Skip to main content
Log in

Frisch’s Propagation-Impulse Model: A Comprehensive Mathematical Analysis

  • Published:
Foundations of Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 30 December 2022

This article has been updated

Abstract

Frisch’s 1933 macroeconomic model for business cycles has been extensively studied. The present study is the first comprehensive mathematical analysis of Frisch’s model. It provides a detailed reconstruction of how the model was built. We demonstrate the workability of Frisch’s PPIP model without adding hypotheses or changing the value of Frisch’s parameters. We prove that (1) the propagation model oscillates; (2) the PPIP model is mathematically incomplete; (3) the latter could have been calibrated by Frisch; (4) Frisch’s analysis and demonstration are based on Poincaré’s methodology

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

Notes

  1. Frisch’s essay was published in the book Economic Essays in Honor of Gustav Cassel for which contributors were invited to write a chapter. In other words, Frisch did not have to follow the selection process as we have in a scientific journal, and he did not have to format his article according to the standards of a scientific article. Moreover, Frisch sent his chapter with a delay, and consequently it could not be reviewed by the editors as originally planned (Bjerkholt 2007, pp. 473–474).

  2. It is worth reminding that Frisch met Divisia and other French mathematicians during his stay in Paris in 1921–1923. He also defended his doctorate on a subject in mathematical statistics rather than in economics (Bjerkholt 2007, p. 13).

  3. Frisch had also his own time series, but he did not provide them (Bjerkholt 2007, p. 457).

  4. In the particular case where the impressed frequency of the periodic force is equal to the natural (undamped) frequency of the system, amplitude of oscillations increase beyond all bounds as time passes. Such phenomenon is called resonance. As an example, in 1831, when an army was marching across a drawbridge in Britain, the drawbridge vibrated and the amplitude of the vibration grew rapidly. All soldiers were then thrown.

  5. We can also include Tinbergen who explained that “The first publication of this sort was a paper in Polish by Kalecki in Proba Teorij Konjunktury, Warszawa, 1933. A few months later appeared Frisch’s “Propagation Problems and Impulse Problems”. Both theories were presented at the Leyden meeting of the Econometric Society in 1933” (Tinbergen 1935, p. 268).

  6. The influence of the early work in econometrics on the theory of oscillations developed in mathematics and physics would deserve a separate investigation. However, it is worth mentioning that Rocard proposed in 1941 an economic model based on the analyses of Frisch and Kalecki and on relaxation oscillations. Rocard’s 1941 chaotic econometric model preceded Lorenz’ butterfly of 22 years. Ginoux (2017) established that this “new old” three-dimensional autonomous dynamical system is a new jerk system whose solution exhibits a chaotic attractor the topology of which varies, from a double scroll attractor to a Möbius-strip and then to a toroidal attractor, according to the values of a control parameter.

  7. Frisch clarified that “For a more detailed mathematical analysis the reader is referred to a paper to appear in one of the early numbers of Econometrica” (Frisch 1933, p. 199). Unfortunately, such a paper has never been published. While Frisch did not provide an explicit mathematical formulation for his “propagation-impulse model”, his model is complete in the sense that Frisch found the values of the periods of the economic cycles by calibrating this model. Therefore, when Duque (2009, p. 48) argued that this model is incomplete, it must be understood that it is mathematically incomplete.

  8. The annual investment is determined by the accelerator principle (Dupont-Kieffer 2012).

  9. See Sect. 3.1, Eq. (4).

  10. We can notice that \(\alpha\) is necessary non-null otherwise the system would not oscillate.

  11. For more details about Frisch’s method of resolution of system (14a14b), see Duque (2009) .

  12. As Duque (2009, p. 23) explained “these values were the result of endless calculations and trial-and-error attempts as evidenced by his notes taken while preparing the manuscript”.

  13. For an extended analysis of Zambelli’s error, see Jovanovic and Ginoux (2020).

  14. Frisch (1933, 199) referred to a paper to appear in Econometrica, but such a paper has never been published.

  15. Let’s notice that although the perturbations produced by such erratic shocks make vary the damped period and the amplitude, such variations, taking place “within such limits that it is reasonable to speak of an average period and an average amplitude”, do not correspond to the moving average as it can be easily evidenced.

  16. Of course, the increase of the number n of erratic shocks would improve the accuracy of the modeling.

References

  • Akerman, J. (1928). Om det Ekonomiska Livets Rytmik [Rhythmics of Economic Life] University of Lund.

  • Andronov, A. A. & Khaikin, S. E. (1937 [1949]). Theory of oscillations (Transl. and adapted by S. Lefschetz). Princeton University Press.

  • Arrow, K. J. (1960). The work of Ragnar Frisch, econometrician. Econometrica, 28(2), 175–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backhouse, R. E. (2015). Revisiting Samuelson’s “Foundations of economic analysis.” Journal of Economic Literature, 53(2), 326–350.

  • Bjerkholt, O. (2007). Ragnar Frisch’s contribution to business cycle analysis. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 13(3), 449–486.

  • Bjerkholt, O., & Dupont, A. (2010). Ragnar Frisch’s conception of econometrics. History of Political Economy, 42(1), 21–73.

  • Blatt, J. M. (1980). On the Frisch Model of Business Cycles. Oxford Economic Papers, 32(3), 467–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boumans, M. (2005). How Economists Model the World into Numbers, Routeledge. Taylor & Francis.

  • Boumans, M. (2005). Frisch on testing of business cycle theories. Journal of Econometrics, 67(1), 129–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carret, V. (2020). Ragnar Frisch 1933 model: And yet it rocks! HAL archives-ouverts.fr.

  • Christ, C. F. (1983). The Founding of the Econometric Society and Econometrica. Econometrica, 51(1), 3–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S., & Trabandt, M. (2018). On DSGE models. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), 113–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooke, K. L. (1963). Differential—Difference Equations. In P. Joseph (Ed.), International symposium on nonlinear differential equations and nonlinear mechanics (pp. 155–171). LaSalle, Solomon Lefschetz, Academic Press.

  • Dupont-Kieffer, A. (2012). The accelerator principle at the core of Frisch’s 1933 rocking horse model. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 34(4), 447–473.

  • Duque, R. (2009). The Rocking Horse Reloaded: An overview over Ragnar Frisch’s 1933 Propagation and Impulse Problems University of Oslo].

  • Frisch, R. (1931). The interrelation between capital production and consumer-taking. Journal of Political Economy, 39(5), 646–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. (1933). Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics. In Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel (pp. 171–205). George Allen and Unwin Ltd.

  • Frisch, R., & Holme, H. (1935). The characteristic solutions of a mixed difference and differential equation occurring in economic dynamics. Econometrica, 3(2), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fröberg, C.-E. (1985). Numerical mathematics: Theory and computer applications. Basic Books.

  • Ginoux, J.-M. (2017). History of nonlinear Oscillations Theory in France (1880-1940). Springer International Publishing.

  • Ginoux, J.-M., Jovanovic, F., Meucci, R. & Llibre, J. (2022). Rocard’s 1941 chaotic relaxation econometric oscillator. International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos. March 2022, forthcoming paper.

  • Hamburger, L. (1931). Analogie des fluctuations économiques et des oscillations de relaxation. Indices du Mouvement des Affaires, 9 - supplément(Janvier), 1-35.

  • Hansen, L. P., & Heckman, J. J. (1996). The Empirical Foundations of Calibration. The journal of economic perspectives, 10(1), 87–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1927). Differential equations subject to error, and population estimates. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 22(159), 283–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, F. & Ginoux, J.-M. (2020). The ’Rocking Horse Model Does Rock’: Solving Zambelli’s puzzle (October 17, 2020). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3713959 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3713959

  • Juglar, C. (1889). Des crises commerciales et de leur retour periodique en France, en Angleterre et aux Etats-Unis (2nd ed.). Guillaumin.

  • Kalecki, M. (1935). A macrodynamic theory of business cycles. Econometrica, 3(3), 327–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Gall, P. (1994). Histoire de l’Econométrie, 1914–1944. L’Erosion du Déterminisme [Doctoral dissertation, Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne].

  • Lord Rayleigh (John William Strutt). (1883). On maintained vibrations. Philosophical Magazine, Series 5, 15(94), 229–235.

  • Louçà, F. (2007). The years of high econometrics. A short history of the generation that reinvented economics

  • Minorsky, N. (1942). Self-excited oscillations in dynamical systems possessing retarded actions. Journal of Applied Mechanics, 9(2), A65–A71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minorsky, N. (1947). Introduction to non-linear mechanics (Originally published 1944–1946, as Restricted reports by David W. Taylor Model Basin, U.S. Navy). J. W. Edwards.

  • Minorsky, N. (1948). Self-excited mechanical oscillations. Journal of Applied Physics, 19, 332–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, W. C. (1913). Business cycles. University of California Press.

  • Morgan, M. S. (1990). The history of econometric ideas. Cambridge University Press.

  • Poincaré, H. (1992 [1892, 1893, 1899]). New Methods of Celestial Mechanics, edited by Daniel Goroff (3 volumes). English translation of the French original edition of Les Méthodes Nouvelles de la Mécanique Céleste, Paris, Gauthier-Villars, 1892, 1893, 1899 (3 volumes). American Institute of Physics.

  • Rocard, Y. (1941). Théorie des oscillateurs. Édition de la Revue Scientifique.

  • Rudin, W. (1966). Real and complex analysis. McGraw-Hill.

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1974). Remembrances of Frisch. European Economic Review, 5(1), 7–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky, E. (1927). Slozhenie sluchainykh prichin, kak istochnik tsiklicheskikh protsessov. Voprosy kon”yunktury, 3, 34–64.

  • Thalberg, B. (1990). A reconsideration of frisch’s original cycle model. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinear and multisectoral macrodynamics. Essays in honour of Richard Goodwin (pp. 96–117). The MacMillan Press Ltd.

  • Tinbergen, J. (1935). Annual survey: Suggestions on a quantitative business cycle theory. Econometrica, 3(3), 241–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Pol, B. (1925). Het onderling verband tusschen eenige moderne vorderingen in de draadlooze telegrafie en telefonie, (“The Interrelation of Some Modern Advances in Wireless Telegraphy and Telephony”). Polytechnish Weekblad, 19, 791–794.

  • Van der Pol, B. (1926). On relaxation-oscillations. The London, Edinburgh, and Dublin Philosophical Magazine and Journal of Science, 2(VII), 978–992.

  • Velupillai, K. (1992). Implicit nonlinearities in the economic dynamics of ’impulse and propagation’. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinearities, disequilibria and simulation–proceedings of the arne ryde symposium on quantitative methods in the stabilization of macrodynamic systems. Essays in honor of Bjorn Thalberg. The MacMillan Press Ltd.

  • Venkatachalam, R., & Velupillai, K. (2012). Origins and early development of the nonlinear endogenous mathematical theory of the business cycle. Economia Politica, 24(1), 45–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yule, G. U. (1927). On a method of investigating periodicities in disturbed series, with special reference to wolfer’s sunspot numbers. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London, Series A, 226, 267–298.

  • Zambelli, S. (1992). The wooden horse that wouldn’t rock: Reconsidering Frisch. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinearities, disequilibria and simulation—proceedings of the Arne Ryde symposium on quantitative methods in the stabilization of macrodynamic systems. Essays in honor of Bjorn Thalberg. The MacMillan Press Ltd.

Download references

Acknowledgements

Author would like to thank the reviewers who considerably improved this work with their remarks and helpful advices.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Franck Jovanovic.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ginoux, JM., Jovanovic, F. Frisch’s Propagation-Impulse Model: A Comprehensive Mathematical Analysis. Found Sci 28, 57–84 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10699-021-09827-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10699-021-09827-9

Keywords

Navigation