Skip to main content
Log in

Islamic revolution and Anfal

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Islamic revolution is nothing but Islamic revivalism or the establishment of an Islamic state based on Sharia. In this paper, I focus on the Islamic revolution in Iran that has been exceptionally considered as a ‘social revolution’ targeting an overhaul of the economic institutions. Can the economic model of Islamic revivalism be reduced to one of the principal dichotomous models of state socialism or free market economy as suggested by many economists? It will be shown that Anfal or the Imam’s exclusive property over all public properties known as res nullius has been the major invention of the Islamic revivalism in Iran. This provides an independent Islamic model that has been left unnoticed by specialists in Islamic economics that can be characterized as a specific economic system, namely Islamic political capitalism. This system is not reducible to state socialism or competitive free markets. This paper fills the gap and demonstrates that Anfal institutionalizes a confiscatory regime enhancing a rent-seeking society hindering private property rights and competitive free markets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Jama’at-i-Islami (Community of Islam) is an Islamic movement founded in 1941 in British India and was a political party till 1947 following partition of India by the Islamic author, theorist and political philosopher, Seyyed Abul Ala Maududi.

  2. It is a Persian expression for the guardianship of an Islamist jurist (Faqih or jurisconsult) who is vicegerent exercising delegated power on behalf of the Prophet and his righteous successors, namely the Imam. It pertains to a political system that underpins the way the Shi’i theologians govern Iran since the 1979 Revolution. In this system, all political and religious authority belongs to the Shi’i clergy and particularly to the Supreme Jurisconsult who makes all the state’s key decisions. The Supreme Leader as the representative of the Imam provides guardianship (Velayat) over the nation and secures the top-down Islamization of the sovereignty. Articles 5, 57, and 110 of the Constitution of the Islamic Republic of Iran describe the scope of authority and various functions of the jurisconsult of the vicegerent.

  3. Abu Dahrr was the fourth or fifth person converting to Islam and was a member of Muhajrun (emigrants) who accompanied the Prophet in his emigration from Mecca to Medina. Abu Dharr is remembered for his strict piety and also his opposition to Muawiyah.

  4. Badr happened in 624 A.D. in what is modern-day Saudi Arabia’s province of Hejaz. It was the first defensive clash between the Meccans and the Muslim people of Medina after they fled from persecution in Mecca. This Surah is part of Madani Surahs (Surah Madaniyah) or Madani chapters of the Koran that were revealed at Medina after Muhammad’s hijra from Mecca. These Surahs often elaborate on moral principles, legislation, warfare, and principles for establishing the Muslim community (McAuliffe, 2006, p. 111).

  5. See Vahabi (2023, chapter 5) for the details regarding the Koranic and historical references to Anfal and the controversial issues between Sunnite and Shiite interpretations of Anfal.

  6. This is the author’s translation. For an alternative official translation see PURL: https://www.legal-tools.org/doc/4205c7/ retrieved on September 10, 2021.

  7. See Iran (Islamic Republic of)’s Constitution of 1979 with Amendments through 1989, constituteproject.org, retrieved on June 28, 2021.

  8. Revolving doors is the outcome of the intricate mechanism of the so-called ‘unethical’ but yet legal behavior: “In the last decade, the ‘revolving door’ phenomenon—defined as such when the heads of state agencies, after completing their bureaucratic terms, enter the very sector they have regulated—has intensified, and has been widely documented as having negative effects on the economy.” (Brezis & Cariolle, 2019, p. 595). The authors document its presence in many sectors including the pharmaceutical, telecommunication, and defense. Zingales (2015) underlines its significance particularly in the finance sector. According to an OECD report (2009), the revolving door has been one of the major causes of the 2008 crisis. Vukovic (2021) demonstrates the ‘political bailouts’ by exploring the relationship between political connections and corporate bailouts during 2008–2009.

  9. See Iran Data Portal, https://irandataportal.syr.edu/the-general-policies-pertaining-to-principle-44-of-the-constitution-of-the-islamic-republic-of-iran

  10. There are other estimations about the total value of assets. According to Mohsen Rezai (July 5, 2006), the total amount has been 1000 thousand billion Rials.

  11. Some Iranian economists, political scientists and sociologists prefer the term ‘neoliberal’.

  12. Mir-Hossein Mousavi served as the seventy-ninth and last Prime Minister of Iran from 1981 to 1989. He was known as an advocate of a statist program during the Khomeini’s era and then became one of the two so-called ‘Reformist’ candidates along with Mehdi Karoubi against the administration of incumbent President of Iran Mahmoud Ahmadinejad for the 2009 presidential election. According to official results, he did not win the election, and following alleged vote-rigging and manipulation, his campaign sparked a long protest that eventually turned into a national and international movement against Ahmadinejad’s government and the Supreme jurisprudent Ali Khamenei. Mousavi chose green as his campaign color, and his opposition ‘reformist’ movement was known as the Green Movement. Although he insisted on his loyalty to the constitution of the Islamic Republic of Iran, he, his wife and Mehdi Karroubi were detained at their residence and are currently under house arrest.

  13. This term was often used by many radical and leftist economists who had a strong sympathy for the ‘popular anti-imperialist’ and so-called ‘equalitarian’ tendencies of the IRI during 1979–1989.

  14. “The private sector is defined as a sector composed of all companies and associations in which 80 percent of their shares belong directly or indirectly through legal persons to natural persons.” (Najafi Khah, 2016, p. 123).

References

  • Abazari, Y., & Zakeri, A. (2019). Three decades of coexistence of religion and Neoliberalism in Iran. Critique of Political Economy (in Persian).

  • Abrahamian, E. (1993). Khomeinism. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abrahamian, E. (2009). Why the Islamic Republic has survived. Middle East Report, 250, 10–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • al-Hilli (al-Muhaqqiq), J. I. H. (1988). Shara'i' al-Islam fi masa'il al-halal wa l-haram (Islam Sharia regarding halal and haram), vol. 1, Second edition, Tehran: Entesharat Esteqlal (in Persian).

  • Al-Mufid, M. I. N. (1989). Al-Muqni’ah (The Legally Sufficient) (2nd ed.). Daftar Entesharat Islami.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babookani, E. A. A., Saadi, H., & Tabeebi Jabali, M. (2018). Pajooheshay Fqih-i, No. 2, Summer, pp. 405–427 (in Persian).

  • Behdad, S. (1989). Property rights in contemporary Islamic economic thought: A critical perspective. Review of Social Economy, 47(2), 185–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behdad, S. (1994). A disputed Utopia: Islamic economics in revolutionary Iran. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 36(4), 775–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behdad, S. (1995). The post-revolutionary economic crisis. In S. Rahnema & S. Behdad (Eds.), Iran after the Revolution: Crisis of an Islamic State (pp. 97–128). I.B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Behdad, S. (2006). Islam, revivalism, and public policy. In S. Behdad & F. Nomani (Eds.), Islam and the Everyday World: Public Policy Dilemmas (pp. 1–37). Routledge.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Behdad, S., & Nomani, F. (2012). Women’s Labour in the Islamic Republic of Iran: Losers and Survivors. Middle Eastern Studies, 48(5), 707–733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brezis, E., & Cariolle, J. (2019). The revolving door, state connections, and inequality of influence in the financial sector. Journal of Institutional Economics, 15(4), 595–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehsani, K. (2009). Survival through dispossession: Privatization of Public Goods in the Islamic Republic (No. 250, pp. 26–33). Middle East Report, Spring.

  • Ehsani, K. (2013). The politics of property in the Islamic Republic of Iran. In S. A. Arjomand & N. J. Brown (Eds.), The rule of law, Islam, and constitutional politics in Egypt and Iran (pp. 153–178). New York: SUNY Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, K. (2013). The rise of the subcontracting state: Politics of pseudo-privatization in the Islamic Republic of Iran. International Journal of Middle East Studies, 45, 45–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, K. (2017). A social revolution politics and the welfare state in Iran. University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2015). Political capitalism. Cato Journal, 35(1), 41–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2018). Political capitalism, how economic and political power is made and maintained. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khomeini, R. (2000). Ketab Al-Bey (The Book of Sale) (Vol. 3). Tehran: Moassesseh tanzeem va nashr asar al-Imam al-Khomeini.

  • Kolko, G. (1963). The Triumph of conservatism: A reinterpretation of American History, 1900–1916. The Free Press of Glencoe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolko, G. (1965). Railroads and regulation 1877–1916. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kulayni, M. I. Y. (1988). Al-Kafi (Extant) (Vol. 1). Dar al-kotob al-islamieh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2018). Islam and economic performance. Journal of Economic Literature, 56(4), 1292–1359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerman, E. (1981). Mawdudi’s concept of Islam. Middle Eastern Studies, 17(4), 492–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahamed, A. (2012). Tafsir Tatbeeghi Ayeh Sharifeh Anfal” (A comparative interpretation of the honorable verse of Anfal). Faslnameh Motalleat Tafsiri, 3(9), 81–104. (in Persian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, S. (2015). Iran’s political economy since the revolution. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McAuliffe, J. D. (2006). The Cambridge companion to the Qur’an. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B. (2019). Capitalism alone, the future of the system that rules the world. Belknap press of Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mesbahi, M., Shahbazi Ghyasi, M., & Nakhli, S. R. (2011). Osool va siasathay hakem bar masraf Anfal va daramadhay hasel az an dar dowlat islami,” (The governing principles and policies regarding the expenditure of the income originated from Anfal in the Islamic State), Faslnameh pajoohesh-hay eghtesadi Iran, Number 48, Fall, pp. 193–221 (in Persian).

  • Montazeri, H.-A. (1987). Darasat fi velayet al-faqih va feqhe al-dowlah al-islamieh (Studies on Velayat faqih and the jurisprudence of the Islamic state), Vol. 14. Al-markaz al-alemi il-darasat al-islamieh.

  • Najafi Khah, M. (2016). Marz-e myan bakhsh omomei va bakhsh khosousi dar hoghogh Iran ba takeed bar barnameh khosousi sazi va broon separi (The delineation of the public and private sector in the Iranian law with the emphasis on the privatization program and outsourcing), Faslnameh elmi-pajooheshi Shapa, 21(4), Winter, pp. 101–133 (in Persian).

  • Nasr, S. V. R. (1994). The vanguard of the Islamic revolution: The Jamaʻat-i Islami of Pakistan. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nasr, S. V. R. (1996). Mawdudi and the making of Islamic Revivalism. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Negri, A. (2008). Afterword: On the concept of revolution. In F. John, L. David, & Z. Andreja (Eds.), Revolution in the making of the modern world: Social identities, globalization, and modernity (pp. 252–260). Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mousavi Nik, S. H. (2009). Gozar az Iqtesad dowlati be shebh dowlati (The transition from state to parastate economy), the Research Centre of Islamic Legislative Assembly, November, Serial number 9915, subject code 220 (in Persian).

  • Nili, M., & Associates (2015). Iqtesad Iran be koja miravad? Kholaseh tarh motaleati tahleel avamel taseergozar bar amalkard myan moddat iqtesad Iran (Where the Iranian economy is going? A summary of study project regarding the analysis of factors impacting the performance of the Iranian economy in medium term), Tehran: Intesharat Donyai Iqtesad (in Persian).

  • Nomani, F., & Behdad, S. (2006). Class and Labor in Iran: Did the Revolution Matter? Syracuse University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noori, H. (1990). “Hookomat islami and naghsh Anfal” (The Islamic Government and the Role of Anfal), Hawza (in Persian), Numbers 37 and 38.

  • OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2009). Revolving doors, accountability and transparency. Public Governance Committee.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pryor, F. L. (2009). The political economy of a semi-industrialized theocratic state: The Islamic Republic of Iran. In M. Ferrero & R. Wintrobe (Eds.), The political economy of theocracy (pp. 243–270). Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rahman Zadeh Heravi, M. (2018). Negahi be Iqtesad Siasi Iran az Daheh 1340 ta 1395 (A glimpse over the political economy of Iran from 1961 until 2016) (first edn). Nashr Akhtaran (in Persian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rahnema, S. (1995). Continuity and change in industrial policy. In S. Rahnema & S. Behdad (Eds.), Iran after the revolution: Crisis of an Islamic State (pp. 129–49). I.B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rahnema, S., & Behdad, S. (1995). Introduction. In S. Rahnema & S. Behdad (Eds.), Iran after the revolution crisis of an Islamic State (pp. 1–18). I.B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riley, D., & Brenner, R. (2022). Seven theses on American politics. New Left Review, 138, 21–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saeidi, A. (2004). The accountability of para-governmental organizations (bonyads): The case of Iranian foundations. Iranian Studies, 37(3), 479–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tusi, M. I. H. (1955). Al-Iqtisad (economics). Ketabkhaneh Jamee Chehl Sotoon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2004). The political economy of destructive power. Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2015). The political economy of predation: Manhunting and the economics of Escape. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice, 168(3–4), 153–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2023). Destructive coordination, Anfal and Islamic Political Capitalism: A new reading of contemporary Iran. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Valadbaygi, K. (2021). Hybrid neoliberalism: Capitalist development in contemporary Iran. New Political Economy, 26(3), 313–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vukovic, V. (2021). The politics of bailouts: Estimating the causal effects of political connections on corporate bailouts during the 2008–2009 US financial crisis. Public Choice, 189, 213–238. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00871-w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber M. (1905/1985). The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism, translated by Talcott Parsons. London: Unwin.

  • Weber, M. (1922/1978). Economy and Society, Vol. 1. Berkeley: University of California Press.

  • Zingales, L. (2015). Presidential address: Does finance benefit society? The Journal of Finance, 70(4), 1327–1363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zingales, L. (2017). Towards a political theory of the firm. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31(3), 113–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mehrdad Vahabi.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

None.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vahabi, M. Islamic revolution and Anfal. Public Choice (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01129-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01129-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation