Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Garbage In and Garbage Out? On Waste Havens in Switzerland

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates whether the introduction of a unit-based garbage fee induces waste dumping in nearby communities which do not implement such a policy. To identify the existence of a “waste haven effect”, I hypothesize that the likelihood of “importing” or “exporting” waste depends on the distance to municipalities which have chosen the alternative policy option. Distances between municipalities are captured by routing data. I find some evidence for waste havens in a cross-section of Swiss municipalities. Exploiting variation in waste policy over time in a panel dataset for the canton of Ticino, I find that a decrease in distance is associated with an increase in the amount of waste collected by non-unit-pricing municipalities. The effect size is relatively small: An increase by one standard deviation in the impact factor applied to identify the waste haven effect increases the amount of collected waste per capita in non-unit-pricing municipalities by less than 3%.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Bel and Gradus (2016) for examples of countries with unit pricing of household garbage.

  2. Aargauer Zeitung, 24.07.14. www.aargauerzeitung.ch, last accessed on 02.04.2015.

  3. The terms waste spillovers and waste haven effect describe the same behavior in this context and are used interchangeably throughout the paper.

  4. See, e.g., Oates (1999) for a discussion of fiscal federalism.

  5. There is a vast number of studies on the so-called “pollution haven effect”, which hypothesizes that industries relocate production due to changes in environmental regulations. See Copeland and Taylor (2004) and Copeland (2011) for reviews of the literature.

  6. Kinnaman and Fullerton (2000a) and Bel and Gradus (2016) provide reviews of this literature.

  7. No spillovers were detected for other types of waste.

  8. Garbage or waste here and throughout the paper is defined as the non-recycled (unsorted) leftovers of solid waste.

  9. I follow the notation of Kinnaman and Fullerton (2000b) when possible.

  10. Viscusi et al. (2011) separate between private values and external social norms. Here, both may induce such guilt costs.

  11. Dumping in public trashcans can be added to this group of options, at least for small amounts of garbage.

  12. Remember that \(g^i\) is the amount collected at the curbside. Accordingly, there is a difference between the amount of waste generated (\(g^i + x^i + b^i\)) and the amount of waste collected (\(g^i\)).

  13. Further details will be given in Sect. 3.

  14. It remains an empirical question how many of these bilateral relations are relevant for waste spillovers. The rationale of the unit pricing municipality suggests that waste should accumulate close to the border, as the exporting households try to keep their transport costs low.

  15. A similar hypothesis could be formulated regarding the expected fines for waste dumping. There is no available data on the height of fines, thus I leave such a hypothesis for future research.

  16. I thank the editor for this suggestion.

  17. Note that as I calculate \(\Delta \ln \ { Waste}\ p.c._{ij} = \ln { Waste}\ p.c._{i} - \ln { Waste}\ p.c._{j}\), the average difference is negative.

  18. Note that a regression discontinuity design, using road traveling time as the forcing variable, could only identify the joint effect of unit pricing and waste spillovers at the border.

  19. Even though Bel and Gradus (2016) found that accounting for endogeneity of unit prices does not significantly influence the elasticities estimated in the literature.

  20. See Table B1 in the “Appendix” for precise information on data sources. Data was unavailable for certain municipalities within some of the cantons. In the canton of Ticino, I drop the observations which report exactly the same amount of waste per capita as other nearby communities—as it indicates that figures were jointly reported to the office for waste and hazardous waste sites (Ufficio rifiuti e siti inquinati) which then split the data at the municipal level, keeping the amount of waste per capita constant.

  21. More precisely, only the canton of Nidwalden had municipalities without unit pricing in 2012 which are missing in the sample.

  22. I report estimates that include the canton of Vaud in Online Appendix B.2. The mentioned measurement errors make it likely that the regressions excluding Vaud are the more credible estimates.

  23. Unfortunately, most cantons are unable to provide information about the date when their communities switched to unit pricing, which consequently limits the possibilities for panel investigations.

  24. I cross-checked distances with Google maps routing data. Mapquest consistently estimates lower traveling times (i.e., approximately 5–10% lower) between municipalities; as this study is more interested in relative than absolute distances between communities, this does not qualitatively affect our results.

  25. As no data on waste per capita is available for municipalities of Nidwalden, they are not included in the sample for the following regression analysis. As the 11 municipalities of Nidwalden had not introduced unit pricing in 2012 and are thus potential waste havens, the distance to these municipalities was still taken into account when computing the distance measure for the unit-pricing municipalities in the sample.

  26. The left slope of Fig. 3a is not significant, while the right slope in Fig. 3a is significantly different from zero. The results of the univariate regressions are provided in Table B3.

  27. Due to data constraints, I cannot control for the education level, but variables reflecting political preferences are included.

  28. This indicator is retrieved from recycling-map.ch, a web page that collects information on recycling stations in Switzerland. On this website, when one enters the name of a municipality, a list of recycling stations appears, including which types of waste they accept. In a minority of cases, the response includes collection stations which are close-by, but not within the municipality’s boundaries (e.g., intercommunal collection centers are mentioned even if outside the area of the municipality). Thus, the resulting count variable can be interpreted as the number of bulky goods collection centers that a municipality has on its own ground or close-by.

  29. Descriptions and sources of all variables are summarized in Table B2 in the “Appendix”.

  30. I also applied specifications using a squared income term to test for an environmental Kuznets curve-type relationship as found in Ichinose et al. (2015). I find no evidence for a hump-shaped relationship between waste per capital and income. Results are available upon request.

  31. The coefficient for population density becomes insignificant in the last specification, most likely due to collinearity with the “center”-dummy in the community-type fixed effects.

  32. All regressions are run using specification (1) in Table 1 using OLS estimation, and standard errors are clustered on districts.

  33. Potentially, higher income municipalities also have higher unit prices, which would favor waste spillovers.

  34. I further tested interactions of commuter-town dummies with distance and of the share of social welfare recipients with distance. Both coefficients are insignificant.

  35. The most striking difference is that in the subsample of non-unit-pricing municipalities, the share of foreigners shows a significant positive correlation with waste per capita in two of four regressions.

  36. I use the dyadic-robust standard errors made available through Cameron and Miller’s (2014) Stata code “regdyad2”.

  37. Note that the effect here becomes stronger when looking at the 10 min interaction term then for the 5 min interaction term. The shaded areas in Fig. 1c provide an explanation for this pattern: In the case of a waste haven behavior, they are larger the further the distance away from the border.

  38. Note that these point estimates may suffer from the endogeneity problems mentioned in Sect. 3.1. However, Table 6 presents results regarding the non-recyclable waste reduction that are very similar to those of the quasi-natural experiment in the canton of Vaud examined by Carattini et al. (2015). This calms concerns about endogeneity and unobserved heterogeneity.

  39. The Stata command “cgmwildboot” was used to compute the bootstrapped standard errors. Results are available from the author upon request.

  40. No municipality switched back from unit- to non-unit-pricing in Switzerland yet.

  41. Theoretically, this may not be true for unit-pricing municipalities: They might affect the distance by excessive waste spillovers, forcing others to introduce unit pricing, thus the distance to non-unit-pricing municipalities would increase.

  42. Standard errors are clustered on municipalities. The results are robust to clustering on the “circle” level (in Ticino “circoli”), which is one administrative level below the districts (“distretti”).

References

  • Allers MA, Hoeben C (2010) Effects of unit-based garbage pricing: a differences-in-differences approach. Environ Resour Econ 45(3):405–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baggs J (2009) International trade in hazardous waste. Rev Int Econ 17(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bel G, Gradus R (2016) Effects of unit-based pricing on household waste collection demand: a meta-regression analysis. Resour Energy Econ 44:169–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron AC, Gelbach JB, Miller DL (2008) Bootstrap-based improvements for inference with clustered errors. Rev Econ Stat 90(3):414–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron AC, Miller DL (2014) Robust inference for dyadic data. Unpublished manuscript, University of California-Davis

  • Carattini S, Baranzini A, Lalive R (2015) Is taxing waste a waste of time? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment. Unpublished manuscript, Presented at the EAERE 21st Annual Conference 2015, Helsinki

  • Copeland B R (2011) Trade and the environment. In: Bernhofen D, Falvey R, Greenaway D, Kreickemeier U (eds) Palgrave handbook of international trade. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 423–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (2004) Trade, growth, and the environment. J Econ Lit 42(1):7–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Jaeger S, Eyckmans J (2012) Do households export their recyclable waste? Working paper 2012/21, Hogeschool-Universiteit Brussel, Faculteit Economie en Management

  • Dijkgraaf E, Gradus RHJM (2004) Cost savings in unit-based pricing of household waste: the case of the Netherlands. Resour Energy Econ 26(4):353–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbs IM (1991) Litter and waste management: disposal taxes versus user charges. Can J Econ/Rev can d’écon 24(1):221–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara I, Missios P (2012) A cross-country study of household waste prevention and recycling: assessing the effectiveness of policy instruments. Land Econ 88(4):710–744

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS (1992) Pricing and regulating affect environmental ethics. Environ Resour Econ 2(4):399–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Kinnaman TC (1995) Garbage, recycling, and illicit burning or dumping. J Environ Econ Manag 29(1):78–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Kinnaman TC (1996) Household responses to pricing garbage by the bag. Am Econ Rev 86(4):971–984

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilardi F, Füglister K (2008) Empirical modeling of policy diffusion in federal states: the dyadic approach. Swiss Polit Sci Rev 14(3):413–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy U, Meier S, Rey-Biel P (2011) When and why incentives (don’t) work to modify behavior. J Econ Perspect 25(4):191–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higashida K, Managi S (2014) Determinants of trade in recyclable wastes: evidence from commodity-based trade of waste and scrap. Environ Dev Econ 19(02):250–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichinose D, Yamamoto M, Yoshida Y (2015) The decoupling of affluence and waste discharge under spatial correlation: do richer communities discharge more waste? Environ Dev Econ 20(2):161–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn ME, Li P, Zhao D (2015) Water pollution progress at borders: the role of changes in China’s political promotion incentives. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7(4):223–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellenberg D (2010) Consumer waste, backhauling, and pollution havens. J Appl Econ 13(2):283–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellenberg D (2012) Trading wastes. J Environ Econ Manag 64(1):68–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinnaman TC (2006) Policy watch: examining the justification for residential recycling. J Econ Perspect 20(4):219–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinnaman TC, Fullerton D (2000a) The economics of municipal solid waste management. In: Folmer H, Tietenberg T (eds) The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2000/2001. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 100–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinnaman TC, Fullerton D (2000b) Garbage and recycling with endogenous local policy. J Urban Econ 48(3):419–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson A (1999) State taxes and interstate hazardous waste shipments. Am Econ Rev 89(3):666–677

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Lit 37(3):1120–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Usui T, Takeuchi K (2014) Evaluating unit-based pricing of residential solid waste: a panel data analysis. Environ Resour Econ 58(2):245–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi WK, Huber J, Bell J (2011) Promoting recycling: private values, social norms, and economic incentives. Am Econ Rev 101(3):65–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tobias Erhardt.

Additional information

I am grateful to Giulia Felber, Frank Krysiak, Reto Odermatt, Christian Rutzer, Michaela Slotwinski, Alessandro Tavoni, and Rolf Weder for valuable comments and discussions. Moreover, I thank participants of the Economics Lunch Seminar at the University of Basel, the 50th Annual Conference of the Canadian Economics Association, the 5th Annual AERE Summer Conference, and the 22nd Annual Conference of the EAERE for their remarks.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 246 KB)

A Appendix Tables

A Appendix Tables

See Tables 8, 9 and 10.

Table 8 Mathematical symbols listed in order of first appearance
Table 9 Summary statistics cross section
Table 10 Summary statistics panel data Ticino

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Erhardt, T. Garbage In and Garbage Out? On Waste Havens in Switzerland. Environ Resource Econ 73, 251–282 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0260-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0260-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation