Introduction

A rich body of literature addresses the question of how separation affects parents’ economic well-being (e.g., Bianchi et al., 1999; Smock, 1994). Different measures have been employed, for example individual and family income (Poortman, 2000), housing costs (Bröckel & Andreß, 2015), and wealth (Boertien & Lersch, 2021; Kapelle & Baxter, 2021). Regarding social inequality of economic well-being after separation, a variety of studies point to the relevance of socio-demographics, such as couple and child characteristics before and after separation, and the parent’s gender (Hao, 1996; Poortman, 2000; Ross, 1995; Smock, 1993). Post-separation parental behavior has attracted less attention in this regard. As time spent with children cannot be spent doing paid work, parental employment opportunities and earnings post-separation notably hinge on the ex-partner’s childcare involvement. This is particularly true for mothers. The interplay of labor market dynamics and family demographics produces parenthood wage gaps (van Winkle & Fasang, 2020) that can be more detrimental for women in the case of ‘absent fathers’ after separation. Germany is an interesting case to study in this context, as almost every third marriage dissolves (Federal Statistical Office, 2021), but shared parenting is still rather scarce (Walper et al., 2016, 2020) despite the introduction of major family policy reforms geared towards boosting work-family balance and paternal family involvement over the last two decades. Instead, the predominant post-separation model is characterized by resident mothers and non-resident fathers (Köppen, 2018). Thus, care-active fathers should make a difference for mothers’ post-separation economic well-being.

This article aims to investigate the association between the economic well-being of mothers and fathers and post-separation paternal childcare involvement in Germany. This explorative analysis necessarily remains purely descriptive in absence of an adequate (quasi-) experimental setting, which would allow for a causal analysis. In particular we are unable to explore potential endogeneities of union dissolution, of the pre-separation division of labor within the couple, or even of union formation, which might be driven by the same factors that shape parents’ economic well-being thereafter. However, our study provides interesting insights into the potential mechanisms behind income evolution post-separation and their associations with paternal childcare engagement. Moreover, we uncover the importance of specification issues.

Based on German panel data for separated parents (both formerly cohabiting and formerly married) and referring to the post-separation year with respect to the pre-separation year, the study explores the short-term gender and group associations with parental economic well-being. Focusing on the predominant post-separation model of resident mothers and nonresident fathers, we add to the previous literature by observing both ex-partners. This allows us to explore paternal childcare on weekdays reported by fathers themselves, and to employ a measure of household income after exchange of alimony/child maintenance payments among ex-partners (which, in the SOEP data is only possible when both ex-partners are observed). There is only one previous study employing a similar sample for the U.S. context: Bianchi et al. (1999) are limited to a similarly small sample size due to the requirement of following both ex-partners after separation. We update their analysis in the German context, add a focus on post-separation paternal childcare involvement, and additionally consider non-married separated couples.

Background and Hypotheses

Social scientists have employed a variety of theories to explain how union dissolution affects adults and children (cf. Amato, 2000, 2010). From the economic standpoint conveyed in the resource model (Johnson & Wu, 2002; McLanahan & Sandefur, 1994; Soons et al., 2009), separation is related to economic costs such as the loss of a second income, lost economies of scale and foregone earnings due to increased childcare obligations. Depending on their individual endowments with human capital, social networks and physical attractiveness, parents are differently protected against these risks. Individual resources act as moderators, determining the speed with which parents manage to adjust (Amato, 2000).Footnote 1 Parents (mostly mothers) who have been specializing in unpaid work during marriage suffer from decreased employment and earning capacities since their human capital depreciates during that time (Duncan & Hoffman, 1985; Sørensen, 1994). This decline in individual resources is partly compensated by public and private transfer receipts which rely on social policies and spousal alimony obligations, respectively. However, alimony payments often do not suffice to fully cover child maintenance, inducing a further decline in resources (Leopold & Kalmijn, 2016). Instead, repartnering proves to be an effective strategy combatting material hardship after separation, especially for women (Duncan & Hoffman, 1985).

Studies based on German data come to different conclusions on the permanence of income losses after separation, depending on the data and sample. Augustijn (2022) investigates the association between separated mothers’ subjective evaluations of economic well-being and the physical custody arrangement, based on a sample drawn from the 2019 Family Models in Germany (FAMOD) study. The researcher  concludes that mothers in joint custody settings fare better than their peers with sole custody. This still holds when pre-separation couple constellations and individual characteristics are taken into account. Radenacker (2020) finds that the employment and earnings of West German mothers who divorced between 2008 and 2015 increased considerably within a four-year window around separation, albeit remaining far below the levels necessary for financial independence. Brüggmann (2020) explores the employment and income effects of divorce for West German women between 2000 and 2005 and finds that marginal employment is reduced and regular employment is increased after divorce, but there is no impact on daily earnings. Leopold and Kalmijn (2016) focus on a period spanning one year before separation to five years thereafter, and find that declines in economic well-being for mothers with preschool age children were sharper than for fathers. However, according to their findings, most declines were only temporary, with divorced parents approaching childless divorcees over time. Bröckel and Andreß (2015) refer to a time span that covers the year before divorce up to two years thereafter. They find that even after the turn of the millennium, in spite of increasing female labor participation and the expansion of public childcare economic consequences of divorce in terms of equivalized disposable income were still more negative for women than for men.

Overall, the literature points to the importance of two main factors for economic conditions after separation: first, post-separation behavior, and second, pre-separation conditions. Specifically, mothers can reap the returns from pre-separation human capital investment only if they spend sufficient time on the labor market post-separation. Here, paternal childcare time comes into play, yet this important driver of parental well-being post-separation has seldomly been analyzed so far. There are good reasons to expect that non-resident fathers spend less time with their children compared to before separation, since not residing with the child means less contact opportunities and practical barriers hindering access to the child.Footnote 2 This includes the time that is spent on planning and organizing daily family life, which is referred to as ‘mental labor’ in the literature (Hochschild, 2012). Koster et al. (2021) argue that the residence-gradient in childcare should be higher for fathers since in the context of traditional gender roles, fathers are less expected to act as the primary caretakers than mothers. However, if even non-resident fathers, representing the major subgroup of separated fathers in Germany, provide sufficient (measurable) variation in their weekly childcare time, the association with maternal economic well-being poses an interesting empirical question. This is even more the case if labor market activity is a feasible option for mothers. Despite a still dominant resident-mother normFootnote 3 in today’s Germany, a change towards more egalitarian attitudes has become evident in recent years (Blohm & Walter, 2018; Danzer et al., 2021), triggered by major policy reforms such as the parental leave reform in 2007 (Unterhofer & Wrohlich, 2017; Zoch & Schober, 2018). Hence, separated mothers with care-active ex-partners are “allowed” to use released time budgets for gainful work. This further strengthens our expectation that care-active fathers should make a difference for separated mothers’ economic well-being.

However, increased childcare engagement on the part of fathers, freeing up maternal time for gainful employment, and new social norms encouraging mothers to take up this option do not suffice: women must also have access to attractive wages. Poor human capital endowment pre-separation, be it due to low formal qualifications and/or high levels of depreciation of human capital in the course of family breaks, limits potential returns to maternal employment post-separation. Generally speaking, economic activity post-separation might be endogenous, reflecting selection processes prior to separation. There is myriad empirical evidence hinting at potential selectivity of union formation (e.g., Greenwood et al., 2014; Guner et al., 2018; Lichter et al., 2022), of intra-couple labor division during marriage (e.g., Boll et al., 2014; Bredemeier & Juessen, 2013; Fleche et al. 2020; Goussé et al., 2017) and of separation (e.g., Amato, 2000; Bredemeier et al., 2021; Lise & Yamada, 2019; Voena, 2015)Footnote 4 along specific individual characteristics. Moreover, the endogeneity of separation is theoretically motivated by rational choice models, comparing anticipated individual utility and costs of staying vs. leaving the union (Becker et al., 1977; Thibaut & Kelley, 1959). In light of this literature, it seems that paternal childcare behavior post-separation and resulting economic outcomes are also at least partly endogenous, shaped by the same factors underlying pre-separation conditions, i.e. individual and couple traits and constellations, as well as opportunity structures. We argue that at least part of this endogeneity should be filtered out by our restricting our sample to separated parental couples only, and our employing an individual fixed effects approach. Moreover, our descriptive evidence on pre-separation human capital endowments at least partly advocates against endogeneity/reverse causality. Nevertheless, our analysis makes no claim to causality in the absence of exogenous variation in post-separation paternal childcare involvement.

Added Value and Hypotheses of this Study

In contrast to previous studies, this study presents a more comprehensive and economically integrated approach covering both mothers and fathers. We explore the short-term group and gender differentials in economic well-being for the time around separation. Using German panel data, we measure economic well-being by equivalized net household income (ENHI). This allows us to infer parents’ monetary risks around separation, which cannot be inferred from subjective indicators such as satisfaction with household income (which we also examine). Further, ENHI allows us to monitor underlying mechanisms such as changes in household composition, earnings, and public and private transfers. We extend the study of Bröckel and Andreß (2015) by using a more recent panel, and by extending the focus to also include non-married separated couples. We further contribute to the literature by investigating economic well-being after exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments among the ex-partners, which is a new and unique feature of our study.

Second, we take a closer look at real (ex-)couples’ economic well-being around separation, linking post-separation economic outcomes to post-separation childcare arrangements and to pre-separation conditions. Comparing (ex-) partners of real couples instead of unrelated mothers and fathers allows us to establish a common point of reference, i.e. the joint household of the couple before separation. That is, gender gaps in economic outcomes after separation are more “pure” in our analysis since cross-couple heterogeneity in within-couple gender differences are filtered out. Different from Bianchi et al. (1999), who also investigate real (ex-)couples, we additionally consider non-married separated couples.

Third, by focusing on non-zero paternal childcare time on a typical weekday, we acknowledge that daily parenting practices should have direct implications for parents’ post-separation employment and partner market opportunities, both shaping parental economic well-being after separation. At the same time, as the literature has shown, parenting decisions after separation are arguably influenced by individual traits and the former couple constellation. Observing relevant pre-separation conditions, we are able to reveal path dependencies in childcare behavior. This approach allows us to explore potential human capital differences pre-separation that could motivate post-separation time use. Thus, we can at least qualitatively assess potential endogeneity of time use for childcare and employment post-separation, driven by income-relevant selection processes pre-separation. At the same time, we are aware that we are able to grasp only part of the selection processes, since neither marriage formation nor separation are random, but are instead likely to be driven by unobserved traits which at the same time shape post-separation behavior and economic welfare.Footnote 5

The following hypotheses guide our study:

Based on an evidently stronger labor market attachment for fathers, we expect them to achieve higher incomes post-separation (t+1) in both groups compared to their female ex-partners (role of gender with respect to income—H1).

Second, we postulate that mothers with ex-partners who are involved in childcare in the year after separation should experience a more favorable income evolution, compared to mothers practicing sole maternal care (role of paternal childcare with respect to maternal income—H2).

Third, we hypothesize that mothers with ex-partners who are involved in childcare in the post-separation year should experience a stronger increase in paid hours and earnings, compared to mothers practicing sole maternal care (role of paternal childcare with respect to maternal paid hours and earnings—H3).

Data and Method

We use the unique survey data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP), which is a representative longitudinal survey of over 25,000 individuals from about 16,000 households (Goebel et al., 2019; SOEP, 2020).

Sample

The sample consists of separated couples (1) with children under 16,Footnote 6 who cohabitated in the year preceding the separation, (2) in which mother and fatherFootnote 7 did not continue cohabitation after separation, (3) in which all minor children live with the mother in the post-separation year, and (4) for whom interviews were successfully conducted in the mother’s and father’s households annually from the pre-separation year (t−1) at least up until the calendar year post-separation (t+1). The year of separation (t0) refers to the information provided by the respondents in the annual survey’s individual questionnaire asking for information regarding changes in one’s family situation.Footnote 8 In the case of several observed consecutive separations, we refer to the first separation that occurred after the birth of a mother’s firstborn child. The sample reduces substantially during sample selection: among 1656 separated mothers with a child under 16 at the time of her first separation occurring after the birth of their firstborn, for only 645 can we both identify the partner from whom these women are separating as the parent of at least one biological child from this relationship and also observe this partner in the survey data. Only 347 remain once we restrict our sample to separating couples that were observed and were not cohabiting in the post-separation year. Finally, for 176 separating couples (176 fathers and 176 mothers), we observe in the survey data that all minor children live with the mother post-separation, and additionally observe information on our key variables concerning childcare and household income both pre- and post-separation for both ex-partners. Note that of previous studies, that with the closest approach to ours, Bianchi et al. (1999), yields a similarly small sample size of 199 separated couples due to the prerequisite of observing both partners around separation.

Our final main analysis sample hence consists of 176 separating couples for which we observe the immediate pre- and post-separation period over the years 1998 to 2018. We restrict our sample to this particular period, since a distinct measure of alimony and child maintenance payments received is not available prior to this date in the SOEP data. This measure is needed to construct equivalized net household income after exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments among the ex-partners (see Sect. 3.2 for more details). Figure 1 displays the distribution of separation years for the separating couples in our analysis sample.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source SOEP v.35, own calculations

Sample distribution of year of separation (t0).

Variables

Dependent Variables

Regarding economic outcomes, individual gross annual labor earnings capture regular income from paid work.Footnote 9 According to neoclassical models, gross earnings are closely related to market productivity. In economic theory, gross earnings reflect a partner’s market productivity, and thus together with household productivity, her comparative advantage for market work (Becker, 1965), and her economic autonomy after union dissolution, impacting bargaining power during marriage (Manser & Brown, 1980; McElroy & Horney, 1981). However, individual earnings are not appropriate for measuring individual economic well-being. If, as is standard in economic theory, one assumes that economic well-being arises from consumption opportunities and leisure, net household income is more adequate. Further, household size must be taken into account.

We therefore generate the measure equivalized net household income (ENHI), using the weights from the OECD’s modified scale (OECD, 1982). Net household income, from which ENHI is derived, is measured for the previous year and relies on the variable “household post-government income” (i11102) provided by the SOEP team in the $PEQUIV dataset (Grabka, 2020). We modify the original variable in several ways. First, we recode the variable to represent the net household income of each respective survey year (instead of the calendar year preceding the interview). Second, we aim at measuring household income after exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments among the ex-partners. Hence, received child support and alimony payments reported by the recipient partner are included in the recipients’ household income and are subtracted from the ex-partners’ household income post-separation. We term this the ‘symmetric approach’. Note that it is our unique sample of parental separations for which we observe both ex-partners pre- and post-separation that allows us to subtract monthly spouse and child maintenance payments received by one ex-partner from the paying ex-partner’s net household income.Footnote 10 We build the ENHI variable for mothers’ and fathers’ incomes around separation (from t−1 to t+1) employing the time-varyingFootnote 11 Modified OECD Equivalence Weights (Hagenaars et al., 1994).

To illustrate the distinctive features of our proposed “symmetric approach” to account for post-separation exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments among the ex-partners, we additionally measure ENHI using what we call the ‘asymmetric approach’, which is simply what is provided as the original variable of net household income in the SOEP $PEQUIV dataset. It includes received spouse and child maintenance payments, but it does not subtract paid spouse and child maintenance payments (Grabka, 2020, p. 42).Footnote 12 Table 2 in the Appendix, which reports the mean values of our key variables, depicts NHI and ENHI for mothers and fathers in our sample both according to the asymmetric and the symmetric approach. Using the asymmetric approach leads to a higher paternal income (both NHI and ENHI) in year t+1. Specifically, fathers experience an ENHI increase in this setting. The reason why is that in the asymmetric approach, alimony and maintenance payments are not deducted from the payer’s income. Since there are male payers only, maternal income is unaffected. Henceforth, we stick to the ‘symmetric approach’. We argue that accounting for these payments both on the recipient’s and the payer’s side renders income measures more informative with respect to disposable income. Concentrating on the symmetric approach, it turns out that both fathers and mothers experience a decrease in mean income around separation. Obviously, the deduction of alimony payments on the side of fathers more than outweighs the household composition effect. Additionally, since fathers regularly earn higher incomes, the lost second labor income should harm maternal income more strongly than paternal income. This negative effect adds to unchanged household composition for mothers, which is why income decrease is more pronounced for mothers.

Core Explanatory Variables

Concerning parents’ time investments into children after separation, which potentially affect parents’ economic well-being after separation, we focus on fathers’ childcare time on weekdays, since in only 9.09% of separations in our sample do mothers spend zero hours on childcare in the year after separation on a typical weekday, but this holds true for 71.02% of fathers (see Table 2 in the Appendix).Footnote 13 Childcare time is reported as average hours on a usual weekday, which we employ as a dichotomous indicator of “zero hours” vs. “more than zero hours” spent on childcare by fathers. Childcare time during the weekend is not included in this measure since it is not available continuously throughout our observation period. Thus, when we term fathers “care-inactive” in this study, we refer to whether they report spending any time on childcare during weekdays in the year after separation.

Irrespective of fathers’ daily childcare involvement, our sample consists of resident mothers, i.e. all minor children reside with the mother after separation. Therefore, it is the father’s post-separation equivalized income only that can be affected by a decreasing number of minor biological children in the household after separation. In contrast, both parents’ equivalized incomes are subject to repartnering processes, and repartnering might go hand in hand with stepchildren moving in (although this is seldom the case—only 4.5% of mothers and 12.5% of fathers have repartnered in t+1).

To further explore the interrelations between parental childcare arrangements and economic well-being, the sample is stratified into two groups (Table 1), with one group comprising separations where the father’s childcare time on weekdays is zero (125 separations) and a second group consisting of separations where the father spends at least some regular time with the child(ren) during weekdays (51 separations). The former is the group which most strongly adheres to traditional gender roles, shifting the full burden of childcare onto the mother.Footnote 14 We hence call couples in the former group “Traditionalist”, and couples in the latter group “Care-Sharer”.

Table 1 Two groups according to paternal childcare time in the post-separation year (t+1)

Methods

Given the limited sample size, and in absence of an adequate (quasi-)experimental setting (that would allow for a causal analysis), we perform a purely descriptive exploratory analysis. For the two groups of separated couples (with and without paternal childcare involvement on weekdays), we calculate and plot predicted group means of the outcome variables with their 95% confidence intervals for two points in time relative to the year of separation (t)—t−1 and t+1. We do the same for a selected number of additional key variables. We adjust for calendar year fixed effects in all analyses. This way, inflation is filtered out, which is necessary to compare monetary terms across time, and any other time-specific effects are also filtered out. Note that although a differentiation by divorce cohorts would be desirable to trace e.g. policy reforms, this is not possible in our case due to small observation numbers.

Regarding outcome variables, we refer to ENHI and NHI to test our hypotheses H1 and H2. Regarding additional key variables, we calculate and plot their mean predicted values to be able to detect underlying changes in components of net household income. These are mothers’ and fathers’ gross annual labor earnings, public and private transfers, received alimony and child maintenance payments (as a component of private transfers), contractually agreed weekly working hours, and childcare hours. Maternal earnings and paid hours are used to test hypothesis H3.

We run regressions with individual fixed effects for mothers and fathers separately. With the pre-separation income level as our reference, we explore the statistical significance of group differences in income changes over time. In particular, we estimate the following equation

$${\text{ln}}(y_{itc} ) = \theta + \beta_{1} \alpha_{t} + { }\beta_{2} Group_{i} + \beta_{3} (\alpha_{t} \times Group_{i} ) + { }\delta_{{\text{c}}} + u_{i} + \varepsilon_{itc} ,$$
(1)

where \({y}_{itc}\) is the outcome of interest (ENHI of mothers or fathers, respectively) observed for parent i in period t (with t = [pre-separation year t−1; post-separation year t+1]) in calendar year c. The indicator of the post-separation year (\({\alpha }_{t}\)) is interacted with\({Group}_{i}\), which is an indicator variable for paternal care-involvement groups, as specified earlier in Sect. 3.2: The “Traditionalist” group comprises separations with care-inactive fathers, the “Care-Sharer” group consists of separations with care-active fathers who provide at least some regular childcare during weekdays in the year after separation. The equation includes a Constant (\(\theta\)), calendar year fixed effects (\({\delta }_{\mathrm{c}}\)), individual fixed effects (\({u}_{i}\)), and a time-varying random error term (\(\varepsilon_{itc}\)).This specification corresponds to the standard difference-in-differences setup with two-way fixed effects. However, in the absence of exogenous variation in post-separation paternal childcare involvement, it has no causal interpretation, since the assumption of parallel trends cannot be made. Additionally, setups with two-way fixed effects rely on a constant-effect assumption (see de Chaisemartin & D'Haultfoeuille, 2022 for a survey of the recent literature), e.g. over time (in our case: calendar year of separation), which equally cannot be made.

Results

Figure 2 illustrates the difference in household income post-separation between the asymmetric (Panel 2a) and the symmetric approach (Panel 2b) and depending on whether equivalence weights are used (ENHI) or not (NHI).Footnote 15

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source SOEP v.35; own calculations

Predicted group means of equivalized annual net household income (ENHI) of mothers and fathers (to the left) and of annual net household income (NHI) of mothers and fathers (to the right), both in Euros. Asymmetric approach: (equivalized) annual net household income includes received alimony and child maintenance payments among the ex-partners, while paid alimony and child maintenance payments are not subtracted. Symmetric approach: (equivalized) annual net household income calculated after exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments among ex-partners, i.e., received child support and alimony payments reported by the recipient partner are included in the recipients’ household income and are subtracted from the ex-partners’ household income post-separation. Adjusted for survey year fixed effects. “Traditionalist”: all children reside with mother, no paternal childcare on weekdays. “Care-Sharer”: all children reside with mother, some paternal childcare on weekdays.

Annual net household income (NHI) decreases for both sexes and groups in both specification settings. However, equivalized income (ENHI) clearly increases for both father groups in the specification referring to the asymmetric approach (Panel 2a), while it decreases and stagnates for Traditionalist and Care-Sharer-fathers, respectively, based on the symmetric approach (Panel 2b). Thus, fathers’ financial situations are much less advantageous once the payment of alimony and child maintenance is taken into account (symmetric approach). In the remainder of the paper, we hence employ the symmetric approach.

Under the symmetric approach, it becomes evident that predicted group means accounting for year fixed effects support the descriptive findings stating that all four groups experience an NHI decrease, which translates into an ENHI decrease for all groups except Care-Sharer-fathers: their equivalized income stagnates. Thus, focusing on total annual income only would miss an important part of the story.

It turns out that particularly for care-active fathers (Care-Sharer), the financial situation is less negative when referring to equivalized instead of total annual income, due to a favorable change in household composition. Since all minor children in our sample reside with the mother post-separation, and only 12.5% of fathers (and 4.5% of mothers) have a new partner residing with them in the year succeeding separation, father-headed households are likely to decrease in size.

We argue that equivalized net household income (after exchange of alimony and child maintenance payments) is the relevant measure for economic well-being, since it accounts for the (cost-relevant) household composition. For this reason, at-risk-of-poverty rates refer to equivalized household income (Eurostat, 2021; OECD, 2022). Our findings indicate that economic risks increase for both groups of resident mothers and for nonresident care-inactive fathers. Referring to the gender income gap in year t+1, Care-Sharer fathers are clearly ahead of Care-Sharer-mothers (the average gap amounts to 3.318€), but the income difference is marginal between Traditionalist-parents (the average gap amounts to 780€). Thus, hypothesis H1 is only partially confirmed by our data. Care-Sharer-fathers faring better than Traditionalist-fathers is a somewhat puzzling result at first sight, which we further investigate later on. When it comes to hypothesis H2, our findings do not find any support, since mothers whose ex-partners engage in some childcare during the week do not fare better than mothers who bear the full childcare burden.

Before we delve into a more detailed descriptive analysis of the underlying mechanisms behind the results presented so far, we aim to isolate the association of parental childcare behavior with economic success post-separation in a multivariate analysis. To this end, we employ Eq. (1) and regress the (log of) our main outcome variable, equivalized annual net household income (ENHI), on a group dummy additional to individual and year fixed effects. The coefficients on time-group interactions indicate that the group differences in household income change around separation net of any time-invariant individual and calendar year effects. As Table 4 in the Appendix shows, the multivariate results confirm the predicted values shown in Fig. 2 for both parents. For fathers, estimated group differences in post-separation ENHI changes amount to about 19%. While this difference is not statistically significant in the OLS model with year fixed effects only (Column 3), statistical significance emerges in panel regressions once individual fixed effects are included (Column 4). While Traditionalist-fathers experience on average a 19% decline in ENHI, this is not the case for Care-Sharer-fathers, whose ENHI remains on average rather stable. Among mothers, the average decline in ENHI is estimated to be about 30%, with no significant group differences. In sum, Care-Sharer-fathers’ ENHI lead over Traditionalist-fathers is confirmed when observed or unobserved time invariant characteristics, potentially reflecting selection into groups, are accounted for in the within-person perspective. On the other hand, no significant group differences can be ascertained for mothers.

To better understand the mechanisms behind the divergent income patterns, we conduct two exercises. First, we look at the components of income—mainly labor income and received transfers—to identify the relevant drivers. Additionally, we explore pre-separation conditions to qualitatively assess potential selection into groups, potentially reflecting childcare preferences and shaping labor market options after separation.

Panel 3a and 3b of Fig. 3 illustrate the evolution of parents’ employment probabilities and annual labor earnings around separation. The well-known gender gaps in employment and earnings become apparent: both paternal employment and paternal earnings lie well above maternal ones, for both groups and at both points in time.Footnote 16 Interestingly, Traditionalist-mothers show the most favorable earnings trend, while the earnings of the other groups either stagnate and show only a minor increase. The earnings lead of fathers becomes plausible when considering human capital endowments (see Table 3 in Appendix). Whereas genders are almost equally equipped with educational credentials (on average 12 years of education), fathers have a lead over mothers in terms of full-time work experience (on average more than twice the years); this holds for both groups. According to human capital theory (Becker, 1964; Mincer, 1974), the higher on-the-job-training translates into higher earnings. As Panel 3c of Fig. 3 shows, the well-known gender difference in working hours contributes to the gender gap in earnings. Although both groups of mothers increase their agreed hoursFootnote 17 after separation, they do not manage to catch up with fathers. Further, the increase in hours for Care-Sharer-mothers does not translate into increased earnings.Footnote 18 However, neither on the side of mothers, nor of fathers do considerable group differences in pre-separation human capital emerge. The same results apply for differences in age or self-assessed health. Thus, inter-group pre-separation human capital differences can hardly be blamed for diverging post-separation economic conditions.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Source SOEP v.35; own calculations

Predicted group means of parents’ employment (1 = employed, 0 otherwise), parents’ annual earnings (in Euros), contractually agreed weekly working hours and childcare time on weekdays (in hours) around separation. Adjusted for survey year fixed effects. “Traditionalist”: all children reside with mother, no paternal childcare on weekdays. “Care-Sharer”: all children reside with mother, some paternal childcare on weekdays.

In sum, the results for earnings and hours do not support our hypothesis H3. Presumably, strategic behavior in terms of increased hours of work before separation is partly inhibited here, since mothers anticipate their consistently high childcare obligations in the post-separation period, which discourages them from increasing their labor market involvement pre-separation. Brüggmann (2020) confirms this strategic behavior for German women divorcees. What cannot be examined here is whether mothers trade earnings for higher flexibility (Gangl & Ziefle, 2009).

Fathers show different trends in working hours, which only partly manifest in earnings evolution. Care-Sharer-fathers might combine a modest increase in hours with switching to a job with more flexible schedules, which comes with lower hourly earnings. Traditionalist-fathers’ decrease in hours is striking, especially in the context of this group’s zero childcare hours in year t+1 (Panel 3d of Fig. 3). Potential endogeneity due to selection processes occurring many years before separation cannot be ruled out here, and they can only partly be addressed by our fixed effects-approach. At least, a lower income capacity of Traditionalist-fathers compared to Care-Sharer-fathers seems unlikely, since they had higher earnings pre-separation; moreover, they manage to keep their earnings stable over time. Another explanation would be that Traditionalist-fathers tend to shift their attention to something else, which could be a new partnership and stepchildren. Koster et al. (2021) refer to traditional gender roles when expecting a more pronounced resident gradient in childcare hours for fathers. Further, there seems to be evidence for the notion that fathers tend to shift their attention to children with whom they live (Fuerstenberg & Cherlin, 1991). Note that we refer to gross earnings here to circumvent any biases from changes in marital status.

Additionally, we compare weekly work hours with parents’ childcare time on weekdays. Panel 3d of Fig. 3 reveals the well-known gender gap in unpaid work, which still holds after separation and irrespective of partners’ childcare arrangements. While fathers reduce their engagement even further, mothers stick to their primary carer role, and this holds particularly true for Care-Sharer-mothers. Care-Sharer-mothers seem to strive for intense parenthood before and after separation (see Table 3 in Appendix). They spent on average 7.84 h per day on childcare the year prior to separation (Traditionalist-mothers: 7.10 h), and they barely reduce their childcare after separation with 7.24 h in year t+1 (Traditionalist-mothers: 6.04 h). Apart from differences in preferences, the higher engagement of Care-Sharer-mothers could also relate to the younger age of their children (94% of group 2-mothers, but only 83% of Traditionalist-mothers have a child under 14 in the household). As a result, and despite paternal engagement during weekdays, Care-Sharer-mothers remain involved after separation with higher hours compared to Traditionalist-mothers, which might explain the more favorable earnings trend of Traditionalist-mothers.

As we have seen, Care-Sharer-mothers increase their paid hours, but see their earnings stagnate, pointing to adjusted working conditions offering a better fit with high family demands. Earlier on, we opted for a similar interpretation of Care-Sharer-fathers’ behavior, and indeed, Care-Sharer-fathers were more involved in childcare before separation compared to Traditionalist-fathers (3.41 h vs. 1.80 h, see Table 3 in Appendix), and remain so afterwards (2.65 h vs. 0.00 h). Thus, the group differentiation reveals that Care-Sharer-parents can be characterized as more childcare-oriented throughout separation, notwithstanding the severe gender gaps which also emerge here. Additionally, Care-Sharer-couples divorce later on average, with potentially stronger family ties for Care-Sharer-fathers as a cause or consequence, but in any case, associated with stronger paternal childcare investment.Footnote 19

Next, we explore the role of public and private transfers for parents’ economic well-being after separation. As Panel 4a of Fig. 4 illustrates, Traditionalist-mothers experience a marginal increase and Care-Sharer-mothers a slight decrease in public transfer receipts around separation, while fathers receive much less than before separation. Additional analyses show that the notion of a less advantageous evolution of public transfers for fathers remains valid if child-related components of public transfers (child allowance, additional child benefit, childcare subsidy) are excluded.Footnote 20 It appears that either mothers or children are in most cases the primary recipients of public transfers. Moreover, mothers experience a notable increase in private transfers around separation, which is starkest for Traditionalist-mothers, who bear the full childcare burden (see Panel 4b of Fig. 4). This seems plausible since Care-Sharer-fathers should be compensated for their non-zero childcare hours by somewhat lower payments. Note that our sample of real (ex-)couples allows us to approximately equate average payments received with average payments made within the same group. In contrast, private transfer receipts are irrelevant to fathers. A decomposition analysis of private transfers confirms this view. In particular, these findings are still valid if one focuses on alimony and child maintenance receipt only, which represent two out of five components of aggregate private transfers (see Panel 4c of Fig. 4). Summarizing the results for fathers so far, we find that while fathers’ equivalized income benefits from a decreasing household size in both groups, Traditionalist-fathers do not manage to translate their higher time budget for gainful work into sufficiently high earnings to outweigh the relative higher alimony and child maintenance payments with respect to Care-Sharer-fathers.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source SOEP v.35; own calculations

Predicted group means of parents’ public and private transfers (alimony and child maintenance payments) received (in Euros) around separation. Adjusted for survey year fixed effects. Traditionalist: all children reside with mother, no paternal childcare on weekdays. Care-Sharer: all children reside with mother, some paternal childcare on weekdays.

Finally, we test whether actual income evolution corresponds to subjective evaluations of economic well-being. Figure 5 in the Appendix depicts the results. It becomes evident that mothers’ evaluations closely fit the actual financial situation, while Traditionalist-(Care-Sharer-) fathers perceive their situation as better (worse) than it is according to the ENHI measure proposed in this study. This does not necessarily mean distorted paternal receptions, since measurement errors in our data may occur in different areas, e.g. understated true childcare obligations, psycho-emotional burden, or understated financial burden (we do not measure discretionary cash transfers) of fathers who are emotionally bonded to their children but live separately from them. In the end, the perceived situation may come closer to the truth than what quantitative measures suggest. It therefore does not come as a surprise that life satisfaction decrease is less pronounced for mothers compared to fathers (see Panel A1c of Figure A1), which confirms previous findings (Leopold & Kalmijn, 2016).

Conclusion

In an economically integrated approach covering real (ex-)couples, we explore the short-term group and gender differentials in economic well-being for the time around separation. We refer to the standard in contemporary Germany, a female resident-parent setting. Our main focus is on the associations with paternal childcare post-separation. Our data confirm the well-known gender gap in income, which persists throughout separation, albeit being more pronounced among those ex-couples where fathers spend some hours caring for their children on weekdays. Those fathers experience stable equivalized income around separation, while mothers and care-inactive fathers suffer a decline, which clearly contradicts our expectations. However, after considering this more carefully, this seems somewhat plausible since fathers with zero childcare hours on weekdays are confronted with higher alimony payments and at the same time fail to increase their earnings accordingly, resulting in an income disadvantage compared to fathers with non-zero childcare hours. However, the childcare support in the “non-zero childcare hours” father group (Care Sharer) is presumably too low to make a difference for maternal careers, earnings and equivalized income: mothers formerly coupled with those fathers do not fare better economically than their female counterparts who take on the full childcare burden. An explanation for this unexpected result is that despite the help from their ex-spouses, those mothers still spend more time on childcare on weekdays, presumably due to younger children and/or preferences for higher childcare standards. Pre-separation group differences in mother’s human capital are unlikely to play a role in explaining our main result since there are hardly any group differences. However, we do find notable pre-separation group and gender differences with respect to childcare behavior, as well as group differences in gender norms and children’s age. Path dependencies in these factors could reflect some selection into groups according to fertility timing, intra-couple childcare division and related norms and preferences, which can only partly be addressed with our fixed effects approach. While the provided associations are therefore not to be interpreted as causal, we still consider our finding that in maternal sole residency settings, fathers’ childcare engagement during weekdays is not significantly associated with maternal equivalized post-separation income quite important. As argued, the help of fathers could be cancelled out by maternal own preferences for ‘intensive care’ but this is less likely to happen in shared parenting settings where there is more substantial support from fathers. Further, we show that subjective evaluations of economic well-being correspond with actual income for mothers, but less so for fathers.

Our study offers two novel insights into the importance of specification issues when interpreting economic well-being. First, for non-resident fathers, focusing only on annual income would draw a too pessimistic picture of paternal income dynamics. Accounting for the change in household composition by using equivalized income results in a more advantageous income evolution. Second, however, when deducting paid alimony and maintenance from the payer’s income, which is mostly the father, the paternal upward income trend turns into a downward trend for the group of care-inactive fathers, and to a somewhat stagnating pattern for the group of care-active fathers. We term this the ‘symmetric approach’ since those payments are symmetrically accounted for on the side of both the payer and the recipient, drawing—in our view—a more adequate picture of disposable household income.

We conclude that, when they are in the role of residence providers, even high resources do not shield mothers against increased economic risks and persistent economic dependence post-separation. Our findings seem rather unaffected by Germany’s recent family policy reforms geared to higher gender equality, which confirms previous studies (Bröckel & Andreß, 2015). Further, our results qualitatively support the findings from Augustijn (2022) who reports that any form of joint physical custody is better in terms of maternal post-separation economic well-being than sole (maternal) custody.

The limitations of this study are evident. Some exogenous variation in paternal childcare involvement would be necessary to estimate causal effects. Driven by low observation numbers, our broad childcare measure and our failure to map variety in child residence mask the true granularity of actually practiced care arrangements between ex-partners. For the same reason, differentiations by cohorts, age groups, or family constellations were not possible. Tracking population subgroups over their further life course requires data that combines high observation numbers with rich household context and valid income information. Hopefully, data of this kind will be available in the near future.