Skip to main content
Log in

Ernst Cassirer’s Philosophy of Culture: An Economic Assessment of Scope and Limitations

  • Published:
Foundations of Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Cassirer’s philosophy of culture has been examined through various disciplines. Until now, however, no such assessment has taken place within the field of economics. In this paper, I attempt to develop this unexplored task through the economic concepts of commodity, money, capital, and culture. I argue that these concepts can help to draw an updated concept of capitalism and power relations created through capitalist planning. I also claim that these concepts can contribute to understanding the historical specificity of capitalist culture, by understanding it as an historical process of social production. I conclude that these concepts are able to defy Cassirer’s view of capitalism as a system in which economic prosperity and political liberty could be achieved in a universal manner. Finally, I demonstrate that these concepts can shed light on Cassirer’s failed quest to find a coherent universal culture within capitalism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I owe much to Skidelsky’s work. However, I aim to work out problems developed by Cassirer from a different perspective in order to contribute to conceptualizing questions that Skidelsky’s book raises, but which, in the author’s own words, he “cannot answer” (Skidelsky 2011, p. 8).

  2. And not just as a generic human capacity to create symbols, as understood by Cassirer.

  3. “his many contributions to the history of science, culture, and epistemology bespoke a robust attachment to the rationalist spirit of the Aufklarung, from Leibniz to Kant, and to the cultural legacy of German classicism, from Goethe to Schiller and Humboldt” (Gordon 2004, pp. 225–226).

  4. “Cassirer suffered the great misfortune to emerge as a stalwart champion of humanism and Enlightenment rationality at the very moment such ideals were falling into eclipse, not only in Germany but arguably across Western Europe as well” (Gordon 2009).

  5. “Political economy is the science which starts from this view of needs and labour but then has the task of explaining mass relationships and mass-movements in their complexity and their qualitative and quantitative character” (Hegel 2008, p. 187).

  6. According to Beiser (2014), there were many attempts during the second half of the nineteenth century in Germany to once again define the subject matter of philosophy. The most famous definitions were: philosophy as the logic of the sciences (Trendelenburg), philosophy as critique (left-wing Hegelians), philosophy as metaphysics (Schopenhauer), philosophy as epistemology (Fischer, Zeller and the Neo-Kantianism), philosophy as the general system of the sciences (Hartmann), philosophy as the science of normativity (Windelband), and philosophy as a worldview (Dilthey).

  7. In the same vein, Skidelsky stated that “The First World War brought an end to that era…The various social and intellectual forces that he had striven to keep together came rapidly apart. Socialists revolted against liberals; liberals turned their guns on socialists. Anti-Semitism spread; young Jews lost faith in assimilation and turned increasingly to Zionism or international Marxism. The intellectual world suffered the same polarization. The “two cultures” fell irretrievably apart; the Naturwissenschaften were given over to a reinvigorated positivism, while the Geisteswissenschaften shaded increasingly into political mysticism” (Skidelsky 2011, p. 42).

  8. I took this characterization from Pablo Levin.

  9. “Cassirer more or less disappeared from philosophical discourse after the Second World War. Only recently, after decades, interest in the philosophy of Cassirer has increased, not only in philosophy, but also in numerous other disciplines” (Coskun 2007, pp. 1–2).

  10. “It is indeed part of the liberty of princes to do as they like about the things in their power; but since money, which is spent all the time now here and now there, belongs to the world, princes have no special authority over it: that is to command it to depart or to remain according to their will. Therefore, money is like the birds (of the air) which no prince can command, to depart or remain in his city or state or realm, as they go to live where they find the best feeding grounds” (Pratisuoli 1604, quoted in Maifreda 2004, p. 127); “let those who read me fix it well in their minds and let them be persuaded that the laws of trade correspond with so great an exactitude to those of gravity and fluids that nothing do so more than they” (Galiani quoted in Maifreda 2004). Romero (1999) explains that the task of formulating those economic laws began in the late middle ages.

  11. Williams (1983) argued that the modern development of the word “culture” has three different meanings: (1) culture as a process of individual enrichment, (2) culture as a group’s “particular way of life,” (Williams 1983, p. 90); (3) “the works and practices of intellectual and especially artistic activity” (Williams 1983, p. 90). These three senses of culture are different, and they compete with one another.

  12. In our interpretation, this economic concept of culture can be extended to the related concepts of Praxeology, which focuses on the generic study of human society and its technical cultures; Ethology, which is a branch of biology devoted to the study of animal cultures; and Evolutive Ecology, which is devoted to understanding human history in the context of natural history (Levin 2010).

References

  • Avineri, S. (1967). The Hegelian origins of Marx’s political thought. The Review of Metaphysics, 21(1), 33–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Avineri, S. (1968). The social and political thought of Karl Marx. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barash, J. A. (2008). The symbolic construction of reality. The legacy of Ernst Cassirer. Chicago: The university of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayer, T. I. (2001). Cassirer´s metaphysics of symbolic forms. A philosophical commentary. New Haven, London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beiser, F. (2014). After Hegel. German philosophy 1840–1900. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bidney, D. (1949). On the philosophical anthropology of Ernst Cassirer and its relation to the history of anthropological thought. In P. A. Schilpp (Ed.), The philosophy of Ernst Cassirer (pp. 467–544). Evanston: The Library of Living Philosophers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, P. (2009). Book Review: Ernst Cassirer: The Last Philosopher of Culture. By Edward Skidelsky. Princeton, NJ, and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2008. Journal of European Studies, 39(3), 404–406.

  • Cassirer, E. (1946). The myth of the State. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassirer, E. (1951). The philosophy of the enlightenment. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassirer, E. (1954). An essay on man. An introduction to a philosophy of human culture. New York: Doubleday and Company Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassirer, E. (1980). The philosophy of symbolic forms. Volume one: Language. New Haven & London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassirer, E. (1993). Filosofía de la ilustración. Madrid: Fondo de Cultura Económica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cazenave, A., Levin, PyV., & Romero (2018). El concepto de planificación tal como resulta del desarrollo teórico más avanzado de la economía política. Revista de investigación en economía y responsabilidad social, 1, 3–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coskun, D. (2007). Law as a symbolic form. Ernst Cassirer and the anthropocentric view of law. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danford, J. W. (1990). David Hume and the problem of reason: Recovering the human sciences. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B., Marciano, A., & Runde, J. (2004). The Elgar companion to economics and philosophy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dilthey, W. (2015). Introducción a las ciencias del espíritu. Ciudad de México: Fondo de Cultura Económica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freudenthal, G. (2008). The hero of enlightenment. In J. A. Barash (Ed.), The symbolic construction of reality. The legacy of Ernst Cassirer (pp. 189–214). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J. T., & Luft, S. (2015). The philosophy of Ernst Cassirer. A novel assessment. Berlin, Boston: De Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (2000). A parting of the ways: Carnap, Cassirer, and Heidegger. Chicago: Open Court.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (2002). Carnap, Cassirer, and Heidegger: The Davos disputation and twentieth century philosophy. European Journal of Philosophy, 10(3), 263–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gawronsky, D. (1949). Ernst Cassirer: His life and work. In P. A. Schilpp (Ed.), The Philosophy of Ernst Cassirer (pp. 3–37). Evanston: The Library of Living Philosophers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, V. A., & Thorsby, D. (2006). The handbook of economics of art and culture. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, P. E. (2004). Continental divide: Ernst Cassirer and Martin Heidegger at Davos, 1929—An allegory of intellectual history. Modern Intellectual History, 1(2), 219–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, P. E. (2009). Review of Edward Skidelsky (author 1st book), Jeffrey Andrew Barash (editor 2nd book), (Book 1) Ernst Cassirer: The Last Philosopher of Culture;(Book 2) the Symbolic Construction of Reality: The Legacy of Ernst Cassirer. https://ndpr.nd.edu/news/book-1-ernst-cassirer-the-last-philosopher-of-culture-book-2-the-symbolic-construction-of-reality-the-legacy-of-ernst-cassirer/.

  • Grosholz, E. R. (2010). The humanism of Ernst Cassirer. The Hudson Review, 62(4), 691–698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Habermas, J. (2001). The liberating power of symbols: Ernst Cassirer’s humanistic legacy and the Warburg Library. In J. Habermas (Ed.), The liberating power of symbols. Philosophical essays. Cambridge: Polity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hegel, G. W. F. (2008). Outlines of the philosophy of right. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hegel, G. W. F. (2017). Fenomenología del espíritu. Mexico City: Fondo de cultura económica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holborn, H. (1949). Ernst Cassirer. In P. A. Schilpp (Ed.), The philosophy of Ernst Cassirer (pp. 41–45). Evanston: The Library of Living Philosophers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Honenberger, P. (2010). Review of Skidelsky, “Ernst Cassirer: The last philosopher of culture”. Metaphilosophy, 41(1–2), 239–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horkheimer, M., & Adorno, T. W. (2002). Dialectic of enlightenment. Philosophical fragments. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, H. S. (1958). Consciousness and society: The reorientation of European social thought, 1890–1930. New York: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1991). Kant: Political writings. New Yok: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1998). Critique of pure reason. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, P. A. (2016). Chapter thirty-six-the last 50 years: Mismeasurement and mismanagement are impeding scientific research. Current Topics in Developmental Biology, 116, 617–631.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, P. (1997). El capital tecnológico. Buenos Aires: Editorial Tecnos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, P. (2004). El progreso social desde la perspectiva del tercer sector. ¿Quién planifica a quién? http://www.economicas.uba.ar/wp-content/uploads/2015/11/El-progreso-social-desde-la-perspectiva-del-tercer-sector_-%C2%BFqui%C3%A9n-planifica-a-qui%C3%A9n_.pdf.

  • Levín, P. (2010). Esquema de la ciencia económica. Revista de Economía Política de Buenos Aires, 7 y 8(4), 247–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, P. (2014). La “reforma del 18”. Su teoría en el sombrero. In P. Levin, A. Cazenave, P. Piqué, C. Rikap & V. Romero (Eds.), Apuntes para el Metaplán (pp. 5–16). Buenos Aires: Facultad de Ciencias Económicas (UBA).

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, P. (2016). Concepto económico de salud mental. Indagación exploratoria. Vertex. Revista Argentina de Psiquiatría, 125(XXVII), 25–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, P., Cazenave, A., & Piqué, P. (2018). Ensayo sobre el posible aporte de la economía política a la filosofía de la aspiración. Revista de Investigación en Economía y Responsabilidad Social, 1(2), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maifreda, G. (2004). From Oikonomia to Political Economy. Constructing economic knowledge from the renaissance to the Scientific Revolution. Farnham: Ashgate Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1904). A contribution to the critique of political economy. Chicago: Charles H. Kerr & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1976). Capital. A critique of political economy. Volume one. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piqué, P. (2017). La obra de Adam Smith en el estudio y en la enseñanza de la historia del pensamiento económico. Tesis de doctorado de la Facultad Ciencias Económicas de la Universidad de Buenos Aires http://bibliotecadigital.econ.uba.ar/econ/collection/tesis/document/1501-1281_PiqueP.

  • Pos, H. J. (1949). Recollections of Ernst Cassirer. In P. A. Schilpp (Ed.), The Philosophy of Ernst Cassirer (pp. 61–73). Evanston: The Library of Living Philosophers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Redman, D. A. (1997). The rise of political economy as a science methodology and the classical economists. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rikap, C. (2015). ¿Escisión entre la Enseñanza y la Investigación?: El caso de la Universidad de Buenos Aires. Ciencia, docencia y tecnología, 51, 54–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romero, J. L. (1999). Estudio de la mentalidad burguesa. Buenos Aires: Alianza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schilpp, P. A. (1949). The philosophy of Ernst Cassirer. Evanston: The Library of Living Philosophers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schnädelbach, H. (1991). Filosofía en Alemania 1831–1933. Madrid: Cátedra.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skidelsky, E. (2011). Ernst Cassirer: The last philosopher of culture. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snow, C. P. (2012). The two cultures. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (2001). Economics and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, R. (1960a). Culture and society. 1780–1950. Garden City. New York: Anchor Books Doubleday & Company, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, R. (1960b). Culture and society. 1750–1950. Garden City: Anchor Books, Doubleday Company & Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, R. (1983). Keywords. A vocabulary of culture and society. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work would not have been possible without the fruitful theoretical discussions I have had with Pablo Levin and my colleagues at CEPLAD, as part of “The Heteronomon” research project. While the present work has a single author, it is important to underline the collective nature of the ideas being developed. Any errors are the sole responsibility of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pilar Piqué.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Piqué, P. Ernst Cassirer’s Philosophy of Culture: An Economic Assessment of Scope and Limitations. Found Sci 26, 341–354 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10699-020-09678-w

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10699-020-09678-w

Keywords

Navigation