Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Are global taxes feasible?

  • Policy Watch
  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Over the years, many proposals for global taxes—taxes levied on a worldwide basis—have been made. None has been successful, essentially because one cannot have global taxes without a global government. This paper first reviews some major global taxes that have been proposed and then considers whether experience in two other spheres in which countries deal with each other to resolve fiscal questions—the financing of international organizations and international taxation (how national taxes deal with cross-border flows)—offers any lessons about the feasibility of a global tax. Since countries have little appetite for giving up fiscal sovereignty or for explicitly redistributive fiscal arrangements, most past global tax proposals had little or no prospect of success. But less ambitious attempts to develop a more ‘global’ approach to taxation through a transparent process that involves most who are affected, provides them some demonstrable benefit to all, and remains firmly under national control may perhaps over time move us a bit closer toward achieving the better world that global tax proponents presumably wish to achieve.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Interestingly, Piketty’s contribution to Astarita (2015), like that of most other contributors to this EU workshop, focused entirely on the presumably more feasible task of strengthening national wealth taxes. Although many (e.g., Hubbard 2015) have discussed Piketty’s global wealth tax proposal in detail, the present paper focuses on the broader question of whether any ‘global’ tax is feasible.

  2. For example: why have countries found it easier to reach agreements about international trade flows than about international investment flows? There is a World Trade Organization (WTO), but there is no corresponding World Tax Organization. For a recent look at some considerations bearing on such issues, see, e.g., Dreher and Lang (2016). As Bird and Gendron (2007) note, the trade liberalization required for WTO membership, which generally reduced tariff revenues, influenced domestic tax policy in some countries, leading them to adopt a value-added tax (VAT) in part as a substitute revenue source—though not always with full success (Baunsgaard and Keen 2010). But it is not as easy to draw a direct line between international agreements (e.g., the OECD treaty model) and corporate income tax systems in different countries (see Sect. 4).

  3. For a useful compilation of wealth data for different countries, see Davies (2008); for more recent reviews of trends, see Alvaredo et al. (2017) and Lange et al. (2018). A useful review of the case for increased taxation of wealth and especially transfers of wealth may be found in Institute for Fiscal Studies (2010, 2011).

  4. An alternative approach to global redistributive taxation suggested by Steinberg et al. (1978) was to finance development aid through a ‘shadow tax’ calculated by assessing countries in terms of their capacity (ability to pay) as measured by the estimated yield of a set of ‘standard’ taxes if levied on the relevant tax base at the average rates applied by all countries. Unlike most global redistributive schemes, this approach leaves countries free to collect what taxes they want to collect and involves no international intrusion on national fiscal sovereignty. Like all such proposals, however, it requires a degree of worldwide political commitment that does not exist.

  5. Useful earlier reviews of global taxes from various perspectives include Steinberg et al. (1978) Cline (1979), Mendez (1992, 1997, 2001), Shome (1995), Frankman (1996), Baumert (1998), Paul and Wahlberg (2002), Wahlberg (2005), Herman (2013), and Carter (2015). Many of these reviews are by advocates of such taxes; for a notable exception see McMahon (2001).

  6. See also UNDP (2012) on these (and other) ideas for ‘innovative’ ways to finance development aid.

  7. See Frankman (1996). Several of these proposals are discussed later in this section; see also Bird (2015a).

  8. For a good discussion of proposed fiscal approaches to this issue, see Brzoska (2004).

  9. Extensive discussions of fiscal and other approaches to providing global public goods may be found in Kaul et al. (1999, 2002), Kaul and Conceicao (2006), Sandler (1997, 1998, 2002) and Barrett (2007) though not all the issues discussed in these sources are strictly global public goods, defined by Barrett (2007, p. 1) as outcomes making “people everywhere better off.”

  10. See https://phys.org/news/2012-11-imf-chief-sms-tax-philippines.html.

  11. This argument has some merit: for an early example, see Roller and Waverman (2001) and for a recent thorough review, see Matheson and Petit (2017). However, many who make it appear to assume the internet is ‘free,’ which of course it is not and never has been. As Morozov (2013) notes, the common assumption that “the internet” has a clear and unarguable meaning inevitably leads to confusion.

  12. Pogge (2008); see also Casal (2011), Steiner (2011) and Pogge (2011) for philosophical discussion of this idea.

  13. In the 1980s over 160 countries ratified a UN convention on the Law of the Sea—although some, including the USA, specifically objected to provisions that may be interpreted to support such tax proposals.

  14. As noted in Sect. 4, much the same can be said about the most visible outcome of the recent discussion of the international aspects of corporate income taxes—the acceptance of a uniform country-by-country reporting system.

  15. The effects of these levies are only beginning to be understood: see, for instance, the analysis of the German bank levy by Buch et al. (2014) and the discussion of their incidence in Kogler (2015). To illustrate how complicated some of these taxes are, see the 252-page official manual issued at the time of the introduction of the UK bank levy (available at http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/budget-updates/autumn-tax/bank-levy-manual.pdf).

  16. Unsurprisingly, given its role as a financial center, by far the strongest opposition to this approach came from the UK (Seely 2013).

  17. Increased capital requirements were a central focus of the ‘Basel 3’ framework that emerged from extensive discussion of financial regulation under the auspices of the Bank for International Settlements (see www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3.htm).

  18. IMF (2010) preferred FAT to FTT largely because it would be easier to implement than (in effect) attempting to encompass the financial sector within the VAT and its effects would likely be less distorting than those of a cascading FTT; for a review of the extensive but inconclusive literature on including the financial sector within VAT, see James (2015). Vella (2012) also argued that there was a stronger case for a FAT than for an FTT on both equity and efficiency grounds; the opposite view is presented by Cannas et al (2014).

  19. Bird (2015a) lists various FTTs in 38 countries in 2013. Additional countries—for example, Denmark, Ecuador, Singapore, Sweden—have had some variety of FTT in the past—some on securities, some on bank debits or transactions, some on currency transactions and some on automated payment systems. Many countries also levy special taxes on transfers of real property, which appear to be more politically acceptable (though economically less desirable) than imposing annual taxes on wealth held in this form (Bird and Slack 2004).

  20. Before India decided to recall all large denomination currency notes in 2016, a similar idea was suggested in part to reduce corruption (ArthaKraniti 2013). As Coelho (2009) notes, however, even in Brazil, where his analysis suggests the tax at one time was perhaps the most productive in Latin America, it never yielded much more than 1.5% of GDP. For a similarly restrained view of the likely revenue potential of an FTT, see European Commission (2010).

  21. The UK tax is a small (0.5%) levy paid by purchasers of UK shares; it is assessed and collected primarily through an electronic securities settlement system. It is considered to work well, although registered market makers and large banks are exempted. In contrast, a similar small tax imposed by Sweden in 1986 is usually considered to have been a failure because of its dramatic effect on trading volumes: most bond trading soon vanished and most (60%) of trading in Swedish shares moved abroad. Although this tax was abolished in 1991, a new ‘stability fee’ at a rate of 0.036% was imposed on the liabilities of banks and other credit institutions in 2009. This levy is like the bank levy imposed on bank balance sheets in 2011 by the UK—at a rate of 0.05%, increased in 2013 to 0.13% to ensure that despite reductions in the corporate tax rate, the taxes paid by banks would not be decreased (Seely 2013).

  22. The 11 countries—all in the Eurozone—that have indicated they will sign on are Austria, Belgium, Estonia, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Spain. Several other members of the Eurozone (e.g., Finland and Ireland) have at times indicated they too might sign on, but none of the non-Euro EU countries has publicly shown much interest in doing so.

  23. See www.eu.eruopa.eu/taxation_customs/taxation-financial/sector_en#prop. See Heber and Steinberg (2014) for further discussion.

  24. Unsurprisingly, perhaps, ECLAC (2011) suggested that revenues from both the FTT and the Tobin tax should be devoted to this purpose.

  25. The (recently largely abolished) Brazilian tax—the IOF—is described in Coutinho (2012); for an analysis of the earlier Chilean experience, see Agosin and Ffrench-Davis (1996).

  26. Consider, for example, the unusually well worked-out proposal in Taskforce (2010) for what is essentially a Tobin tax (the Global Solidarity Levy). This proposal assumes the tax would be administered by “an authority with formal oversight powers for licensed international settlement infrastructure and executive oversight of the proposed settlement institution’s tax raising functions in conformity with the legislation in the jurisdiction of residence or operation of the settlement institution” (Taskforce 2010, p. 28). This authority was to be developed by an inter-governmental tax commission, chaired by the IMF and convened by such worthies as the finance ministers and central banks of the G20 and the countries that host the larger international financial centers, the Board of Directors of the Bank of International Settlements, and representatives of the World Customs Organisation Council. The proceeds would then flow to a Global Solidarity Fund for distribution, as determined by ‘…its own decision-making board comprising a range of stakeholders including civil society and business sector [from developed and developing countries] together with the Consultative Forum [which would include NGOs and other stakeholders not on the board]’ (Taskforce 2010, p. 31). The vision may be inspiring, but its realization requires a much greater degree of convergence and agreement across countries than anyone has ever seen.

  27. See http://whqlibdoc.who.int/publications/2003/9241591013.pdf.

  28. The UNITAID tax on air travel discussed later finances work on communicable diseases but has no direct effect in reducing their incidence (although it may have a minor effect by reducing carbon emissions).

  29. For two very different analyses demonstrating the non-optimality of uniform ‘Pigovian’ taxes when marginal social costs, demand elasticities, or both, are heterogeneous, see Fleischer (2015) and Griffith et al. (2017). As Keen (1998), Cnossen (2006) and others have discussed, although some arguments may be made for an ad valorem tax, specific taxation of tobacco generally makes sense.

  30. This number (which has sometimes been raised to 75%) appears to have been derived from an earlier standard of 67% suggested in World Bank (1999) which was itself apparently based largely on the argument that the best ‘target’ (yardstick) available was the tax level observed in countries considered to have the strongest tobacco control policies—that is, the highest taxes. Unsurprisingly, the benchmark suggested turned out to be close to that set in the European Union (EU), where Council Directive 2010/12/EW requires that by no later than the end of 2017 excise duties on cigarettes should be at least 60% of the weighted average retail price in all member states (and the actual average level in 2016 was 61.6%).

  31. The impact of taxes on smuggling is, for example, discussed by Cnossen (2006) for the EU, by Irvine and Sims (2012) for Canada, and in more global terms by ICIJ (2009). For other reasons for varying rates, see the references cited in note 29 above.

  32. In 2013, for example, France (where almost all the revenue is collected) charged 1 euro for a domestic economy seat, 10 euros for a higher-class seat, 6 euros for an international economy seat, and 40 euros for a higher-class international seat. In addition to France, Korea, and seven developing countries, most in Africa, now impose such a levy (and Norway allocates part of its tax on carbon emissions to UNITAID) (www.unitaid.eu/en/how/innovative financing).

  33. Kaufman et al. (2017) suggest that one way to reduce what they label the ‘democratic deficit’ between the aid people seem to want to support and the amount of actual aid might be for governments to ‘match’ charitable expenditure abroad in the same way as they match (usually through the tax system) charitable donations domestically. This is already done to a limited extent in some countries; in Canada, for example, foreign donations are given the same tax treatment as domestic donations when given to a charity to which the government has itself given funds. Another way to test the extent to which taxpayers were really willing to support foreign aid might be to permit them to earmark a small fraction of their income taxes for this purpose (Hirschman and Bird 1968). Even in the unusually generous Nordic countries, however, the linkage between how much (and what kind of) aid the public would support if they had the choice and what is done by their governments seems tenuous (Selbervik and Nygaaard 2006).

  34. The EU included international air flights in its more general Emissions Trading System in January 2012 for flights to and from European airports, in effect introducing a ‘carbon tax’ like that discussed in Sect. 2.6 (though one that produced no revenue). Subsequently, however, the tax was first suspended for flights to and from non-member states and then, in October 2013, revised to apply only to the portion of such flights occurring within EU territory (with flights to and from many developing countries being exempted).

  35. On fuel subsidies, see also OECD (2013b), World Bank (2016), and Coady et al. (2015).

  36. The Kyoto Protocol committed countries to meet international binding targets for reducing GHG emissions, with heavier burdens being placed on developed countries as being primarily responsible for the increased GHG found in the atmosphere: see http://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol/items/2830.php. As usual with such international agreements, the targets set are mandatory only to the extent that countries voluntarily live up to them since there is no enforcement mechanism (Gillenwater 2013).

  37. Some jurisdictions (e.g., California) auction allowances rather than dispensing them for free. Other policies not discussed here, such as energy efficiency standards, fuel taxes and subsidies, and support for renewable energy, may affect the ‘price’ of carbon emissions.

  38. For descriptions of existing market-based mechanisms for reducing carbon emissions in the form of both emission trading regimes and taxes, see OECD (2013b), World Bank (2016), and Coady et al. (2015).

  39. Analysis of the political distortions that arise from both the regulatory and the taxation approaches suggests that both may be distorting (Masciandro and Passarelli 2012). Determining which is best in any political setting requires knowing much more than anyone can know. Life is difficult to model.

  40. The arguments against uniform Pigovian taxes mentioned in note 29 above are much weaker in this case. Indeed, as Fleischer (2015) notes, taxing carbon emissions is the ideal ‘textbook’ case for a uniform tax.

  41. Credible estimates of the ‘correct’ level at which to set a carbon tax are difficult, but a 2010 estimate for the USA was $35 per ton of CO2 (IAWG 2013), considerably higher than most existing carbon taxes. In addition, many countries have substantial taxes on motor fuels, which also reduce emissions (Miller and Vella 2013).

  42. For example, Britain adopted the Clean Air Act of 1956, which ended the choking yellow smog that had for decades blanketed London only after the great smog of 1952 killed at least 4000 people and made at least 100,000 ill. (The figures cited come from an official source (http://www.metoffice.gov.uk/education/teens/case-studies/great-smog; other sources give higher estimates.).

  43. See www.upu.int/finances.hmtl and ITU (2014).

  44. See Mehrotra (2013) for a detailed account of the move from one model to the other in the US tax system.

  45. See Mendez (1997) as well as sources cited in http://www.globalpolicy.org/un-finance.html. See also Barrett (2007) for an interesting view of UN finance.

  46. The other 20% is kept by the collecting country. The EU also collects a progressive personal income tax on its own employees, but this is of course simply a transfer within its budget.

  47. Owing to the convoluted way the so-called “UK correction” is calculated as well as a few adjustments made for several other several countries “to mitigate perceived imbalances” as EU (2014, p. 193) puts it, the EU’s fiscal framework is more complex than this capsule description indicates.

  48. There are some differences between VAT bases in EU countries and even to some extent in how GNP (GNI) is estimated, but both must correspond closely to agreed standards.

  49. For examples, see the essays in Martin et al. (2009), Yun-Casalilla et al. (2012), Cardoso and Lains (2010), and Soifer (2015), as well as such detailed country studies as Daunton (2001) on the UK, Mehrotra (2013) on the USA, and Heaman (2017) on Canada. Building a ‘fiscal state’ has proven an especially delicate and difficult task in ‘fragmented’ countries—those with geographically concentrated ethnic–linguistic differences—as discussed in Bird and Ebel (2007) and Vaillancourt and Bird (2016).

  50. Though what is considered ‘fair’ by many may more often resemble what Sheffrin (2013) calls ‘folk justice’ than the welfare-maximizing optimum of the economist or the egalitarian utopia envisaged by some.

  51. This assertion may perhaps be acceptable in the present context but of course, like many of the complex issues touched on in this paper, it is not easily documented and has long been discussed from different perspectives by philosophers (Wellman 2000; Coons 2001), psychologists (Ashmore et al. 2001), and economists and political scientists (Gradstein and Konrad 2006; United Nations 2006), among others.

  52. For a telling example, see Bartik (2017) on the continued waste of billions in business subsidies in the US today.

  53. The sad story of death taxes in the USA (Graetz and Shapiro 2005) makes the point nicely; a similar, less dramatically told, story happened earlier in Canada (Bird 1978).

  54. For inevitably approximate attempts to estimate the possible revenue losses, see Crivelli et al. (2015) and Cobham and Jansky (2017). The considerable country-to-country variation noted by Cobham and Jansky (2017) likely reflects not only different economic circumstances but also, as Genschel and Seelkopf (2016) note, differences in size and in quality of governance.

  55. http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/country-by-country-reporting.htm. The Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (Sect. 2.3 above) is an example of a recent sectoral attempt along these lines. As Forstater (2017) discusses, it is not clear that the information to be collected is either necessary or sufficient, but it is clear that much more effort is needed to put it to good use.

  56. Over 100 countries have agreed to adopt a common reporting standard, including the automated exchange of tax information, as well as to modify their bilateral tax treaties to implement some of the BEPS reforms (see http://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/multilateral-convention-to-implement-tax-treaty-related-measures-to-prevent-beps.htm). For an optimistic view of the prospects that future international tax information exchange and cooperation—driven in part by USA’s independent but related FATCA (Foreign Account Tax Compliance Act)—will improve outcomes in this respect, see Grinberg (2013). For more restrained appraisals from different perspectives, see Eccleston (2012), Shaviro (2014), Avi-Yonath and Xu (2017), and Forstater (2017), Cockfield (2017).

  57. For an elaboration of this approach at the sub-national level, see Bird and Slack (2014).

  58. This concept comes close to Krasner’s classic definition of an international regime (1982, p. 186) as ‘implicit or explicit principles, norms, rules, and decision-making procedures around which actors’ expectations converge in a given area of international relations.’ For discussions of the global governance literature as it applies to international tax issues, see Rixen (2008), Eccleston (2012), Genschel and Rixen (2015), and Dreher and Lang (2016).

  59. For interesting perspectives on how some outside the process view the outcome of the BEPS discussions, see Durst (2014, 2015) and Myszkowski (2016); Civelli et al. 2015) provide a rare empirical estimate of the impact on developing countries; see also the more recent extended appraisal by Cobham and Jansky (2017). The OECD, long seen as a rich country club, may not be the best forum in which to pursue these issues, but this topic is beyond the present discussion.

  60. For example, the Forum of Tax Administrators (FTA), a panel of national tax administrators established in 2002 by the OECD’s Committee on Fiscal Affairs to promote dialogue between administrations; the Leeds Castle Group, a group of tax administrators from a number of major countries, including some non-OECD countries like China and India, who meet regularly to discuss mutual compliance problems; and the Joint International Tax Shelter Center established by the USA, UK, Canada, and Australia to develop and share information on abusive tax avoidance.

  61. Harmonized does not mean uniform: as with the tobacco tax proposals discussed earlier, given the different circumstances facing different countries as well as their different regulatory regimes, if the aim is to bring about similar results in dissimilar contexts often different measures (e.g., different tax rates) are required.

References

  • Agosin, M., & Ffrench-Davis, R. (1996). Measuring capital inflows in Latin America. In M. ul Haq, I. Kaul, & I. Grunberg (Eds.), The Tobin tax: Coping with financial viability (pp. 161–191). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alvaredo, F., et al. (2017). World inequality report 2018. Paris: World Inequality Lab.

    Google Scholar 

  • ArthaKraniti. (2013). Exploring ArthaKranti: A path to fiscal consolidation. ArthaKraniti Research Project Team, ArthaKraniti Pratishthan, Maharashtra Knowledge Corporation, Mumbai, March.

  • Ashmore, R., Jussim, L., & Wilder, D. (2001). Social identity, intergroup conflict and conflict reduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Astarita, C. (Ed.) (2015). Taxing wealth: Past, present, future. Discussion Paper 003, European Commission, July.

  • Avi-Yonath, R., & Xu, H. (2017). Evaluating BEPS. Erasmus Law Review. https://doi.org/10.5553/ELR000080.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartik, T. (2017). A new panel database on business incentives for economic development offered by state and local governments in the United States. Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumert, K. (1998). Global taxes and fees: Recent developments and overcoming obstacles. Global Policy Forum. http://www.globalpolicy.org/component/content/article/216/45849.html. Accessed 8 Mar 2018.

  • Baunsgaard, T., & Keen, M. (2010). Tax revenue and (or?) trade liberalization. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 563–577.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. (1978). Canada’s vanishing death taxes. Osgoode Hall Law Journal, 16(1), 133–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. (1986). The interjurisdictional allocation of income. Australian Tax Forum, 3(3), 333–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. (2015a). Global taxes and international taxation: Mirage and reality. ICTD Working Paper 28, International Centre for Tax and Development, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, UK, January.

  • Bird, R. (2015b). Tobacco and alcohol excise taxes for improving public health and revenue outcomes: Marrying sin and virtue? Policy Research Working Paper 7500, World Bank, November.

  • Bird, R. (2016). Reforming international taxation: Is the process the real product? Hacienda Pública Española/Review of Public Economics, 2(2016), 159–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Ebel, R. (Eds.). (2007). Fiscal fragmentation in decentralized countries: Subsidiarity, solidarity, and asymmetry. Cheltenham/Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Gendron, P. (2007). The VAT in developing and transitional countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Mintz, J. (2003). Sharing the international tax base in a changing world. In S. Cnossen & H.-W. Sinn (Eds.), Public finance and public policy in the new century (pp. 405–446). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Slack, E. (2004). International handbook of land and property taxation. Cheltenham/Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Slack, E. (2014). Local taxes and local expenditures in developing countries: Strengthening the Wicksellian connection. Public Administration and Development, 34(4), 359–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Wilkie, S. (2013). Designing tax policy: Constraints and objectives in an open economy. eJournal of Tax Research, 11(3), 284–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R., & Zolt, E. (2015). Fiscal contracting in Latin America. World Development, 67, 323–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brondolo, J. (2011). Taxing financial transactions: An assessment of administrative feasibility. IMF Working Paper 11/185, August.

  • Brooks, K. (2009). Inter-nation equity: The development of an important but underappreciated international tax policy objective. In J. Head & R. Krever (Eds.), Tax reform in the 21st century. Austin, TX: Wolters Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brzoska, M. (2004). Taxation of the global arms trade? An overview of the issues. Kyklos, 37(2), 149–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buch, C., Hilberg, B., & Tonzer, L. (2014). Taxing banks: An evaluation of the German Bank Levy. CESifo Working Paper No. 4704, February.

  • Cannas, G., et al. (2014). Financial activities taxes, bank levies and systemic risk. European Commission Working Paper N.43-2014.

  • Cardoso, J., & Lains, P. (2010). Paying for the liberal state: The rise of public finance in nineteenth century Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, B. (2015). Micro levies for global public goods. GSRDC Helpdesk Research Report, December. www.gsdrc.org.

  • Casal, P. (2011). Global taxes on natural resources. Journal of Moral Philosophy, 8, 307–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christian Aid. (2013). Christian Aid’s tax justice strategy 20132016. http://www.christianaid.org.uk/Images/christian-aid-tax-justice-strategy-2013-2016.pdf. Accessed 9 Mar 2018.

  • Cintra, M. (2009). Bank transactions: Pathway to the single tax ideal. São Paulo: Cyan Artes Gráficas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cline, W. (1979). Resource transfers to the developing countries: Issues and trends. In W. R. Cline (Ed.), Policy alternatives for a new international economic order (pp. 333–353). New York: Praeger Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cnossen, S. (2006). Tobacco taxation in the European Union. Finanz/Archiv: Public Finance Analysis, 62(2), 305–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coady, D., et al. (2015). How large are global energy subsidies? IMF Working Paper WP/15/105, May.

  • Cobham, A., & Jensky, P. (2017). Global distribution of revenue loss for tax avoidance. WIDER Working Paper 2017/55, March.

  • Cockfield, A. (2017). What’s international tax law got to do with it? Presentation at James Hausman tax law and policy workshop, University of Toronto, October.

  • Coelho, I. (2009). Taxing bank transactionsThe experience in Latin America and elsewhere, September. https://www.google.ca/#q=Coelho%2C+I.+(2009)+Taxing+Bank+Transactions+.

  • Commission of the European Communities. (2005). An analysis of a possible contribution based on airline tickets as a new source of financing development. Commission Staff Working Paper SEC (2005) 733, Brussels, June.

  • Coons, C. (2001). Wellman’s ‘reductive’ justification for redistributive policies that favor compatriots. Ethics, 111(4), 782–788.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cordell, A., & Ide, T. (1997). The new wealth of nations: Taxing cyberspace. Toronto: Between the Lines.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coutinho, M. (2012). Brazil: Understand the tax on financial operations. International Tax Review, September 6. http://www.internationaltaxreview.com/Article/3085512/Brazil-Understanding-the-Tax-on-Financial-Operations-IOF.html.

  • Credit Suisse. (2013). Regulatory update, July 2013Financial transaction taxes. https://www.credit-suisse.com/media/pb/docs/ch/unternehmen/institutionalclients/fs-transaktionsteuern-en.pdf. Accessed 16 Dec 2014.

  • Crivelli, E., De Mooij, R., & Keen, M. (2015). Base erosion, profit shifting and developing countries. IMF Working Paper WP/15/118, May.

  • Daunton, M. (2001). Trusting leviathan: The politics of taxation in Britain 1799–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davies, J. (Ed.). (2008). Personal wealth from a global perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, L. (2014). Pricing energy efficiently. NBER Reporter, No. 1, pp. 8–10.

  • Dreher, A., & Lang, V. (2016). The political economy of international organizations. CESifo Working Paper No. 6077, September.

  • Durst, M. (2014). Beyond BEPS: A tax policy agenda for developing countries. ICTD Working Paper 18, June.

  • Durst, M. (2015). Limitations of the BEPS reforms: Looking beyond corporate taxation for revenue gains. ICTD Working Paper, September.

  • Eccleston, R. (2012). The dynamics of global economic governance: The financial crisis, the OECD and the politics of international tax cooperation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • ECLAC. (2011). Global tax on financial transactions is a priority for stability and development. Press Release, United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, August 24.

  • Eichengreen, B. (1996). The Tobin tax: What have we learned? In M. ul Haq, I. Kaul, & I. Grunberg (Eds.), The Tobin tax: Coping with financial viability (pp. 275–287). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2010). Financial sector taxation. Taxation Papers, Brussels.

  • European Union (EU). (2014). European Union public finance (5th ed.). Brussels: European Union.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evers, M., Meier, I., & Spengel, C. (2017). Country-by-country reporting: Tension between transparency and tax planning. ZEW Discussion Paper No. 17-008.

  • EY. (2014). FTTCollection methods and data requirements. Final Report Specific Contract No 3 TAXUD/2013/DE/314, European Commission, October.

  • Fleischer, V. (2015). Curb your enthusiasm for Pigovian taxes. Vanderbilt Law Review, 68, 1673–1713.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forstater, M. (2017). Beneficial openness? Weighing the costs and benefits of financial transparency. CMI Working Paper 3, March.

  • Fox, W. (2012). Retail sales and use taxation. In R. Ebel & J. Petersen (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of state and local government finance (pp. 406–428). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankman, M. J. (1996). International taxation: The trajectory of an idea from Lorimer to Brandt. World Development, 24(5), 807–820.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuest, C., & Piechl, A. (2012). European fiscal union: What is it? Does it work? And are there really no alternatives? CESifo Forum, 13(2), 3–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., & Rixen, T. (2015). Settling and unsettling the transnational legal order of international taxation. In T. Halliday & G. Shaffer (Eds.), Transnational legal orders (pp. 154–183). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., & Seelkopf, L. (2016). Globalization and tax policy. In Encyclopedia of public administration and public policy (2nd ed.). https://doi.org/10.1081/E-EPAP2-120053258.

  • Gillenwater, M. (2013). The treaty compliance challenge: Enforcement under the Kyoto protocol, February 10. http://ghginstitute.org/2010/02/10/the-treaty-compliance-challenge-enforcement-under-the-kyoto-protocol/.

  • Gradstein, M., & Konrad, K. (Eds.). (2006). Institutions and norms in economic development. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graetz, M., & Shapiro, I. (2005). Death by a thousand cuts: The fight over taxing inherited wealth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griffith, R., O’Connell, M., & Smith, K. (2017). Design of optimal corrective taxes in the alcohol market. Institute for Fiscal Studies, IFS Working Paper W17/02, January.

  • Grinberg, I. (2013). Taxing capital income in emerging countries: Will FACTA open the door? World Tax Journal, no. 3(2013), 325–367.

  • Haq, M., Kaul, I., & Grunberg, I. (Eds.). (1996). The Tobin tax: Coping with financial volatility. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, K. (2013). The political economy of British Columbia’s carbon tax. OECD Environment Working Papers No. 63.

  • Heaman, E. (2017). Tax, order and good government: A new political history of Canada, 1867–1917. Montreal: McGill-Queens University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heber, C., & Steinberg, C. (2014). Market infrastructure regulation and the financial transaction tax. Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance Working paper 2014-07, May.

  • Herman, B. (2013). Half a century of proposals for ‘innovative’ development financing, background paper. United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, DESA Working Paper No. 125, July. https://www.un.org/en/development/desa/policy/wess/wess_bg_papers/bp_wess2012_herman.pdf.

  • Hirschman, A., & Bird, R. (1968). Foreign aid—A critique and a proposal. Essays in international finance No. 69. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, G. (2015). Taxing capital’s gains: Capital’s ideas and tax policy in the twenty-first century. National Tax Journal, 68(2), 409–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Independent Evaluation Group. (2008). Annual review of development effectiveness: Shared global challenges. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Institute for Fiscal Studies. (2010). Dimensions of tax design: The Mirrlees review. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Institute for Fiscal Studies. (2011). Tax by design: The Mirrlees review. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Interagency Working Group (IAWG). (2013). Technical support document: Technical update of the social cost of carbon for regulatory impact analysis under executive order 12866. Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon, United States Government, May.

  • International Consortium of Investigative Journalists (ICIJ). (2009). Tobacco underground: The global trade in smuggled cigarettes. Washington: Center for Public Integrity.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). (2010). A fair and substantial contribution by the financial sector. Final Report for the G-20, Washington, June.

  • International Telecommunications Union. (ITU). (2014). How is ITU Funded? ITU Backgrounders, Plenipotentiary 2014, Busan, Korea.

  • Ip, G. (2013) The gated globe. Special report. The Economist, October 12.

  • Irvine, I., & Sims, W. (2012). A taxing dilemma: Assessing the impact of tax and price changes on the tobacco market, Commentary No. 350, C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto.

  • James, K. (2015). The rise of the value-added tax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jha, P., & Pelo, R. (2014). Global effects of smoking, of quitting, and of taxing tobacco. New England Journal of Medicine, 370, 60–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman, D., McGuirk, E., & Vicente, P. (2017). Foreign aid preferences and perception in donor countries. http://www.pedrovicente.org/aid.pdf. Accessed 8 Mar 2018.

  • Kaul, I., & Conceicao, P. (2006). The new public finance: Responding to global challenges. New York: Oxford University Press for the United Nations Development Programme.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaul, I., Conceicao, P., Le Goulven, K., & Mendoza, R. (Eds.). (2002). Providing global public goods: Managing globalization. New York: Oxford University Press for the United Nations Development Programme.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaul, I., Grunberg, I., & Stern, M. (Eds.). (1999). Global public goods: International cooperation in the 21st century. New York: Oxford University Press for the United Nations Development Programme.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. (1998). The balance between specific and ad valorem taxation. Fiscal Studies, 19(1), 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., Parry, I., & Strand, J. (2013). Planes, ships and taxes. Economic Policy, 28(76), 703–749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, N. (2009). Cap and trade, rehabilitated: Tradable permits to control U.S. greenhouse gas. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3(1), 42–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogler, M. (2015). On the incidence of bank levies; Theory and evidence, September. http://www.sbs.ox.ac.uk/sites/default/files/Business_Taxation/Events/conferences/2015/Doctoral_mtg_2015/kogler-paper.pdf.

  • Krasner, S. (1982). Structural causes and regime considerations: Regimes as intervening variables. International Organization, 36(2), 185–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang, M., & Owens, J. (2013). The role of tax treaties in facilitating development and protecting the tax base. WU International Taxation Research Paper Series, No. 2014-13.

  • Lange, Glenn-Marie, Wodon, Quentin, & Carey, Kevin (Eds.). (2018). The changing wealth of nations 2018: Building a sustainable future. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lustig, N. (2017). Fiscal policy, income redistribution and poverty reduction in low and middle income countries. CEQ Institute, Tulane University, Working Paper 54, January.

  • Mahoney, J., & Thelen, K. (2009). A theory of gradual institutional change. In J. Mahoney & K. Thelen (Eds.), Explaining institutional change: Ambiguity, agency, and power (pp. 1–37). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, I., Mehrotra, A., & Prasad, M. (Eds.). (2009). The new fiscal sociology: Taxation in comparative and historical perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, R., Muuls, M., & Wagner, U. (2012). An evidence review of the EU emissions trading system, focussing on effectiveness of the system in driving industrial abatement. London: Department of Energy & Climate Change.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masciandro, D., & Passarelli, F. (2012). Regulation and taxation: Economics and politics. In J. Alworth & G. Arachi (Eds.), Taxation and the financial crisis (pp. 257–269). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matheson, T., & Petit, P. (2017). Taxing telecommunications in developing countries. IMF Working Paper WP/17/247.

  • McCullagh, D., & Downes, L. (2012). U.N. could tax U.S.-based Web sites, leaked docs show. CNET News, June. http://news.cnet.com/8301-1009_3-57449375-83/u.n-could-tax-u.s.-based-web-sites-leaked-docs-show/.

  • McCulloch, N., & Pacillo, G. (2011). The Tobin tax: A review of the evidence, vol. 2011, no. 68. Institute of Development Studies, Research Report.

  • McKinnon, R. (2012). The conservative case for a wealth tax. Wall Street Journal, January 16. https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052970203462304577139232881346686. Accessed 9 Mar 2018.

  • McLure, C. (2014). Reforming subsidies for fossil fuel competition: Killing several birds with one stone. In R. Bird & J. Martinez-Vazquez (Eds.), Taxation and development: The weakest link? (pp. 238–283). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMahon, F. (2001). A global tax: Unworkable, unnecessary and dangerous. Fraser Institute, Vancouver, June. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?rep=rep1&type=pdf&doi=10.1.1.196.5981.

  • Mehrotra, A. (2013). Making the modern American fiscal state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendez, R. (1992). International public finance: A new perspective on global relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendez, R. (1997). Financing the United Nations and the international public sector. Global Governance, 3, 283–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendez, R. (2001). The case for global taxes: An overview. Paper presented to United Nations ad hoc Expert Group Meeting on Innovations in Mobilizing Global Resources for Development, New York, June. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.197.6984&rep=rep1&type=pdf.

  • Milanovic, B. (2016). Global inequality. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, S., & Vela, M. (2013). Are environmentally related taxes effective? IDB Working Paper No. IDB-WP-467, Inter-American Development Bank, November.

  • Morozov, E. (2013). To save everything, click here. New York: Public Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myszkowski, A. (2016). Mind the gap: The role of politics and the impact of cultural differences on the OECD BEPS project. Bulletin for International Taxation, 70, 279–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neubig, T., & Slemrod, J. (2017). A tax systems perspective on recent global tax initiatives. Tax Notes, 154(13), 1665–1676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (2011). The architecture of climate economics: Designing a global agreement on global warming. Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, 67(1), 9–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (2016). Projections and uncertainties about climate change in an era of minimal climate policies. NBER Working Paper 22933, December 2016. Revised September 2017.

  • OECD. (2013a). Addressing base erosion and profits shifting. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2013b). Climate and carbon: Aligning prices and policies. OECD Environment Policy Paper, October.

  • OECD. (2013c). Revenue statistics 1965–2012. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2014). Addressing the tax challenges of the digital economy. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxfam. (2011). Out of the Bunker: Time for a fair deal on shipping emissions. Oxfam and World Wildlife Fund Briefing Note, September. http://www.oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/bn-out-of-the-bunker-050911-en.pdf.

  • Oxfam. (2016). The case for a billionaire tax. Oxfam Discussion Papers, December.

  • Paul, J., & Wahlberg, K. (2002). Global taxes for global priorities. Global Policy forum, March. http://www.globalpolicy.org/component/content/article/216/46027.html.

  • Picciotto, S. (Ed.). (2017). Taxing multinational enterprises as unitary firms. Brighton: Institute for Development Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pogge, T. (2008). World poverty and human rights. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pogge, T. (2011). Allowing the poor to share the earth. Journal of Moral Philosophy, 8, 335–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. (2003). Taxing international currency flows: A financial safeguard or financial bonanza? School of Economics, University of Adelaide, April. http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.201.6668&rep=rep1&type=pdf.

  • Rixen, T. (2008). Politicization and institutional (non-)change in international taxation. WZB Discussion Paper SP IV 2008-306.

  • Rixen, T. (2010). International taxation and multi-level governance. In H. Enderlein, S. Walti, & M. Zurn (Eds.), Handbook on multi-level governance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (2010). IMF proposals get the big picture right. The Guardian, May 1. https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/01/imf-tax-proposals-banks. Accessed 9 Mar 2018.

  • Roller, L., & Waverman, L. (2001). Telecommunications infrastructure and economic development: A simultaneous approach. American Economic Review, 91(4), 909–923.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rustad, S., Le Billon, P., & Lujala, P. (2017). Has the extractive industries transparency initiative been a success? Identifying and evaluating EITI goals. Resources Policy, 51(2017), 151–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1997). Global challenges: An approach to environmental, political and economic problems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1998). Global and regional public goods: A prognosis for collective action. Fiscal Studies, 19(3), 221–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2001). Economic concepts for the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2002). Financing international public goods. In M. Ferroni & A. Mody (Eds.), International public goods: Incentives, measurement and financing (pp. 81–118). Dordrecht, NL: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seely, A. (2013). Taxation of banking, standard note SN5251. House of Commons Library, July.

  • Seers, D. (1964). International aid: The next steps. Journal of Modern African Studies, 2(4), 471–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selbervik, H., & Nygaaard, K. (2006). Nordic exceptionalism in development assistance: Aid policies and the major donors: The Nordic Countries. CMI Report R2006:8, Chr. Michelsen Institute, Bergen, Norway.

  • Sen, A. (1999). Global justice; Beyond international equity. In I. Kaul, I. Grunberg, & M. Stern (Eds.), Global public goods: International cooperation in the 21st century (pp. 116–125). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaviro, D. (2014). Fixing U.S. international taxation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheffrin, S. (2013). Tax fairness and folk justice. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shome, P. (1995). Global taxes. Working Paper No. 5, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi, November.

  • Siebert, A. (2013). The European Commission’s proposed financial transactions tax. EconoMonitor, April 27, 2013.

  • Soifer, H. (2015). State building in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinberg, E., Yager, J., & Brannon, G. (1978). New means of financing international needs. Washington: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steiner, H. (2011). The global fund: A reply to Casal. Journal of Moral Philosophy, 8, 328–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stubbs, D. (2012). Adopting a currency transaction tax when avoidance is a possibility: Which currencies would take the lead and what rate could they charge? Background Paper for World Economic and Social Survey 2012.

  • Taskforce. (2010). Globalizing solidarity: The case for financial levies. Report of the Committee of Experts to the Taskforce on International Financial Transactions and Development, Paris. http://www.leadinggroup.org/IMG/pdf_Financement_innovants_web_def.pdf.

  • Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2009) Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness (rev. ed.). New York: Penguin Books.

  • Tobin, J. (1974). The new economics one decade older. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. (1978). A proposal for international monetary reform. Eastern Economic Journal, 4(3–4), 153–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (1970). Towards accelerated development: Proposals for the second United Nations development decade. Committee for Development Planning. New York: United Nations.

  • UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). (2012). Innovative financing for development: A new model for development finance?. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2003). Monterrey consensus of the international conference on financing for development. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2006). Social justice in an open world. New York: Department of Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2012). World economic and social survey 2012. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaillancourt, F., & Bird, R. (2016). Decentralization in European and MENA countries: Glue or solvent? In M. Erdoğlu & B. Christiansen (Eds.), Comparative political and economic perspectives on the MENA region (pp. 1–27). Hershey, PA: IGI Global.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vella, J. (2012). The financial transaction tax: Some questionable claims. Interconomica, 2012/2, 90–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wahlberg, K. (2005). Progress on global taxes? Global Policy Forum, December. http://www.globalpolicy.org/component/content/article/216/46020.html.

  • Wellman, C. (2000). Relational facts in liberal political theory: Is there magic in the pronoun ‘My’? Ethics, 110(3), 537–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (1999). Curbing the epidemic: Governments and the economics of tobacco control. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank Group. (2016). State and trends of carbon pricing 2015. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization (WHO). (2009). Public health, innovation and intellectual property: Report of the expert working group on research and development financing, EB 126/6 Add.1.

  • World Health Organization. (2011). WHO technical manual on tobacco tax administration. Geneva: World Health Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization. (2012). Draft guidelines for the implementation of article 6 of the WHO framework convention on tobacco control: Report of the working group, FCTTC/COP/5/8.

  • World Health Organization. (2016). Earmarked tobacco taxes. Geneva: World Health Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yun-Casalilla, B., O’Brien, P., & Comin Comin, F. (2012). The rise of fiscal states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to the International Tax and Investment Center for making it possible for me to work on this topic, and to James Alm, Dan Witt, and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments on earlier versions of the present paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard M. Bird.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bird, R.M. Are global taxes feasible?. Int Tax Public Finance 25, 1372–1400 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9487-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9487-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation