Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal income taxation and migration

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We tackle the issue of optimal dynamic taxation of capital income in an economy with disconnection as in Weil (J Public Econ 38:183–198, 1989), generated by migration and intra-family altruism. We show that, when the government aims at correcting such a disconnection using time-varying weights in the social welfare function, then there is room for nonzero capital income taxation, both in the short and in the long run.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Atkeson et al. (1999) and Chari et al. (1999).

  2. The difference between the government and individuals’ discount rates can be explained in terms of myopia of the latter, or of political instability, where a government takes into account that it might lose office and therefore values the future less than individuals do (see Grossman and Van Huyck 1988).

  3. By the same reasoning, the asymmetry disappears in the special case of logarithmic utility function, since the anticipated policy path does not affect current individual choices and, thus, the cumulative distortionary effect of taxes is ruled out (see also Lansing 1999 and Reinhorn 2013). For a recent discussion on nonzero taxation of capital income, see also Straub and Werning (2014).

  4. Another extension of the basic framework aimed at obtaining a positive taxation of capital consists in the introduction of uncertainty. However, even if Zhu (1992) points out that in such a case the capital income tax may be nonzero in the long run, Chari et al. (1994) show via simulations that the average value of the optimal capital income tax is very close to zero. Other authors have explored the role of market incompleteness in stochastic environments: Chari and Kehoe (1999), for example, consider an economy with state contingent returns on debt acting as shock absorbers. They show that if the government cannot issue bonds with state contingent returns, capital income taxes can be chosen to overcome this problem. More recently, on the role of idiosyncratic uncertainty and private information in invalidating the Chamley–Judd result, see Golosov et al. (2003), Kocherlakota (2005) and Albanesi and Sleet (2006).

  5. See Atkinson and Sandmo (1980) and Erosa and Gervais (2002).

  6. The relevance of the “disconnectedness” of the economy has been firstly analysed by Weil (1989) in the context of the validity of the Ricardian equivalence proposition.

  7. For a presentation of this model in continuous time, see Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1999), chapter 9.

  8. See, for instance, Razin et al. (2002) and Occhino (2008) on fiscal incentives and the relationship between migration and welfare policies; Solé-Auró and Crimmins (2008) on the differences in consumption patterns of natives and immigrants; Czaika and Parsons (2017) for a recent contribution on the effects of international policy agreements on the characteristics of immigrants; and Bell and Eiser (2016) for the effects of the interplay of migration and fiscal policies on the performance of labour markets.

  9. For example, Ramsey (1928) considered constant discounting unacceptable from an ethical standpoint; see, among others, Bernheim (1989), Michel (1990) and Caplin and Lehay (2004).

  10. A notable exception is the work by Farhi and Werning (2005), who obtain a time-varying social discount rate by assuming that the government values future generations directly and not simply through the altruism of the current generation and in the absence of an OLG framework. See also Spataro and De Bonis (2008) for an analysis of the issue in the context of a perpetual youth economy.

  11. For a general analysis of the taxation of savings and, in particular, inheritance taxes in a similar framework, see De Bonis and Spataro (2010).

  12. To see this, consider period 0: the dynasty of the natives consists of 1 native (the founder, born in period − 1) and n children, so that \({{P}}_{-1,0} = (1 +n)\) and the dynasties of the first immigrants are formed by \({{P}}_{0,0} = \alpha (1+n)\) individuals, with \({{N}}_{0} = (1 + \alpha ) (1+n)\). In period 1, the dynasty of natives is formed by the founder, n children and \(n (1+ n)\) nephews, such that \({{P}}_{-1,1} = (1+n)^{2}\). In the same period 1, the dynasties of the first immigrants are formed by \(\alpha (1+ n)\) founders and \(\alpha (1+ n) n\) children, so that \({{P}}_{0,1} = \alpha (1 + n)^{2}\), while new immigrants have entered the economy, equal to a fraction \(\alpha \) of the previous period population and their current children, i.e. \({{P}}_{1,1} = \alpha (1 + \alpha ) (1 +n)^{2}\), so that \({{N}}_{1}= (1 + \alpha )^{2} (1+ n)^{2}\). Generalizing, we end up with the above expressions for \({{P}}_{\mathrm{s,t}.}\) and \({{N}}_{\mathrm{t}}\).

  13. See Stiglitz (2015) for a review.

  14. See Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980); the alternative “dual” approach takes prices and tax rates as control variables (see, for instance, Chamley 1986).

  15. As for the first dynasty, the implementability constraint takes the form: \(\sum \limits _{t=s}^\infty {({\frac{1+n}{1+\beta }})}^{t-s} ({U_{c_{s,t}} c_{s,t} + U_{l_{s,t}} l_{s,t}}) = U_{c_{0,0}} (1+\tilde{r}_{0,0}) {\bar{k}}_{-1}.\)

  16. In our model, thus, the reference point in the government maximization problem is the utility of the dynasties. The dynastic dimension of income has been recently put forward in the context of the distributional effects of taxation (Piketty 2014; Atkinson 2015; Kanbur and Stiglitz 2015; Halvorsen and Thoresen 2017). Even if our framework is very simple, since dynasties only differ as for their date of entry into the economy and we adopt an utilitarian welfare function, we contribute to this literature by adding efficiency aspects to the analysis of the taxation of dynastic income.

  17. We omit the government budget constraint since, by Walras’ law, it is satisfied if the implementability and feasibility constraints hold.

  18. From now onward, we omit the s and t indicators, whenever this does not cause ambiguity: hence, notation \({{X}}^{+1}\) stands for \({{X}}_{{s}, {t}+1}\).

  19. This case occurs, for instance, when the utility function is of the form: \(U=\frac{c^{1-\frac{1}{\sigma }}}{1-\frac{1}{\sigma }} +V(l)\), where \(H_c =-\frac{1}{\sigma }\).

  20. Generally speaking, differences in weight can be connected to different characteristics of natives and immigrants, and of different generations of immigrants; this would be of relevance for the choice of taxation instruments other than capital income taxation.

References

  • Albanesi, S., & Sleet, C. (2006). Dynamic optimal taxation with private information. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkeson, A., Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Taxing capital income: A bad idea. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 23, 3–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B., & Sandmo, A. (1980). Welfare implications of the taxation of savings. The Economic Journal, 90, 529–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). Lectures on public economics. London: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1999). Economic growth. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, N. F., & Eiser, D. (2016). Migration and fiscal policy as factors explaining the labour-market resilience of UK regions to the great recession. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 9(1), 197–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D. (1989). Intergenerational altruism, dynastic equilibria and social welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 56, 119–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplin, A., & Lehay, J. (2004). The social discount rate. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1257–1268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54, 607–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V. V., Christiano, L. J., & Kehoe, P. J. (1994). Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 617–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In J. B. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1, pp. 1670–1745). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Czaika, M., & Parsons, C. R. (2017). The gravity of high-skilled migration policies. Demography, 54(2), 603–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2005). Taxing capital income as pigouvian correction: The role of discounting the future. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 9, 469–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2010). Social discounting, migration and optimal taxation of savings. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 603–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., & Michel, P. (2002). A theory of economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Erosa, A., & Gervais, M. (2002). Optimal taxation in life-cycle economies. Journal of Economic Theory, 105, 338–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farhi, E., & Werning, I. (2005). Inequality, social discounting and estate taxation. NBER Working Paper 1148.

  • Garriga, C. (2003). Optimal fiscal policy in overlapping generations models. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 569–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H. I., & Van Huyck, J. B. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: Excusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review, 78(5), 1088.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halvorsen, E., & Thoresen, T. O. (2017). Distributional effects of the wealth tax under a lifetime-dynastic income concept. CESifo Working Paper 6614.

  • Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd, K. L. (1999). Optimal taxation and spending in general competitive growth models. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur, R., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Dynastic inequality, mobility and equality of opportunity. Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 10542.

  • Kocherlakota, N. (2005). Zero expected wealth taxes: A mirrlees approach to dynamic optimal taxation. Econometrica, 73, 1587–1621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lansing, K. (1999). Optimal redistributive capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics, 73(3), 423–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michel, P. (1990). Criticism of the social time-preference hypothesis in optimal growth. Catholique de Louvain—Center for Operations Research and Economics Paper 9039.

  • Occhino, F. (2008). Optimal fiscal policy when migration is feasible. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8, 1682–1935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 37, 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). Tax burden and migration: A political economy theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 167–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhorn, L. J. (2013). On optimal redistributive capital taxation. New York: mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reis, C. (2012). Social discounting and incentive compatible fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Theory, 147, 2469–2482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Auró, A., & Crimmins, E. M. (2008). Health of immigrants in European countries. International Migration Review, 42(4), 861–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spataro, L., & De Bonis, V. (2008). Accounting for the “disconnectedness” of the economy in OLG models: A case for taxing capital income. Economic Modelling, 25, 411–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). In praise of Frank Ramsey’s contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 125(583), 235–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Straub, L., & Werning, I. (2014). Positive long run capital taxation: Chamley–Judd revisited. (No. w20441). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Weil, P. (1989). Overlapping families of infinitely lived agents. Journal of Public Economics, 38, 183–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, X. (1992). Optimal fiscal policy in a stochastic growth model. Journal of Economic Theory, 58, 250–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Spataro.

Ethics declarations

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of the implementability constraint

In order to obtain the implementability constraint, write Eq. (2) in its intertemporal form:

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {\frac{({c_{s,t} -\tilde{w}_{s,t} l_{s,t}})}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}} =0}. \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Since:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{U_{c_{s,t}}}{U_{c_{s,t+1}}} \frac{({1+\beta })}{({1+n})} = \frac{p_{s,t}}{p_{s,t+1}} =\frac{({1+\tilde{r}_{t+1}})}{({1+n})}, \end{aligned}$$

we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{({1+n})^{t-s}}\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})} =\frac{p_{s,s}}{p_{s,s+1}} \frac{p_{s,s+1}}{p_{s,s+2}} ...\frac{p_{s,t-1}}{p_{s,t}}. \end{aligned}$$

By substituting into Eq. (21), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {\frac{({c_{s,t} -\tilde{w}_{s,t} l_{s,t}}) p_{s,t}}{p_{s,s}} =0} \end{aligned}$$

and exploiting the FOCs from the individual maximization problem, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {\left( {\frac{1+n}{1+\beta }} \right) ^{t-s} ({U_{c_{s,t}} c_{s,t} +U_{l_{s,t}} l_{s,t}})=0}. \end{aligned}$$

which is Eq. (13) in the text.

1.2 Derivation of the feasibility constraint

To derive the feasibility constraint, first aggregate Eq. (2) over population at time t (notice that \(a_{s,s-1} = 0\)):

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{s=0}^t {P_{s,t} a_{s,t} =\sum _{s=0}^t {P_{s,t} \left[ {\frac{({1+r_t})}{({1+n})}a_{s,t-1} +w_t l_{s,t} -c_{s,t} -\frac{\tau _{s,t}^k r_t a_{s,t-1}}{1+n}-\tau _{s,t}^l w_t l_{s,t}} \right] }}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

and by recalling that \(A_t \equiv \sum \limits _{s=0}^t {P_{s,t} a_{s,t}}\), \(P_{s,t} =P_{s,t-1} ({1+n})\) and \(P_{t,t-1} =0\), so that \(\sum \limits _{s=0}^t {P_{s,t-1} a_{s,t-1}} =A_{t-1}\) we can rewrite Eq. (22) as follows

$$\begin{aligned} A_t = ({1+r_t})A_{t-1} +w_t L_t -C_t -T_t \end{aligned}$$

where \(C_{t}\) is aggregate consumption. Finally, by subtracting Eq. (10) and exploiting the market clearing condition we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} K_t = ({1+r_t})K_{t-1} +w_t L_t -C_t -G_t \end{aligned}$$

which, in per capita terms, becomes

$$\begin{aligned} k_t =\frac{({1+r_t})}{({1+\gamma })}k_{t-1} +w_t l_t -c_t -g_t \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{r_t k_{t-1}}{({1+\gamma })} +w_t l_t \equiv y_t\) due to CRS.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 1

Proof

Since a competitive equilibrium (or implementable allocation) satisfies both the feasibility and the implementability constraints by construction, in this “Appendix” we demonstrate the reverse of Proposition 1: any feasible allocation satisfying implementability is a competitive equilibrium.

Suppose that an allocation satisfies the implementability and the feasibility constraints. Then, define a sequence of after tax prices as follows: \(\tilde{w}_{s,t} =-\frac{U_{l_{s,t}}}{U_{c_{s,t}}}\), \(\tilde{r}_{s,t} =\frac{p_{s,t}}{p_{s,t+1}} ({1+n})-1\), with \(p_{s,t} =U_{c_{s,t}} ({\frac{1+n}{1+\beta }})^{t-s}\), \(\forall s\) and \(\forall t\), and a sequence of before tax prices: \(f_{k_{t-1}} =\frac{r_t}{1+\gamma }\), \(f_{l_t} =w_t\). Therefore, by construction such allocation satisfies both the consumers’ and firms’ optimality conditions.

The second step is to show that the allocation satisfies the consumer budget constraint. Take the implementability constraint and substitute \(U_{c_{s,t}}\) and \(U_{l_{s,t}}\) by using the expressions above:

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {({p_{s,t} c_{s,t} -\tilde{w}_{s,t} p_{s,t} l_{s,t}})=0} \quad \forall s. \end{aligned}$$

Then, by recursively using the expression \(p_{s,t} =\frac{p_{s,s} ({1+n})^{t-s}}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}}\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {\frac{({1+n})^{t-s}}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}} p_{s,s} ({c_{s,t} - \tilde{w}_{s,t} l_{s,t}})=0}. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, by eliminating \(p_{s,s}\) and defining \(c_{s,t} -\tilde{w}_{s,t} l_{s,t} = -\,({1+n}) q_{s,t} + ({1+\tilde{r}_{s,t}}) q_{s,t-1}\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{t=s}^\infty {\frac{({1+n})^{t-s}}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}} [{- ({1+n})q_{s,t} + ({1+\tilde{r}_{s,t}}) q_{s,t-1}}]=0} \end{aligned}$$

that turns out to be:

$$\begin{aligned} -\lim \frac{({1+n})^{t-s}}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}} q_{s,t} +q_{s,s} =0 \end{aligned}$$

which holds if \(q_{s,t} = a_{s,t}\) and \(\lim \frac{({1+n})^{t-s}}{\prod \limits _{i=s+1}^t {({1+\tilde{r}_{s,i}})}} a_{s,t} =0\).

As for the public sector budget constraint, by aggregating the individuals’ budget constraints over population at time t and expressing them in per capita terms, we get

$$\begin{aligned} a_t =\frac{({1+r_t})}{({1+\gamma })}a_{t-1} +w_t l_t -c_t -\tau _t. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Finally, by subtracting the feasibility constraint

$$\begin{aligned} k_t =\frac{({1+r_t})}{({1+\gamma })}k_{t-1} +w_t l_t -c_t -g_t \end{aligned}$$

and defining \(b_t =-\,k_{t-1} +a_t\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} b_t =\frac{({1+r_t})}{({1+\gamma })}b_{t-1} +g_t -\tau _t \end{aligned}$$

which is Eq. (11) in the text. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

De Bonis, V., Spataro, L. Optimal income taxation and migration. Int Tax Public Finance 25, 867–882 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9483-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9483-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation