Skip to main content
Log in

Federal reserve appointments and the politics of senate confirmation

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the politicization of Federal Reserve (Fed) appointments. In contrast to the extant appointment literature’s almost exclusive focus on ideological proximity as a predictor of Fed nominations and confirmations, I theorize that senators will be more likely to vote against confirmation when their constituents have little confidence in the Fed because it allows them to more credibly defer blame on the Fed for economic downturns. Drawing on novel estimates of state-level confidence in the Fed as well as new common space estimates of senators’ and central bankers’ monetary policy preferences, I demonstrate that when constituents do not have confidence in the Fed, senators are less likely to vote in favor of confirmation regardless of their ideological proximity to the nominee. The results have important implications for the ability to fill Fed vacancies and, in turn, the balance of power between the Fed and regional bank Presidents in the monetary policymaking process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Prior to 2009, the majority of confirmation votes were taken as voice votes with neither a recorded roll call nor record of the chamber’s division. In the two decades from 1988 to 2008, only 5 of the 19 Fed nominations were taken by roll call.

  2. As noted in Adolph (2013, p. 246), the argument often is oversimplified and overstated in the extant research. For one, Rogoff (1985) shows that the social planner can achieve their preferred inflation outcomes better by delegating monetary authority to an individual who is more conservative than the planner him or herself, but not infinitely more or uniformly conservative as is often described. Furthermore, a substantial research agenda building on Toma (1982) and Shugart and Tollison (1983), among others, challenges the notion of central bankers as social planners and highlights the importance of central bankers’ preferences and the bureaucratic systems in which they operate.

  3. The nominations of both Marvin Goodfriend and Nellie Liang met that fate in 2017 and 2019, respectively.

  4. The Democratic senators who had supported Powell’s appointment to the Board previously but opposed his elevation to Chairman include Blumenthal (D-CT), Booker (D-NJ), Feinstein (D-CA), Gillibrand (D-NY), Markety (D-MA), and Warren (D-MA). The opposing coalition was joined by Harris (D-CA) and Merkley (D-OR), who had not cast votes for his 2014 confirmation.

  5. See Ainsley et al. (2020) for a more extensive discussion of the source of sample biases that emerge from the strategic selection of roll call votes.

  6. The method increasingly is the norm in state-level public opinion research and has been shown to produce estimates similar to state-level polls and outperform disaggregation even for much larger samples than the one relied on herein (Lax and Phillips 2009).

  7. All state-level party affiliation data are drawn from Gallup polls in Gallup US Daily.

  8. All estimates of state-level public opinion and replication data are available from the author upon request.

  9. All estimates of macroeconomic policy ideal points and the replication files to produce them are available from the author upon request.

  10. Recall that the reason the macroeconomic policy ideal points from Senate roll call vote records are insufficient on there own is that we need Fed nominees and senators placed in a common ideological space. Just as we cannot estimate individual \(\alpha _i\)’s for the 125 senators not on the banking committee because they do not participate in the committee hearings, nominees to the Fed do not vote on Senate legislation and thus we cannot estimate their ideological positions in that space.

  11. The results can be examined further by looking at second differences, as proposed by Berry et al. (2010) and Rainey (2016), to address the established problems with compression in limited dependent variable models. For senators not in the nominating president’s party, the estimated second difference is \(-0.487\) with a 95% confidence interval of \(\left[ -0.8, -.1\right]\); for senators in the nominating president’s party, the estimated second difference is \(-0.132\) with a 90% confidence interval of \(\left[ -0.26, -0.03\right]\).

References

  • Adolph, Christopher. (2013). Bankers, bureaucrats, and central bank politics: The myth of neutrality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ainsley, Caitlin. (2017). The politics of central bank appointments. Journal of Politics, 79(4), 1205–1219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainsley, Caitlin, Carrubba, Clifford J., Crisp, Brian F., Demirkaya, Betul, Gabel, Matthew J., & Hadzic, Dino. (2020). Roll-call vote selection: Implications for the study of legislative politics. American Political Science Review, 114, 691–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, James E. (1991). Leaning into the wind or ducking out of the storm? U.S. Monetary Policy in the 1980s. In Alberto Alesina & Geoffrey Carliner (Eds.), Politics and Economics in the 1980s (pp. 41–82). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, William D., DeMeritt, Jacqueline H. R., & Esarey, Justin. (2010). Testing for interaction in binary logit and probit models: Is a product term essential? American Journal of Political Science, 54, 248–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, Sarah, & Maltzman, Forrest. (2009). Advice and consent during the bush years: The politics of confirming federal judges. Judicature, 92, 320–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binder, Sarah, & Spindel, Mark. (2017). The myth of independence: How congress governs the federal reserve. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, Alan S., & Morgan, John. (2005). Are two heads better than one? Monetary policy by committee. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 37, 798–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, Charles M., Cover, Albert D., & Segal, Jeffrey A. (1990). Senate voting on supreme court nominees: A neoinstitutional model. American Political Science Review, 84, 525–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Kelly H. (2001). The president versus the senate: Appointments in the American system of separated powers and the federal reserve. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 17(2), 319–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Kelly H. (2003). Appointing central bankers: The politics of monetary policy in the United States and the European monetary union. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, Henry W., & McGregor, Rob Roy. (2000). A long history of FOMC voting behavior. Southern Economic Journal, 66, 906–922.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, Henry W., McGregor, Rob Roy, & Vermilyea, Todd. (2004). Committee decisions on monetary policy: Evidence from historical records of the federal open market committee. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, Henry W., Havrilesky, Thomas M., & McGregor, Rob Roy. (1993). Partisan monetary policies: Presidential influence through the power of appointment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 185–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, Lee, Lindstädt, René, Segal, Jeffrey A., & Westerland, Chad. (2006). The changing dynamics of senate voting on supreme court nominees. Journal of Politics, 68(2), 296–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, Thomas H., & Hill, Jeffrey S. (1993). Deference or preference? Explaining senate confirmation of presidential nominees to administrative agencies. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5(1), 23–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Havrilesky, Thomas. (1993). The pressures on American monetary policy. Norwell: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Havrilesky, Thomas. (1994). Outside influences on monetary policy: a summary of recent findings. Contemporary Economic Policy, 12(1), 46–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Havrilesky, Thomas, & Gildea, John. (1992). Reliable and unreliable partisan appointees to the Board of Governors. Public Choice, 73(4), 397–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imai, Kosuke, Lo, James, & Olmsted, Jonathan. (2016). Fast estimation of ideal points with massive data. American Political Science Review, 110(4), 631–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, Edward J. (1980). Politics and Fed policymaking The more things change the more they remain the same. Journal of Monetary Economics, 6(2), 199–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kastellec, Jonathan P., Lax, Jeffrey R., & Phillips, Justin H. (2010). Public opinion and senate confirmation of supreme court nominees. Journal of Politics, 72(3), 767–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keech, William R. (1994). Economic politics: The costs of democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keech, William R., & Morris, Irwin. (1997). Appointments, presidential power, and the federal reserve. Journal of Macroeconomics, 19, 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, Finn E., & Prescott, Edward C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lax, Jeffrey R., & Phillips, Justin H. (2009). How should we estimate public opinion in the states? American Journal of Political Science, 53(1), 107–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, Irwin L. (2000). Congress, the president, and the federal reserve: The politics of american monetary policy-making. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rainey, Carlisle. (2016). Compression and conditional effects: A product term is essential when using logistic regression to test for interaction*. Political Science Research and Methods, 4(3), 621–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, Kenneth. (1985). The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter, Alexander W., & Luther, William J. (2019). Adaptation and central banking. Public Choice, 180, 243–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaling, Eric. (1995). Institutions and monetary policy. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schnakenberg, Keith E., Turner, Ian R., & Uribe-McGuire, Alicia. (2017). Allies or commitment devices? A model of appointments to the Federal Reserve. Economics & Politics, 29, 118–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, William F., II., & Tollison, Robert D. (1983). Preliminary evidence on the use of inputs by the federal reserve system. American Economic Review, 73, 291–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smales, Lee A., & Apergis, Nick. (2016). The influence of FOMC member characteristics on the monetary policy decision-making process. Journal of Banking & Finance, 64, 216–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toma, Mark. (1982). Inflationary bias of the federal reserve system: A bureaucratic perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 163–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waller, Christopher J. (1992). A bargaining model of partisan appointments to the central bank. Journal of Monetary Economics, 29, 411–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woolley, John T. (1984). The federal reserve and the politics of monetary policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Caitlin Ainsley.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ainsley, C. Federal reserve appointments and the politics of senate confirmation. Public Choice 190, 93–110 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-021-00919-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-021-00919-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation