Skip to main content
Log in

Vertical Integration in the Japanese Movie Industry

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines vertical integration in the Japanese movie industry. I estimate an admission price equation, and a moviegoing demand equation derived from a discrete choice model of product differentiation. In order to overcome identification problems, this study exploits a panel structure dataset. My results show that the price of vertically integrated theaters tends to be higher than nonintegrated theaters, but it appears to be due to the inherent high quality of vertically integrated theaters. On the other hand, vertically integrated theaters are more popular among consumers and have higher attendance than nonintegrated theaters. Even after controlling the theater fixed effects, attendance for vertically integrated theaters is still larger than nonintegrated theaters. That is, the integration of producers/distributors and theaters is likely to be a source of economic efficiency. Policy implications are also proposed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Vertical integration is one of the hottest issues among antirust experts. As one may be able to recall, in 2001, although the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) had approved the proposed merger between General Electric and Honeywell after detailed investigation, the European Commission (EC) blocked the integration because of the threat of market foreclosure of aircraft engine and avionics firms through the bundling practice of the merging firms. Nalebuff (2009) conducted a detailed analysis of this case. Cooper et al. (2005a) conducted a comparative study of the U.S. and European Union approaches to vertical controls. In February 2007, the EC released the draft version of the guidelines for the assessment of the merger between companies in a vertical or conglomerate relationship in order to make the EC’s commitment more clear and predictable for businesses (see the EC (2007)).

  2. Cooper et al. (2005b) and Lafontaine and Slade (2007) comprehensively surveyed empirical studies of vertical integration/divestment and vertical controls.

  3. This subsection greatly depends on the literature listed in the References.

  4. Gil (2009b) points out that contracts between exhibitors and distributors generally are silent about movie run length and the revenue-sharing contract is a source of incentive misalignment between independent theaters and distributors. Details in movie contracts in Japan are not well known, however Kinema Junpo Film Institute (2005) reports that, generally, box office revenues are also shared by distributors and exhibitors and movie run length is determined between distributors and exhibitors ex-post, with given initial box office conditions as well as various other factors.

  5. This subsection also refers to Kaneyama (1994), Kinema Junpo Film Institute (2005), and Murakami and Ogawa (1999).

  6. There are many empirical IO studies using the nested logit model. For example, Ohashi (2003) studied the U.S. VCR market, Einav (2007) studied the U.S. movie market, and Clements and Ohashi (2005) and Corts and Lederman (2009) studied the U.S. video game market, using the nested logit model.

  7. Therefore, ξs include approximation errors.

  8. See Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry, Tokutei Sabisu Sangyo Jittai Chosa Hokokusho: Eigakan Hen (Report on Survey of Selected Service Industry: Movie Theaters), Tokyo: Keizai Sangyo Tokei Kyokai, each edition (in Japanese).

  9. Geographic market delineation is another important issue that must be examined. However, this is beyond the scope of this study and, therefore, I simply define each prefecture as a market. It must be noted that Japanese geographic features are very complicated: these consist of four large islands and many small ones, with the large islands including many mountains and rivers. The simple distance between two points tends not to represent the travel cost, because mountains and rivers may be located between the points. On the other hand, the borders of prefectures are typically defined by mountains and rivers; hence, the market definition of this study does not seem to cause serious problems.

  10. In this study, all distances between two points are calculated as the Great Circle Distance.

  11. In estimating the fixed effect model, three market dummies are dropped.

  12. The model does not include a constant term.

  13. Hanssen (2000) and Kenney and Klein (2000) study the economics of block booking.

  14. Orbach and Einav (2007) study uniform pricing in the U.S. movie exhibition market.

  15. In addition to the discounts for students and older people, there is the service day, on which the admission price is set at 1,000 JPY, and the ladies’ day, on which the price for females is discounted to 1,000 JPY. These are uniformly applied by almost all theaters.

References

  • Berry ST (1994) Estimating discrete-choice model of product differentiation. RAND J Econ 25(2):242–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry ST, Levinsohn J, Pakes A (1995) Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica 63(4):841–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blass A, Carlton DW (2001) The choice of organizational form in gasoline retailing and the cost of laws that limit that choice. J Law Econ 44(2):511–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chipty T (2001) Vertical integration, market foreclosure, and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. Am Econ Rev 91(3):428–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements M, Ohashi H (2005) Indirect network effects and the product cycle: video games in the U.S., 1994–2002. J Ind Econ 53(4):515–542

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper JC, Froeb LM, O’Brien D, Vita MG (2005a) A comparative study of United States and European union approaches to vertical policy. Geo. Mason L. Rev 13(2):289–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper JC, Froeb LM, O’Brien D, Vita MG (2005b) Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference. Int J Ind Organ 23(7–8):639–664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corts KS (2001) The strategic effects of vertical market structure: common agency and divisionalization in the US motion picture industry. J Econ Manage Strategy 10(4):509–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corts KS, Lederman M (2009) Software exclusivity and the scope of indirect network effects in the U.S. video game market. Int J Ind Organ 27(2):121–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis P (2006) Spatial competition in retail market: movie theaters. RAND J Econ 37(4):964–982

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vany A (2004) Hollywood Economics: How Extreme Uncertainty Shapes the Film Industry. Routledge, Abingdon

    Google Scholar 

  • Einav L (2007) Seasonality in the US motion picture industry. RAND J Econ 38(1):127–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2007) “Draft Commission Guidelines on the Assessment of Non-horizontal Mergers,” (http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/legislation/draft_nonhorizontal_mergers.pdf).

  • Gil R (2006) Make-or-buy in movie: integration and ex-post renegotiation. Int J Ind Organ 25(4):643–656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil R (2009a) “An Empirical Investigation of Paramount Antitrust Case,” forthcoming in Applied Economics.

  • Gil R (2009b) “Revenue Sharing Distortions and Vertical Integration in the Movie Industry,” forthcoming in Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.

  • Hanssen FA (2000) The block booking of films reexamined. J Law Econ 43(2):395–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings JS (2004) Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: empirical evidence from contract changes in Southern California. Am Econ Rev 94(1):317–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings JS, Gilbert RJ (2005) Market power, vertical integration and the wholesale price of gasoline. J Ind Econ 53(4):469–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin GZ, Leslie P (2009) Reputation incentives for restaurant hygiene. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 1(1):236–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaneyama K (1994) Eiga Kai ni Shinro wo Tore (Take the course toward Movie Business). Synergy Kikagaku, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenney RW, Klein B (2000) How booking facilitated self-enforcing film contracts. J Law Econ 43(2):427–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinema Junpo Film Institute (2005) Eiga Produsa no Kiso Chishiki (A Basic Guide for the Producer). Kinema Junpo, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine F, Slade M (2007) Vertical integration and firm boundaries: the evidence. J Econ Lit 45(3):629–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motion Picture Producers Association of Japan, Statistics of Film Industry in Japan: Year 1955–1999 & Year 2000–2006, (http://www.eiren.org/toukei/index.html), 2007 (in Japanese).

  • Murakami Y, Ogawa N (1999) Nihon Eiga Sangyo Saizensen (Japan Movie Now). Kadokawa Shoten, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Nalebuff B (2009) Bundling: GE-Honeywell (2001). In: Kwoka JE Jr, White LJ (eds) The Antitrust Revolution. Oxford University, Oxford, pp 416–440

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohashi H (2003) The role of indirect network effects in the U.S. VCR market, 1978–86. J Econ Manage Strategy 12(4):447–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orbach BY, Einav L (2007) Uniform prices for differentiated goods: the case of the movie-theater industry. Int Rev Law Econ 27(2):129–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepard A (1993) Contractual form, retail price, and asset characteristics in gasoline retailing. RAND J Econ 24(1):58–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slade M (1998) Beer and the Tie: Did Divestiture of Brewer-owned Public Houses Lead to Higher Beer Prices. Economic Journal 108(448):565–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki A (2009) Market foreclosure and vertical merger: a case study of the vertical merger between turner broadcasting and time warner. Int J Ind Organ 27(4):532–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toho Co. Ltd. (2008) “Fact Book,” http://www.toho.co.jp/toho_ir/pdfs/080422_factbook.pdf (in Japanese).

  • Vita M (2000) Regulatory restrictions on vertical integration and control: the competitive impact of gasoline divorcement policies. J. Regul. Econ. 18(3):217–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waterman D, Weiss AA (1996) The effects of vertical integration between cable television systems and pay cable networks. J Econom 72(1–2):357–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to express sincere gratitude to the editor (Michael Peneder) and an anonymous referee. I am also thankful to attendees at seminars at the Competition Policy Research Center (CPRC), Aoyama Gakuin, the Japan Economic Association annual meetings, and the Canadian Law and Economics Association meetings, for their valuable comments and suggestions. This is an outgrowth of research projects at the CPRC. I would like to thank the Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry and the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications for allowing me to use the data used in this study. The views expressed in this paper are mine, and do not reflect the views of the CPRC, the Japan Fair Trade Commission, or any individual commissioner. Needless to say, all remaining errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mitsuru Sunada.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sunada, M. Vertical Integration in the Japanese Movie Industry. J Ind Compet Trade 10, 135–150 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-009-0059-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-009-0059-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation