. Please note that the vertical axis in Fig. 1 depicts the left-hand side of Eqs. 10 and 15. Thus, the axis measures the values taken by the functions g(T X ) and h(T Y ). The latter function, shown in Fig. 1 by the corresponding bold upward-sloping curve, will be explained below.

  14. The option to decide whether to exit or reinvest at the end of the initial investment cycle is not free. To ascertain the existence of the costs involved, assume first that firm Y decides to reinvest. In this event, given that \(T_X^ * < T_Y^ * \), firm Y renews its capital slower than firm X. However, by doing so, it foregoes the benefit of taking advantage of technological change at a quicker pace. Moreover, firm Y may have to absorb the costs that accompany the shutting down of business operations. Later in the application of the model, such costs will be introduced as a fixed percentage ϕ of the undepreciated value of the capital stock.

  15. Clearly, since in this case, there is no infinite series of reinvestments, the objective function of firm Y consists solely of a single acquisition of capital stock. This explains why the denominator in Eq. 8 is missing from Eq. 13.

  16. In an economy with a small number of distinct kinds of capital goods, it may be possible to sidestep the issues discussed immediately below by resorting to a fully disaggregated analysis. However, as the model under consideration is intended to be generalizable to an economy with any number of heterogeneous capital goods, the adopted approach to aggregation is of particular methodological importance.

  17. Observe though that since the differences in capital policies lead to \(T_X^ * < T_Y^ * \), the proposed adjustment results always in underestimation of the capital stock at the level of the scrapping firm.

  18. It should be pointed out that that the replacement investment to capital stock ratio is a good proxy of the inverse of the useful life of the capital stock.

  19. Since shifts in the elasticity of demand parameter η Y make the optimal useful life of capital T Y highly volatile, consumer demand influences the optimal useful life and hence the productivity of the capital equipment used to produce Y. However, then, this finding contradicts the real business cycle theory because, as argued by Kydland and Prescott (1982), Long and Plosser (1983), and Plosser (1989), the real business cycle theory requires capital life and productivity to be persistent. This and several other implications of the model for the real business cycle theory were brought to my attention by a referee. Therefore, it goes without saying that I am most grateful to him and stand committed to develop his suggestions in a follow-on paper.

  20. This inference is based on the realization that the price elasticity of demand η Y enters into Eq. 23 because of the presence in the model of scrapping firm Y. However, the distinction between capital-replacing and capital-scrapping firms is not the only difference of Eq. 23 with the models that were estimated by Feldstein and Foot (1971) and Eisner (1972). In addition, it differs from them in that while it explains at least as much of the variation in the replacement investment to capital stock ratio as them, it does so with a different set of explanatory variables that derive directly from the theory of rational entrepreneurial behavior.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Guerrieri, V. (2006). Capital deepening and non-balanced economic growth. MIT/University of Chicago working paper. http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/download_pdf.php?id=1191.

  • Åkerman, G. (1923). Realkapital and Kapitalzins. Stockholm: Centraltrycheriet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1968). Optimal capital policy with irreversible investment. In J. N. Wolfe (Ed.) Value, capital and growth: Papers in honour of Sir John Hicks (pp. 1–19). Chicago, IL: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Augier, J., & Augier, L. (2003). Production period and cycles: Several interpretations in a neo-Austrian economic perspective. Review of Austrian Economics, 16, 205–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baetjer, H. (2000). Capital as embodied knowledge: Some implications for the theory of economic growth. Review of Austrian Economics, 13, 147–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitros, G. C. (2007). The optimal lifetime of assets under uncertainty in the rate of embodied technical change. Athens University of Economic and Business, Department of Economics, Discussion paper no. 183. (Forthcoming in Metroeconomica).

  • Bitros, G. C., & Flytzanis, E. (2005). On the optimal lifetime of assets. Athens University of Economic and Business, Department of Economics, Discussion paper no. 170.

  • Blitz, R. C. (1958). Capital longevity and economic development. American Economic Review, 48, 313–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boddy, R., & Gort, M. (1971). The substitution of capital for capital. Review of Economics and Statistics, 53, 179–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1889). Positive theory of capital, 2nd volume in the 3-volume work capital and interest. South Holland, Ill.: Libertarian (The three volumes were originally published in German in 1984, 1989, and 1909; translated by G. D. Hunke and H. F. Sennholtz).

    Google Scholar 

  • Boot, J. C. G., & de Wit, G. M. (1960). Investment demand: An empirical contribution to the aggregation problem. International Economic Review, 1, 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brems, H. (1968). Quantitative economic theory: A synthetic approach. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. R. (1965). Technical change and the measurement of capital and output. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 289–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisner, R. (1972). Components of capital expenditures: Replacement and modernization versus expansion. Review of Economics and Statistics, LIV, 297–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. S., & Foot, D. K. (1971). The other half of gross investment: Replacement and modernization expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics, LIII, 49–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F. M. (1965). Embodied technical change and the existence of an aggregate capital stock. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 263–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F. M. (1968). Embodied technology and the aggregation of fixed and movable capital goods. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 417–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (1978). Austrian macroeconomics: A diagrammatical exposition. In L. M. Spadaro (Ed.) New directions in Austrian Economics (pp. 167–204). Kansas City: Sheed Andrews & McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (1986). Trade cycle theory: A reappraisal. Cato Journal, 6, 437–459.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (1988). Theory of the business cycle in the light of modern macroeconomics. Review of Austrian Economics, 3, 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (1991). New classical and old austrian economics: Equilibrium business cycle theory in perspective. Review of Austrian Economics, 5, 91–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structure. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, S. (1992). Costs of adjustment, the aggregation problem and investment. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74, 422–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, J. P. (1968). Adjustment cost, in the theory of investment of the firm. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 47–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, T. (1960). A study in the theory of investment. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haberler, G. (1986). Reflections on Hayek’s business cycle theory. Cato Journal, 6, 421–435.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E. (1968). Technical change and capital from the point of view of the dual. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 35–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1939). Profits, interest and investment. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967). Studies in philosophy, politics, and economics. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1967). The Hayek story. In J. R. Hicks (Ed.) Critical essays in monetary theory (pp. 203–215). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1970). A neo-Austrian growth theory. Economic Journal, 80, 257–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1973). The Austrian theory of capital and its rebirth in modern economics. In J. R. Hicks, & W. Weber (Eds.) Menger and Austrian school of economics. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W. (1963). Capital theory and investment behavior. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 53, 247–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., & Griliches, Z. (1967). The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies, 34, 249–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, J. P. (2001). Empirical evidence on the Austrian business cycle theory. Review of Austrian Economics, 14, 331–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50, 1345–1370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1956). Capital and its structure. London: Bell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lombardo, G. A., & Mulligan, R. F. (2003). Resource allocation: A Hayekian paradigm for maritime conglomerates. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 6, 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. B., & Plosser, C. I. (1983). Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 39–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machlup, F. (1976). Hayek’s contribution to economics. In F. Machlup (Ed.) Essays on Hayek (pp. 13–59). Hillsdale, MI: Hillsdale College.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, E. M. (1982). Capital aggregation in the presence of obsolescence-inducing technical change. Review of Income and Wealth, 29, 284–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, E. M. (1990). Can a perpetual inventory capital stock be used for production function parameter estimation? Review of Income and Wealth, 36, 67–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery, S. W. (2006). Austrian persistence? Capital-based business cycle theory and the dynamics of investment spending. Review of Austrian Economics, 19, 17–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, R. F. (2005). The Austrian business cycle: A vector error-correction model with commercial and industrial loans. Journal of Private Enterprise, 22, 51–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, R. F. (2006). An empirical examination of austrian business cycle theory. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 9, 69–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plosser, C. I. (1989). Understanding real business cycles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 51–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sechrest, L. J. (1997). Austrian and monetarist business cycle theories: Substitutes or complements? In P. J. Boettke, & S. Horwitz (Eds.) Advances in Austrian economics (vol. 4, (pp. 7–31)). Oxford: JAI.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Shah, P. J. (1997). The theory of business fluctuations: New keynesians, old monetarists, and Austrians. In P. J. Boettke, & S. Horwitz (Eds.) Advances in Austrian economics (vol. 4, (pp. 33–62)). Oxford: JAI.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1961). Investment and production: A study in the theory of the capital-using enterprise. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, S. W. (2004). Uncertainty in the Austrian theory of capital. Review of Austrian Economics, 17, 67–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Terborgh, G. (1949). Dynamic equipment policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veracierto, M. L. (2002). Plant-level irreversible investment and equilibrium business cycles. American Economic Review, 92, 181–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1966). Human action: A treatise on economics (3rd ed.). Chicago: Henry Regnery.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L., Haberler, G., Rothbard, M. N., & Hayek, F. A. (1983). The Austrian theory of the trade cycle and other essays. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westfield, F. M. (1958). A mathematical note on optimum longevity. American Economic Review, 48, 329–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1898). Interest and prices. New York: Augustus M. Kelley (translated from Swedish by R. F. Kahn in 1936; reprint 1965).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1923). Realkapital och Kapitalranta. Ekonomisk Tidskrift, 25, 145–180 (translated as the second appendix to Lectures in Political Economy, 1, London, 1934).

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

The referees did a splendid job. With their comments and suggestions they helped me improve the paper both substantively and stylistically. Therefore, I recognize their valuable contribution with great pleasure and appreciation. I received valuable comments also from Professors Natali Hritonenko and Yuri Yatsenko, as well as Athanasios Petralias, a former student of mine and now Ph.D. candidate in the Statistics Department of the Athens University of Economics and Business. To all of them, I express my sincere thanks. However, for blemishes still remaining in the paper, all responsibility rests with me.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George C. Bitros.

Appendices

Appendix A

Suppose that embodied technological progress reduces the capital–output coefficient b X (t) at the constant and exogenous rate μ. This rate scales with time because it depends on the interval over which it is considered. Therefore, suppose that we are at time t and we observe a vintage of capital that was built υ periods ago. On average, from υ to t, the capital coefficient must have declined as follows:

$$\frac{{b_X \left( t \right) - b_X \left( \upsilon \right)}}{{b_X \left( \upsilon \right)}} = \mu \left( {t - \upsilon } \right),$$
(26)

with μ < 0.

From this, we get:

$$b_X \left( t \right) = b_X \left( \upsilon \right)\left[ {1 + \mu \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} \right].$$
(27)

Now, assume that the process of technological progress begins at t = υ. At that moment, the capital coefficient will be equal to b(υ). Next, divide the interval t − υ into m equal time steps. At the end of the first time step, the capital coefficient will be:

$$b_X \left( {\upsilon + \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right) = b_X \left( \upsilon \right)\left[ {1 + \mu \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right].$$
(28)

At the end of the second timestep the capital coefficient will be:

$$b_X \left( {\upsilon + 2\frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right) = b_X \left( {\upsilon + \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right)\left[ {1 + \mu \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right] = b_X \left( \upsilon \right)\left[ {1 + \mu \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right]^2 .$$
(29)

And at the end of the m time step, the capital coefficient will have declined to:

$$b_{X} {\left( t \right)} = b_{X} {\left( {\upsilon + {\left( {m - 1} \right)}\frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right)}{\left[ {1 + \mu \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right]}^{m} .$$
(30)

Now, let m→∞. Then, the time step (t − υ)/m will go to zero, and we will have:

$$b_X \left( t \right) = b_X \left( \upsilon \right)\left[ {1 + \mu \frac{{t - \upsilon }}{m}} \right]^m = b_X \left( \upsilon \right)e^{\mu \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} ,$$
(31)

which is Eq. 3 in the text.

Appendix B

Inserting Eqs. 10 into 9 and rearranging, we obtain:

$$P_X \left( 0 \right) = \frac{{\eta _X }}{{1 + \eta _X }}\frac{{\sigma - \mu }}{\sigma }\frac{{1 - e^{ - \mu T_X } + \beta \sigma }}{{1 - e^{ - \left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T_X } }}b_X \left( 0 \right)w.$$
(32)

In turn, if this is introduced into Eq. 7, it yields:

$$n_X \left( 0 \right) = - \frac{1}{{1 + \eta _X }}\frac{{1 - e^{\mu T_X } + \beta \sigma }}{\sigma }w.$$
(33)

However, the representative firm is presumed to defend its monopoly by restricting itself through pricing rule Eq. 5 to making only normal profits, i.e., profits that would result in an industry in perfectly competitive long-run equilibrium. Therefore, it will let the price elasticity of demand η X approach to minus infinity and use the approximation:

$$\frac{{\eta _X }}{{1 + \eta _X }} = 1.$$
(34)

Now, if we deduct 1 from both sides of this equation and insert the result into Eq. 33, we obtain:

$$n_X \left( 0 \right) = 0.$$
(35)

This proves that under the adopted pricing rule, the unit net worth of equipment in the initial vintage is set equal to zero and corroborates the claim made in the text.

Appendix C

At υ, the worth of revenue minus the labor cost of operating a unit of equipment per small fraction dt of a year located at time t is given by:

$$\left[ {\frac{{P\left( \upsilon \right)}}{{b\left( \upsilon \right)}}e^{\mu \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} - w} \right]e^{ - \sigma \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} {\text{d}}t$$
(36)

where w and σ denote, respectively, the economy-wide rates of wages and interest.

Consequently, at υ, the worth of the sum total of revenue minus operating labor cost of a unit of such equipment over its entire useful life T is:

$$n_X \left( 0 \right) = \int_\upsilon ^{\upsilon + T} {\left[ {\frac{{P\left( \upsilon \right)}}{{b\left( \upsilon \right)}}e^{\mu \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} - w} \right]e^{ - \sigma \left( {t - \upsilon } \right)} } {\text{d}}t - \beta w = \frac{{P_X \left( \upsilon \right)}}{{b_X \left( \upsilon \right)}}\frac{{1 - e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T} }}{{\sigma - \mu }} - w\frac{{1 - e^{ - \sigma T} }}{\sigma }.$$
(37)

Now, let P be the purchase price of a new unit of electricity generators. Assuming its salvage value upon retirement is zero, its net worth is:

$$n\left( \upsilon \right) = \frac{{P\left( \upsilon \right)}}{{b\left( \upsilon \right)}}\frac{{1 - e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T} }}{{\sigma - \mu }} - w\frac{{1 - e^{ - \sigma T} }}{\sigma } - P.$$
(38)

Finally, since by Eq. 4 the minimum labor required to build a new unit of electricity-generating capacity is β, under perfectly competitive transfer prices from the capital building to the capital using department of the representative firm, plus the assumption that electricity-generating capacity is built solely by means of labor, it will hold that:

$$P = \beta w.$$
(39)

Thus, substituting Eq. 39 into Eq. 38 gives Eq. 7.

Appendix D

Let a capital stock be replaced forever every υ years. At time t = 0, the firm acquires the vintage zero capital stock \(K_X \left( 0 \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)\). At time t = T X , the vintage zero capital stock is retired and replaced by vintage υ capital stock. However, vintage T X capital stock is more efficient due to technological progress. How more efficient it is relative to vintage zero capital stock is given by \(b_X \left( {T_X } \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)e^{\mu T_X } \). Hence, to keep the capacity constant from vintage to vintage, at t = υ, the capital stock that is needed for replacement is less. In particular, its quantity is given by \(K_X \left( {T_X } \right) = b_X \left( {T_X } \right)X\left( 0 \right) = b_X \left( 04 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{\mu T_X } \). At t = 2T X , the capital stock that will be needed for replacement will be \(K_X \left( {2T_X } \right) = b_X \left( {2T_X } \right)X\left( 0 \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{2\mu T_X } \), at time t = jT X , the capital stock that will be needed is \(K_X \left( {jT_X } \right) = b_X \left( {jT_X } \right)X\left( 0 \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{j\mu T_X } \), and so on.

Now, consider the net worth of the acquisitions. At time t = 0, the net worth of the capital stock is \(n_X \left( 0 \right)K_X \left( 0 \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)\). At time t = υ, the net worth of the acquired capital stock is \(n_X \left( {T_X } \right)K_X \left( {T_X } \right) = b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{\mu T_X } \). Notice in this expression that n(υ) has been substituted for n(0). This has been done on account of the expressions 6 and 7 in the text. Therefore, if the net worth of the capital stock acquired at t = υ is discounted to t = 0 using the discounting term \(e^{ - \sigma T_X } \), we obtain \(b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T_X } \). Finally, repeating the preceding steps for the net worth of capital stock acquired at t = jT X gives \(b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)jT_X } \). Consequently, since in addition to the initial acquisition there take place j replacements, the net present value of the 1 + j acquisitions of capital stock is given by:

$$b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)\left[ {1 + e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T_X } + \ldots + e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)jT_X } } \right].$$
(40)

The expression in the brackets is a geometric progression with 1 + j terms, each of which is equal to the preceding one multiplied by \(e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)jT_X } \), where (μ − σ)T X  < 0. This implies that the bracketed expression constitutes a geometric progression with declining terms. Thus, if we set j→∞, at t = 0, the sum of the infinite series of replacements K X (0), K X (T X ), K X (2T X ),... is given by:

$$A_X \left( 0 \right) = \frac{{b_X \left( 0 \right)n_X \left( 0 \right)X\left( 0 \right)}}{{1 - e^{\left( {\mu - \sigma } \right)T_X } }}.$$
(41)

This is Eq. 8 in the text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bitros, G.C. Why the structure of capital and the useful lives of its components matter: A test based on a model of Austrian descent. Rev Austrian Econ 21, 301–328 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-008-0049-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-008-0049-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation