Skip to main content
Log in

The Signaling Effect of Emission Taxes Under International Duopoly

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze equilibrium emission taxes under international Cournot duopoly in the presence of asymmetric information between firms. When each firm does not know the production cost of its rival located in the other country, the government of each country can use its emission tax as a signal of the competitiveness of its domestic firm. We show that, owing to this signaling effect, the equilibrium emission tax and expected welfare of each country can be higher than those under symmetric information between firms or even higher than those obtained if the governments were to non-strategically set the tax rate equal to the (expected) marginal damage from pollution (i.e., the Pigouvian tax level). Our results suggest that the presence of asymmetric information between firms can mitigate a “race to the bottom” in strategic environmental policymaking.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Examples of bilateral agreements that have recently entered into force or have been negotiated include Malaysia-India (in force since 2011), South Korea-China (in force since 2015), South Korea-EU (fully in force since 2015), Singapore-EU (negotiation completed), Vietnam-EU (negotiation completed), and Malaysia-EU (under negotiation). In addition, the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement has been signed in 2016 and includes Japan, Malaysia, Singapore, and Vietnam, and the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership has been under negotiation among countries including China, India, Japan, South Korea, and ASEAN.

  2. South Korea and Vietnam impose effluent charges on emissions of some air and/or water pollutants. Vietnam also imposes environmental taxes on several products such as fossil fuels and pesticides. Moreover, Singapore and South Korea plan or consider introducing carbon taxes to reduce greenhouse gas emissions from 2020 under the Paris Agreement (World Bank 2016; Singapore, Ministry of Finance 2017). Note that, while our model assumes local pollution, our main results would be qualitatively similar even assuming a transboundary pollution scenario, such as global warming (see the discussion in Sect. 5).

  3. Several empirical studies also find little evidence for a race to the bottom in environmental policymaking (e.g., List and Gerking 2000; Fredriksson and Millimet 2002; Millimet 2003).

  4. Barigozzi and Villeneuve (2006) analyze the signaling role of excise tax policy when the government is informed about the negative side effect of a particular product, while uninformed consumers form beliefs about the intensity of the side effect based on the observed tax rate.

  5. Moreover, from a technical viewpoint, our study considers a “simultaneous” signaling game in which two governments simultaneously signal their private information through their emission tax rates. In the industrial organization literature, studies such as Mailath (1989), Caminal (1990), and Daughety and Reinganum (2008) use simultaneous signaling games to analyze price signaling by oligopolistic firms.

  6. For the analysis of strategic trade policy under asymmetric information, see also Qui (1994) and Brainard and Martimort (1997).

  7. We employ a third-market model in which there exists only one firm and no domestic consumers in each country to facilitate the comparison of our results with those of previous studies, such as Conrad (1993), Barrett (1994), and Ulph (1996). If we assumed that there exist multiple (identical) firms or domestic consumers within each country, governments would have another incentive to increase or decrease their emission tax rates, which does not arise in our current setting. Even then, however, we could still obtain the signaling effect that induces governments to set higher emission taxes. We discuss this issue in Sect. 5.

  8. We do not consider firms’ abatement activities; therefore, the emission of the pollutant in country i is equal to the output level of firm i, \(q_i\). However, even if we incorporated firms’ use of (end-of-pipe) abatement technology, our results would remain qualitatively unchanged. Moreover, even if we assumed that pollution is transboundary, we would obtain qualitatively similar results. We provide a more detailed discussion on this latter issue in Sect. 5.

  9. The time structure of the game is essential for our study. If we adopted a different time structure where, for example, firms choose their output levels before governments choose emission taxes, or firms and governments simultaneously make their choices, then the signaling component of the emission taxes would be eliminated.

  10. The types of firms are independently determined, and each government has no information about the type of the foreign firm when it sets its emission tax rate. Therefore, it is natural to assume that the tax rate set by government i does not convey any information about the type of firm j; that is, the posterior belief about firm j’s marginal cost is independent of the emission tax rate set by government i, \(t_i\).

  11. Supposing symmetric information between firms and no emission tax policies in either country, a high-type firm could be active in the market even when its rival is a low-type firm if and only if \(q_i(0,c^H,0;0,1)=(a-2c^H+c^L)/3>0\). To be precise, the right-hand inequality in Assumption (a) follows from this condition, and therefore, it is a sufficient (but not necessary) condition for firms’ output to be positive in the equilibrium in the benchmark case or in the signaling equilibrium analyzed below.

  12. If \(k <1/2\) and governments were allowed to use a negative emission tax, they would indeed set the emission tax at a negative level in the benchmark case [see (6) or (7)] and, then, the analysis and results of this study would be qualitatively the same as those of Collie and Hviid (1993) on export subsidies. On the results obtained in that case, see footnotes 18 and 36.

  13. Our approach to setting up this benchmark is similar to that of Mailath (1989).

  14. Note that, under Assumption 1, the right-hand side of (6) for \(c_i \in \{c^L,c^H\}\) is always strictly positive for any \(\lambda \in (0,1)\) and \(E(t_j) \ge 0\).

  15. The reason behind these properties is the following. A decrease in firm i’s marginal cost, or an increase in government j’s tax rate, induces firm i to produce more output and thereby generate more pollution. This results in two opposite effects on government i’s optimal tax rate. First, government i has an incentive to increase its tax rate to restrict firm i’s emissions. Second, the larger output of firm i induces government i to expand firm i’s market share further and, thus, to reduce its tax rate. When the pollution damage is sufficiently severe (\(k>1/2\)), the former effect dominates.

  16. This tax rule is endogenously obtained if we assume that the government chooses its tax rate by taking as given not only the tax rate set by the foreign government but also the output of the foreign firm; that is, government i maximizes (5) taking \(q_j\) as independent of \(t_i\) (i.e., \(\partial q_j/\partial t_i=0\)). Barrett (1994) and Nannerup (1998) also use this kind of scenario as a benchmark in their analysis of emission standards. On the other hand, other studies such as Conrad (1993) consider the “cooperative equilibrium” as a benchmark, where two governments coordinate their tax rates to maximize their joint welfare. At the end of this section, we also consider this kind of equilibrium in our setting and compare it with the non-signaling and Pigouvian equilibria.

  17. Equation (4) shows that, as country j’s emission tax rate \(t_j\) is lower, firm i’s output level \(q_i\) decreases.

  18. When \(k<1/2\) and governments are allowed to use negative emission taxes (i.e., export subsidies), the equilibrium emission taxes would be negative in this benchmark [see (7)]. Nevertheless, \(t^N(c^m)<t^P(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), still holds and, thus, the pre-commitment effect works in the direction of lowering emission taxes (i.e., increasing export subsidies), which is qualitatively the same as in the case of \(k>1/2\). By contrast, in the presence of asymmetric information between firms, the result obtained when \(k<1/2\) is opposite to our result for \(k>1/2\). See also footnote 36.

  19. The exact expressions for \(EW^N(c^m)\) and \(EW^P(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), are provided in “Appendix A”.

  20. We also employ a numerical analysis in Sects. 4.2 and 4.3. The details of the numerical analysis in this paper are available upon request.

  21. In the complete information setting, the tax rates in the non-signaling and Pigouvian equilibria are given by \(t^N(c^m;c^n)=(2k-1)[(2k+3)(a-c^m)-2(a-c^n)]/[(2k+1)(2k+5)]\) and \(t^P(c^m;c^n)=k[(k+2)(a-c^m)-(a-c^n)]/[(k+1)(k+3)]\), \(m,n=L,H\), where \(c^m\) (\(c^n\)) is the domestic (foreign) firm’s marginal cost. Moreover, we can show that \(t^N(c^m;c^n)<t^P(c^m;c^n)\) holds for \(m,n=L,H\) under Assumption 1.

  22. To be more precise, the tax rates given by (9) are valid as long as \((a-c^L)/(a-c^H)\le (k+2)/2\). Otherwise, and if two firms have different marginal costs, joint welfare maximization requires the high-type firm to cease production. Then, it is optimal to set \(t^C(c^L;c^H)=k(a-c^L)/(k+2)\) and \(t^C(c^H;c^L)\) at a sufficiently high level, so that the high-type firm ceases production.

  23. Moreover, as \(\lambda \) is larger, the tax rates in the cooperative equilibrium are more likely to exceed those in the non-signaling and Pigouvian equilibria. This is because, while \(t^C(c^m;c^n)\) is constant with respect to \(\lambda \), \(t^N(c^m)\) and \(t^P(c^m)\) are decreasing in \(\lambda \) as can be seen from (7) and (8), where \(\bar{c}=\lambda c^L+(1-\lambda )c^H\).

  24. At the end of Sect. 4.2, we also discuss the comparison of the cooperative and signaling equilibria. More detailed results of the comparison of the cooperative and other equilibria are available upon request.

  25. Equation (2) shows that country j’s emission tax rate \(t_j\) affects firm i’s output level \(q_i\) through its effect on firm i’s posterior belief, \(\mu _i(t_j)\); for example, if a change in \(t_j\) increases \(\mu _i(t_j)\), it results in a decrease in \(q_i\).

  26. In “Appendix B.5”, we show that all pooling equilibria are eliminated under the Intuitive Criterion. See also the discussion at the end of this section.

  27. More precisely, under Assumption 1, the left-hand side of (11) is always positive, increasing in k, but bounded above by two, whereas the right-hand side is positive only if \(k>1\) but unboundedly increasing in k. Thus, condition (11) tends to hold when k is sufficiently large.

  28. Condition (11) is most likely to hold when \(\Delta \rightarrow 2\) and \(\lambda \rightarrow 1\), and, then, it is reduced to \(2-12/(2k+5) \le k^2-k\), which is satisfied for \(k\ge 1.3256\). Therefore, condition (11) holds only if \(k>1.3256\).

  29. See “Appendix B.4” for the exact expression for \(EW^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\).

  30. By substituting \(a-\bar{c}=\lambda (a-c^L)+(1-\lambda )(a-c^H)\) into (7) and (8), we can easily show that \(t^N(c^m)\) and \(t^P(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), are homogeneous of degree one in \(a-c^L\) and \(a-c^H\). Similarly, we can express the right-hand sides of (13), (14), and (30) in terms of \(a-c^L\) and \(a-c^H\) and verify that \(t^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), is also homogeneous of degree one in \(a-c^L\) and \(a-c^H\). Moreover, as explained in “Appendices A and B.4”, \(EW^e(c^m)\) for \(e=N,P,S\) and \(m=L,H\) is given by (18) in “Appendix A”. Given that \(a-2c^m+c^n=2(a-c^m)-(a-c^n)\) for \(m,n=L,H\) and that \(t^e(\cdot )\) is homogeneous of degree one in \(a-c^L\) and \(a-c^H\), we can verify that \(EW^e(c^m)\) is homogeneous of degree two in \(a-c^L\) and \(a-c^H\).

  31. More precisely, Fig. 1 shows that \(t^S(c^L)>t^P(c^L)\) is more likely as \(\lambda \) is larger, unless \(\Delta \) is close to two; however, when \(\Delta \) is close to two, \(t^S(c^L)>t^P(c^L)\) is less likely as \(\lambda \) is larger. The reason for the latter statement is that, when \(\Delta \) is close to two, a larger \(\lambda \) tightens condition (12) (i.e., narrows the colored area in Fig. 1) to a relatively large extent and considerably reduces the low-type government’s need to distort its tax rate upward in the signaling equilibrium.

  32. Formally, we can infer from (13) that \(\lim _{c^L \rightarrow c^H} R^S(c^L;E(t^S))=\lim _{c^L \rightarrow c^H} R^N(c^L;E(t^S))\) and we can also verify that \(\lim _{c^L \rightarrow c^H}t^S(c^L)=(2k-1)(a-c^H)/(2k+5)=\lim _{c^L \rightarrow c^H}t^N(c^L)\).

  33. In contrast, the low-type government’s tax rate in the signaling equilibrium is lower than that in the cooperative equilibrium when faced with the low-type foreign government; that is, \(t^S(c^L)<t^C(c^L;c^L)\).

  34. In particular, in the limit of \(\lambda \rightarrow 0\), \(EW^S(c^L)\) is lower than \(EW^N(c^L)\) for any \(\Delta \) and k satisfying Assumption 1 and condition (12).

  35. Indeed, when \(\lambda =0.95\), the region of parameters \(\Delta \) and k where \(EW^S(c^L)>EW^P(c^L)>EW^N(c^L)\) holds in Fig. 2f is entirely contained within that where \(t^S(c^L)>t^P(c^L)>t^N(c^L)\) holds in Fig. 1c.

  36. When \(k<1/2\) and governments are allowed to use negative emission taxes (i.e., export subsidies), we can infer from (6) that governments would like to set lower negative emission taxes (i.e., larger export subsidies) as the marginal cost of their domestic firm is lower, in contrast to the case of \(k>1/2\). Thus, in the signaling equilibrium, the low-type government would distort its emission taxes downward (i.e., distort its export subsidies upward) to signal its type, which implies that the signaling effect strengthens the pre-commitment effect. This is opposite to our main result for \(k>1/2\), but it is qualitatively the same as the result of Collie and Hviid (1993).

  37. To obtain the signaling effect of emission standards mentioned here, we may have to incorporate firms’ use of (end-of-pipe) abatement technology into the current setting. If we consider binding emission standards but without abatement activities, each firm’s output level is directly determined by the emission standards of its own country and does not depend on its beliefs about the rival’s marginal production cost. Governments would then have no signaling incentive, even in the presence of asymmetric information between firms.

  38. Antoniou et al. (2010) examine whether the government and the firm within each country have incentives to share information about the demand size in a third market when governments regulate pollution either through emission taxes or emission standards. In their study, since the demand size is known by both domestic and foreign firms, there is no signaling effect of emission taxes or standards even when the government is informed about the demand size by its domestic firm.

  39. Note that \(\tau ^{L1}-X^L<\tau ^{H1}-X^H\) can also hold and, then, a tax rate within the interval \([\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) can also be the separating best response for the low-type government. However, as we show below, such best response cannot survive the refinement under the Intuitive Criterion.

  40. As for \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))\), in the proof of Case 1, we have dealt with the case of \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) = (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) together with the case of \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\). However, in what follows, we deal with the former case together with the case of \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) < (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\).

  41. \(dH^S(T)/dT|_{T=0}<1\) follows from the fact that \(dH^S(T)/dT|_{T=0}\) is increasing in \(\Delta \in (1,2)\) and \(\lambda \in (0,1)\) and \(\lim _{\Delta \rightarrow 2, \lambda \rightarrow 1}dH^S(T)/dT|_{T=0}=1/2\).

  42. As we explain below, (33) holds for \(t^* < \tau ^{H1}-Z^H\) or \(t^* > \tau ^{H1}+Z^H\), and our proof focuses on the latter case. For \(t^* > \tau ^{H1}+Z^H\), from Lemma B3, we obtain \(EW_i(t^*,c^H,1 ; t_j^{pool}) \ge EW_i(t^*,c^H,\mu _j ; t_j^{pool})\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\). Thus, if the high-type government chose \(t^* > \tau ^{H1}+Z^H\), \(\mu _j=1\) would be the most favorable inference by firm j for the government.

References

  • Antoniou F, Koundouri P, Tsakiris N (2010) Information sharing and environmental policies. Int J Environ Res Public Health 7(10):3561–3578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antoniou F, Hatzipanayotou P, Koundouri P (2012) Second best environmental policies under uncertainty. South Econ J 78(3):1019–1040

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barigozzi F, Villeneuve B (2006) The signaling effect of tax policy. J Public Econ Theory 8(4):611–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) Strategic environmental policy and international trade. J Public Econ 54(3):325–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard SL, Martimort D (1997) Strategic trade policy with incompletely informed policymakers. J Int Econ 42(1):33–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander JA, Spencer BJ (1985) Export subsidies and international market share rivalry. J Int Econ 18(1):83–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caminal R (1990) A dynamic duopoly model with asymmetric information. J Ind Econ 38(3):315–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho I, Kreps DM (1987) Signaling games and stable equilibria. Q J Econ 102(2):179–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collie D, Hviid M (1993) Export subsidies as signals of competitiveness. Scand J Econ 95(3):327–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad K (1993) Taxes and subsidies for pollution-intensive industries as trade policy. J Environ Econ Manag 25(2):121–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daughety AF, Reinganum JF (2008) Imperfect competition and quality signalling. RAND J Econ 39(1):163–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espínola-Arredondo A, Muñoz-García F (2013) When does environmental regulation facilitate entry-deterring practices. J Environ Econ Manag 65(1):133–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espínola-Arredondo A, Muñoz-García F, Bayham J (2014) The entry-deterring effects of inflexible regulation. Can J Econ 47(1):298–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Millimet DL (2002) Strategic interaction and the determination of environmental policy across US states. J Urban Econ 51(1):101–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton SF, Requate T (2004) Vertical structure and strategic environmental trade policy. J Environ Econ Manag 47(2):260–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy PW (1994) Equilibrium pollution taxes in open economies with imperfect competition. J Environ Econ Manag 27(1):49–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Gerking S (2000) Regulatory federalism and environmental protection in the United States. J Reg Sci 40(3):453–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mailath GJ (1989) Simultaneous signaling in an oligopoly model. Q J Econ 104(2):417–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet DL (2003) Assessing the empirical impact of environmental federalism. J Reg Sci 43(4):711–733

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muñoz-García F, Espínola-Arredondo A (2015) The signaling role of subsidies. BE J Econ Anal Policy 15(1):157–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Nannerup N (1998) Strategic environmental policy under incomplete information. Environ Resour Econ 11(1):61–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qui LD (1994) Optimal strategic trade policy under asymmetric information. J Int Econ 36(3):333–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singapore, Ministry of Finance (2017) Budget 2017: moving forward together. http://www.singaporebudget.gov.sg/budget_2017/. Accessed 15 Oct 2017

  • Ulph A (1996) Environmental policy and international trade when governments and producers act strategically. J Environ Econ Manag 30(3):265–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2016) State and trends of carbon pricing. World Bank Group, Washington. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/598811476464765822/State-and-trends-of-carbon-pricing. Accessed 15 Oct 2017

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Akira Miyaoka.

Additional information

I especially thank Keisuke Hattori, Keisaku Higashida, Junichiro Ishida, Shingo Ishiguro, Masayo Kani, Taketo Kawagishi, Noriaki Matsushima, Hirokazu Mizobata, Takayoshi Shinkuma, Toru Takemoto, Kenji Takeuchi, and participants at Contract Theory Workshop, the annual conference of Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, and seminars at Kobe University, Osaka University, and Tezukayama University for helpful discussions and comments. I also thank the editor and two anonymous referees for constructive comments and suggestions. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS KAKENHI 16J00067). The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendices

Proof of Lemma 1

In the non-signaling equilibrium, by taking the first-order condition of (5) with respect to \(t_i\) and rearranging it, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} t_i= & {} \lambda k q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^L\big ),c^L\big )+(1-\lambda )k q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^H\big ),c^H\big ) \nonumber \\&-\,\frac{1}{2}\big [\lambda q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^L\big ),c^L\big )+(1-\lambda )q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^H\big ),c^H\big )\big ], \end{aligned}$$
(15)

which can be further rearranged as (6). In the right-hand side of (15), the first two terms represent the expected marginal damage from pollution and the last term represents the government’s strategic incentive to lower its emission tax rate (i.e., the pre-commitment effect). In the symmetric equilibrium with \(t_A(c^m)=t_B(c^m)=t^N(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), the equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^N)\), is given as a solution to \(E(t^N)=\lambda R^{N}(c^L;E(t^N))+(1-\lambda )R^{N}(c^H;E(t^N))\); thus, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} E(t^N)=\frac{(2k-1)(a-\bar{c})}{2k+5}. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

By substituting \(c_i=c^m\) and \(E(t_j)=E(t^N)\) into (6), we obtain (7).

Next, in the Pigouvian equilibrium, government i chooses the tax rate such that

$$\begin{aligned} t_i=\lambda k q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^L\big ),c^L\big )+(1-\lambda ) k q_i\big (t_i, c_i; t_j\big (c^H\big ),c^H\big ). \end{aligned}$$

This can be rewritten as the following best-response tax rate for government i:

$$\begin{aligned} R^P(c_i;E(t_j))=\frac{k(a-2c_i+\bar{c}+E(t_j))}{2k+3}. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

In the symmetric equilibrium with \(t_A(c^m)=t_B(c^m)=t^P(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), the equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^P)\), is given as a solution to \(E(t^P)=\lambda R^P(c^L; E(t^P))+(1-\lambda )R^P(c^H; E(t^P))\); thus, we obtain \(E(t^P)=k(a-\bar{c})/(k+3)\). By substituting \(c_i=c^m\) and \(E(t_j)=E(t^P)\) into (17), we obtain (8).

Furthermore, since \(R^N(c^m;E(t_j))-R^P(c^m;E(t_j))=-3(a-2c^m+\bar{c}+E(t_j))/[4(k+1)(2k+3)]<0\) for \(m=L,H\) and \(E(t^N)-E(t^P)=-3(a-\bar{c})/[(k+3)(2k+5)]<0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} t^N(c^m)=R^N(c^m;E(t^N))<R^P(c^m;E(t^N))<R^P(c^m;E(t^P))=t^P(c^m), \quad m=L,H. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, the exact expressions for the expected welfare in the non-signaling and Pigouvian equilibria, \(EW^N(c^m)\) and \(EW^P(c^m)\) for \(m=L,H\) respectively, are given by

$$\begin{aligned} EW^e(c^m)&=\lambda \left[ \left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^L+t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^L)}{3}\right) \left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^L-2t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^L)}{3}\right) \right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \left. -\,\frac{k}{2}\left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^L-2t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^L)}{3}\right) ^2\right] \nonumber \\&\qquad +\,(1-\lambda )\left[ \left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^H+t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^H)}{3}\right) \right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \times \left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^H-2t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^H)}{3}\right) \nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad \quad \left. -\,\frac{k}{2}\left( \frac{a-2c^m+c^H-2t^e(c^m)+t^e(c^H)}{3}\right) ^2\right] \end{aligned}$$

for \(e=N,P\) and \(m=L,H\), where \(t^e(\cdot )\) is given by (7) or (8).

Proofs of Lemma 2 and Proposition 1

The proofs consist of the following steps. First, supposing that government j employs tax rule \(t_j(c_j)\) with \(t_j(c^L) \ne t_j(c^H)\), we derive a best-response function for each type of government i, \(R^S(c^m;E(t_j))\), \(m=L,H\), that reflects the need to signal its type (Sect. B.1). Next, using the obtained best-response functions, we verify that there always exists a unique equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^S)\) (Sect. B.2). Then, to complete the proofs of Lemma 2 and Proposition 1, we derive the equilibrium emission tax rates, \(t^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), and verify that the strategies and beliefs do provide a separating equilibrium for two separate cases (Sects. B.3 and B.4). Finally, we show that all pooling equilibria are eliminated under the refinement of the Intuitive Criterion (Sect. B.5).

1.1 Derivation of the Best-Response Functions

Suppose that government j plays the separating strategy \(t_j(c_j)\) with \(t_j(c^L) \ne t_j(c^H)\). In this proof, for notational simplicity, we abbreviate \(EW_i(t_i, c_i, \mu _j(t_i) ; t_j(c^L),t_j(c^H))\) as \(EW_i(t_i, c_i, \mu _j)\).

If there were no signaling considerations, \(EW_i(t_i, c^m, 1)\) and \(EW_i(t_i, c^m, 0)\) would be maximized, respectively, at

$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^{m1}(E(t_j))&=\frac{(2k-1)(2a-3c^m-c^L+2\bar{c}+2E(t_j))}{8(k+1)}, \quad m=L,H, \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^{m0}(E(t_j))&=\frac{(2k-1)(2a-3c^m-c^H+2\bar{c}+2E(t_j))}{8(k+1)}, \quad m=L,H, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

where \(E(t_j)=\lambda t_j(c^L)+(1-\lambda )t_j(c^H)\). From Assumption 1, we obtain \(\tau ^{L1}>\tau ^{L0}>\tau ^{H1}>\tau ^{H0}\).

Note first that \(EW_i(t_i, c_i, \mu _j)\) is not necessarily monotonic with respect to \(\mu _j\), because

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial EW_i(t_i, c_i, \mu _j)}{\partial \mu _j}=\frac{c^H-c^L}{36}&\left\{ (2-k)\left[ 2a-3c_i-(\mu _j c^L+(1-\mu _j)c^H)+2\bar{c}+2E(t_j)\right] \right. \nonumber \\&+2(2k-1)t_i \Bigr \} \end{aligned}$$
(20)

is always non-negative when \(k \le 2\) but can be either positive or negative when \(k > 2\). We here focus on \(EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)\), \(m=L,H\), and obtain the following lemma.

Lemma B1

\(min_{\mu _j}EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)=min\{EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,1), EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,0)\}\), \(m=L,H\).

Proof

When \(k\le 2\), (20) implies that \(\partial EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)/\partial \mu _j\) is always positive. Then, \(EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)\) is increasing in \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\) and reaches its minimum at \(\mu _j=0\). When \(k>2\), \(EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)\) is concave with respect to \(\mu _j\) because \(\partial ^2 EW_i/\partial \mu _j^2=-(k-2)(c^H-c^L)^2/36<0\). Thus, \(EW_i(\tau ^{m0},c^m,\mu _j)\) reaches its minimum either at \(\mu _j=1\) or at \(\mu _j=0\). \(\square \)

For \(m=H\), by comparing \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 1)\) and \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 0)\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i\big (\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 1\big )&\gtreqless EW_i\big (\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 0\big ) \\&\Longleftrightarrow a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j)\\&\gtreqless \frac{1}{9}\big (c^H-c^L\big )(k+1)(k-2). \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, in the following analysis, we consider two possible cases separately.

Case 1\(a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\).

In this case, \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 1) > EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 0)\) and Lemma B1 implies that \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,\mu _j) \ge EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,0)\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\). We first show that the best response for the high-type government is \(R^S(c^H;E(t_j))=\tau ^{H0}\) in the separating equilibrium. Suppose instead that the government chose \(\tilde{t} \ne \tau ^{H0}\) and obtained \(EW_i(\tilde{t},c^H,0)\) in the equilibrium. Then, if the government deviated to \(\tau ^{H0}\), it would be strictly better off whatever belief firm j has after observing such a deviation, because \(EW_i(\tilde{t},c^H,0)<EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,0) \le EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,\mu _j)\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\), where the first inequality follows because \(\tau ^{H0} = \arg \max _{t_i} EW_i(t_i,c^H,0)\). Hence, \(\tilde{t} \ne \tau ^{H0}\) cannot be an equilibrium best response for the high-type government and \(R^S(c^H;E(t_j))=\tau ^{H0}\) must hold in the equilibrium.

Next, we consider the best response for the low-type government in the separating equilibrium, \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))\). We first show the following lemma.

Lemma B2

\(min_{\mu _j}EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,\mu _j)=EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,0)\) when \(a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\).

Proof

By Lemma B1, \(\min _{\mu _j}EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,\mu _j)\!=\!\min \{EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,1), EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,0)\}\), where \(EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,1) > EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,0)\) if and only if \(a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(2k^2-2k-31)/18\). Since \((c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9>(c^H-c^L)(2k^2-2k-31)/18\), we obtain \(\min _{\mu _j}EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,\mu _j)=EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,0)\) when \(a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\). \(\square \)

This lemma implies that, by choosing \(\tau ^{L0}\), the low-type government can attain at least \(EW_i(\tau ^{L0},c^L,0)\) even under the most unfavorable belief by the foreign firm. Thus, in the separating equilibrium, the best-response tax rate \(t_i\) for the low-type government must satisfy the following two conditions:

$$\begin{aligned}&EW_i\big (t_i,c^L,1\big ) \ge EW_i\big (\tau ^{L0},c^L,0\big ), \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned}&EW_i\big (\tau ^{H0},c^H,0\big ) \ge EW_i\big (t_i,c^H,1\big ). \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Equation (21) states that the low-type government prefers to set \(t_i\) and be perceived as a low type rather than allow itself to be perceived as a high type and revert to \(\tau ^{L0}\). Equation (22) states that the high-type government prefers to set \(\tau ^{H0}\) and be perceived as a high type rather than set \(t_i\) and pretend to be a low type.

Equation (21) can be rewritten as \(\tau ^{L1}-X^L \le t_i \le \tau ^{L1}+X^L\), where

$$\begin{aligned} X^L(E(t_j))=\frac{3\sqrt{(c^H-c^L)(4a-7c^L-c^H+4\bar{c}+4E(t_j))}}{8(k+1)}>0, \end{aligned}$$

and (22) can be rewritten as \(t_i \le \tau ^{H1}-X^H\) or \(t_i \ge \tau ^{H1}+X^H\), where

$$\begin{aligned} X^H(E(t_j))=\frac{3\sqrt{(c^H-c^L)(4a-c^L-7c^H+4\bar{c}+4E(t_j))}}{8(k+1)}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\tau ^{L1}>\tau ^{H1}\) and \(X^L>X^H\), we have \(\tau ^{L1}+X^L>\tau ^{H1}+X^H\). Thus, the separating best response for the low-type government must belong to the interval \([\tau ^{H1}+X^H, \tau ^{L1}+X^L]\).Footnote 39 In Fig. 4, this interval is shown by the bold line along the horizontal axis.

Fig. 4
figure 4

\(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\). a\(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) \ge (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\). b\((c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9< a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) < (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\)

Now, by applying the Intuitive Criterion, we refine this set of equilibrium best responses for the low-type government. First, we show the next lemma.

Lemma B3

\(EW_i(t_i,c^H,\mu _j)\) is increasing in \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\) when \(t_i \ge \tau ^{H1}\).

Proof

From (20), we can infer that \(\partial ^2 EW_i(t_i,c^H,\mu _j)/\partial t_i \partial \mu _j=(c^H-c^L)(2k-1)/18>0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial EW_i\left( \tau ^{H1},c^H,\mu _j\right) }{\partial \mu _j} = \frac{c^H-c^L}{144(k+1)}&\left\{ (2k-1)^2(1-\mu _j)(c^H-c^L)\right. \\&+9\left[ 2a-4c^H+2\bar{c}+\mu _j (c^H\!-\!c^L)+2E(t_j)\right] \Bigr \}\!>\!0. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(\partial EW_i(t_i,c^H,\mu _j)/\partial \mu _j>0\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\) and \(t_i \ge \tau ^{H1}\). \(\square \)

Then, for any \(t_i> \tau ^{H1}+X^H(> \tau ^{H1})\) and \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\), we can infer that

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,0)>EW_i(t_i,c^H,1) \ge EW_i(t_i,c^H,\mu _j), \end{aligned}$$

where the first inequality follows because (22) holds with strict inequality for \(t_i > \tau ^{H1}+X^H\), and the second inequality follows from Lemma B3. This implies that the high-type government could never be made better off by deviating from \(\tau ^{H0}\) to \(t_i > \tau ^{H1}+X^H\) irrespective of firm j’s belief after observing such a deviation.

Then, we show that under the Intuitive Criterion, the equilibrium best response for the low-type government is \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))=\max \{\tau ^{H1}+X^H, \tau ^{L1}\}\), where

$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^{H1}+X^H \gtreqless \tau ^{L1} \ \ \Longleftrightarrow \ \ a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) \gtreqless (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k). \end{aligned}$$
(23)

We first consider the case when \(\tau ^{H1}+X^H \ge \tau ^{L1}\), or equivalently \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) \ge (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) (see Fig. 4a). Suppose that the low-type government chose \(\tilde{t} \in (\tau ^{H1}+X^H,\tau ^{L1}+X^L]\) and obtained \(EW_i(\tilde{t},c^L,1)\) in the equilibrium. Then, for any \(\tilde{\tilde{t}} \in (\tau ^{H1}+X^H,\tilde{t})\), the high-type government could never be better off by deviating from \(\tau ^{H0}\) to \(\tilde{\tilde{t}}\), as discussed above. By contrast, since \(EW_i(t_i,c^L,1)\) is decreasing for \(t_i >\tau ^{H1}+X^H (\ge \tau ^{L1})\), the low-type government could be better off by deviating from \(\tilde{t}\) to \(\tilde{\tilde{t}}\) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=1\) on observing such a deviation. Hence, the equilibrium with \(\tilde{t} \in (\tau ^{H1}+X^H,\tau ^{L1}+X^L]\) violates the Intuitive Criterion, and, thus, the best response for the low-type government must be \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))=\tau ^{H1}+X^H\) in the equilibrium.

We next consider the case when \(\tau ^{H1}+X^H < \tau ^{L1}\), or equivalently (\((c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9<\)) \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) < (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) (see Fig. 4b). Suppose that the low-type government chose \(\tilde{t} \in [\tau ^{H1}+X^H,\tau ^{L1}+X^L]{\setminus } \{\tau ^{L1}\}\) and obtained \(EW_i(\tilde{t},c^L,1)\) in the equilibrium. Note that, since \(\tau ^{L1}>\tau ^{H1}+X^H\), the high-type government could never be better off by deviating from \(\tau ^{H0}\) to \(\tau ^{L1}\), as discussed above. By contrast, since \(\tau ^{L1} = \arg \max _{t_i}EW_i(t_i,c^L,1)\), the low-type government could be better off by deviating from \(\tilde{t}\) to \(\tau ^{L1}\) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=1\) on observing such a deviation. Hence, the equilibrium with \(\tilde{t} \in [\tau ^{H1}+X^H,\tau ^{L1}+X^L]{\setminus } \{\tau ^{L1}\}\) violates the Intuitive Criterion, and, thus, the best response for the low-type government must be \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))=\tau ^{L1}\) in the equilibrium.

Finally, we show that even when \([\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) is not empty, any equilibrium where the low-type government chooses \(\tilde{t} \in [\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) violates the Intuitive Criterion. Since \(EW_i(t_i,c^L,1)\) is a quadratic function with its maximum at \(t_i=\tau ^{L1}\), we have \(EW_i(\tau ^{H1}-X^H,c^L,1)=EW_i(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H),c^L,1)\). Moreover, since \(\tau ^{H1}-X^H<\tau ^{L1}\) and \(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)>\tau ^{L1}\), \(EW_i(t_i,c^L,1)\) is increasing in \(t_i \in [\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) and decreasing in \(t_i\) at \(t_i=2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)\). Then, for any \(\tilde{t} \in [\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) and an infinitesimally small number \(\epsilon \), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(\tilde{t},c^L,1)&\le EW_i(\tau ^{H1}-X^H,c^L,1) \nonumber \\&=EW_i(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H),c^L,1)\nonumber \\&<EW_i(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)-\epsilon ,c^L,1). \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Note that, since \(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)-\epsilon >\tau ^{H1}+X^H\), the high-type government never prefers to deviate from \(\tau ^{H0}\) to \(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)-\epsilon \), as discussed above. By contrast, (24) implies that the low-type government prefers to deviate from \(\tilde{t}\) to \(2\tau ^{L1}-(\tau ^{H1}-X^H)-\epsilon \) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=1\) on observing such a deviation. Hence, we can conclude that any equilibrium with \(\tilde{t} \in [\tau ^{L1}-X^L, \tau ^{H1}-X^H]\) violates the Intuitive Criterion.

Case 2\(a-2c^H+\bar{c}+E(t_j) \le (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\).

In this case, \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 1) \le EW_i(\tau ^{H0}, c^H, 0)\). Let \(\bar{t}\) denote the best response of the high-type government in the separating equilibrium, that is, \(R^S(c^H;E(t_j))=\bar{t}\). Let us denote the larger solution of \(EW_i(\bar{t},c^H,0)=EW_i(t_i,c^H,1)\) with respect to \(t_i\) by \(\tau ^{H1}+Y\) with \(Y>0\). Then, the high-type government could never be better off by deviating from \(\bar{t}\) to \(t_i > \tau ^{H1}+Y\) irrespective of firm j’s belief after observing such a deviation, because for any \(t_i > \tau ^{H1}+Y\) and \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\),

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(\bar{t},c^H,0) = EW_i(\tau ^{H1}+Y,c^H,1) > EW_i(t_i,c^H,1) \ge EW_i(t_i,c^H,\mu _j), \end{aligned}$$

where the second inequality follows because \(EW_i(t_i,c^H,1)\) is decreasing for \(t_i \ge \tau ^{H1}\) and the last inequality follows from Lemma B3. Moreover, we have the following lemma.

Lemma B4

\(\tau ^{L1}>\tau ^{H1}+Y\).

Proof

Note first that \(EW_i(\bar{t},c^H,0) \ge EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,1)\) must hold in the equilibrium. This is because Lemma B1 implies that \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,\mu _j) \ge EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,1)\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\) in the current Case 2; thus, the high-type government can always attain at least \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,1)\) by choosing \(\tau ^{H0}\). Moreover, since \(EW_i(t_i,c^H,1)\) is a quadratic function with its maximum at \(t_i=\tau ^{H1}\), we have \(EW_i(\tau ^{H1}+(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0}),c^H,1)=EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,1)\) (see Fig. 5). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(\tau ^{H1}+(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0}),c^H,1)= & {} EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^H,1)\\\le & {} EW_i(\bar{t},c^H,0)=EW_i(\tau ^{H1}+Y,c^H,1). \end{aligned}$$

Thus, given that \(EW_i(t_i,c^H,1)\) is decreasing for \(t_i \ge \tau ^{H1}\), we have \(\tau ^{H1}+Y \le \tau ^{H1}+(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0})\). By using this condition, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \tau ^{H1}+Y \le \tau ^{H1}+(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0})<\tau ^{L0}+(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0})=\tau ^{L0}+(\tau ^{L1}-\tau ^{L0})=\tau ^{L1}, \end{aligned}$$

where the third equality follows from \(\tau ^{H1}-\tau ^{H0}=\tau ^{L1}-\tau ^{L0}=(2k-1)(c^H-c^L)/(8(k+1))\). \(\square \)

Fig. 5
figure 5

\(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) \le (c^H-c^L)(k+1)(k-2)/9\)

Thus, the high-type government never prefers to deviate from \(\bar{t}\) to \(\tau ^{L1}\). Then, we can show that, under the Intuitive Criterion, the best response for the low-type government must be \(R^S(c^L;E(t_j))=\tau ^{L1}\) in the equilibrium. Suppose instead that the government chose \(\tilde{t} \ne \tau ^{L1}\) and obtained \(EW_i(\tilde{t},c^L,1)\). Then, since \(\tau ^{L1} = \arg \max _{t_i}EW_i(t_i,c^L,1)\), the low-type government would prefer to deviate from \(\tilde{t}\) to \(\tau ^{L1}\) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=1\) on observing such a deviation. Hence, any equilibrium with \(\tilde{t} \ne \tau ^{L1}\) violates the Intuitive Criterion.

Finally, we show that, under the Intuitive Criterion, \(R^S(c^H;E(t_j))=\bar{t}=\tau ^{H0}\) must hold for the high-type government in the equilibrium. We first show the following lemma.

Lemma B5

\(EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^L,\mu _j) < EW_i(\tau ^{L1},c^L,1)\) for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\).

Proof

Let us define \(\tau ^L(\mu _j)\equiv \arg \max _{t_i}EW_i(t_i,c^L,\mu _j)=(2k-1)[2a-3c^L-(\mu _j c^L+(1-\mu _j)c^H)+2\bar{c}+2E(t_j)]/(8k+8)\). Then, \(EW_i(\tau ^{H0},c^L,\mu _j) < EW_i(\tau ^L(\mu _j),c^L,\mu _j) \le EW_i(\tau ^{L1},c^L,1)\) holds for any \(\mu _j \in [0,1]\), where the first strict inequality follows from \(\tau ^L(\mu _j) \ne \tau ^{H0}\) and the second inequality follows from \(dEW_i(\tau ^L(\mu _j),c^L,\mu _j)/d\mu _j=\tau ^L(\mu _j)(c^H-c^L)/(4k-2)>0\) and \(\tau ^L(1)=\tau ^{L1}\). \(\square \)

This lemma implies that the low-type government could never be better off by deviating from \(\tau ^{L1}\) to \(\tau ^{H0}\) whatever belief firm j has after observing such a deviation. Now, suppose that the high-type government chose \(\bar{t} \ne \tau ^{H0}\) and obtained \(EW_i(\bar{t},c^H,0)\) in the equilibrium. Then, since \(\tau ^{H0} = \arg \max _{t_i}EW_i(t_i,c^H,0)\), the government would prefer to deviate to \(\tau ^{H0}\) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=0\) on observing such a deviation. Hence, any equilibrium with \(\bar{t} \ne \tau ^{H0}\) violates the Intuitive Criterion.

Summarizing the results of Cases 1 and 2, we can conclude that the best response in the separating equilibrium for each type of government is as follows:Footnote 40

$$\begin{aligned} R^S(c^L;E(t_j))&= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \tau ^{H1}(E(t_j))+X^H(E(t_j)) \ \ &{}\text {if} \ \ \ a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k), \\ \tau ^{L1}(E(t_j)) \ \ &{}\text {if} \ \ \ a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t_j) \le (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k), \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} R^S(c^H;E(t_j))&=\tau ^{H0}(E(t_j)). \end{aligned}$$
(26)

1.2 Existence and Uniqueness of the Equilibrium Expected Tax Rate

In the symmetric equilibrium with \(t_A(c^m)=t_B(c^m)=t^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), the equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^S)\), is a solution to the following equation with respect to T:

$$\begin{aligned} T=\lambda R^S(c^L;T)+(1-\lambda ) R^S(c^H;T), \end{aligned}$$
(27)

where \(R^S(c^L;T)\) and \(R^S(c^H;T)\) are respectively given by (25) and (26) with \(E(t_j)=T\). Let us define \(H^S(T) \equiv \lambda (\tau ^{H1}(T)+X^H(T))+(1-\lambda ) \tau ^{H0}(T)\) and \(H^N(T)\equiv \lambda \tau ^{L1}(T)+(1-\lambda ) \tau ^{H0}(T)\). Then, (27) can be rewritten as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} T= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} H^S(T) \ \ &{}\text {if} \ \ \ a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k), \\ H^N(T) \ \ &{}\text {if} \ \ \ a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T \le (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k). \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Since (23) implies that \(H^S(T) = H^N(T)\) holds when \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T = (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\), the right-hand side of (28) is continuous. Note also that \(H^S(0)>0\) and since

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dH^S(T)}{dT}=\frac{2k-1}{4k+4}+\frac{3\lambda }{4k+4}\sqrt{\frac{1}{1-4\lambda +\frac{4}{\Delta -1}+\frac{4T}{c^H-c^L}}}>0, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Delta \equiv (a-c^L)/(a-c^H)\), we obtain \(dH^S(T)/dT|_{T=0}<1\) and \(d^2H^{S}(T)/dT^2<0\).Footnote 41 Similarly, \(H^N(0)>0\) and \(dH^N(T)/dT=(2k-1)/(4k+4)<1\). Hence, these properties imply that (28) always has a unique solution. In the following two sections, we solve (28) and derive the equilibrium expected tax rate.

1.3 Proof of the Statement of Lemma 2

Suppose that the equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^S)\), satisfies \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t^S) \le (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) and, thus, the best response for each type of government is given by \(R^S(c^L;E(t^S))=\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))\) and \(R^S(c^H;E(t^S))=\tau ^{H0}(E(t^S))\) from (25) and (26). Then, \(E(t^S)\) must be a solution of \(T=H^N(T)\) in (28), which yields

$$\begin{aligned} T^N=\frac{(2k-1)(a-\bar{c})}{2k+5}. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Note that this is a valid and unique solution of (28) if \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T^N \le (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\), which can be rewritten as (11). As a result, under condition (11), the unique pair of equilibrium emission taxes is given by \(t^S(c^L)=\tau ^{L1}(T^N)\) and \(t^S(c^H)=\tau ^{H0}(T^N)\).

Note from (6) and (19) that \(\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))=R^{N}(c^L;E(t^S))\) and \(\tau ^{H0}(E(t^S))=R^{N}(c^H;E(t^S))\), and from (16) and (29) that \(T^N=E(t^N)\). Therefore, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} t^S(c^m)=\tau ^{mm}(T^N)=R^{N}(T^N,c^m)=R^{N}(E(t^N),c^m)=t^N(c^m), \quad m=L,H. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, suppose that government j plays the strategy \(t^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), as shown above, and that each firm maintains the beliefs \(\mu ^S(t)\) such that \(\mu ^S(t)=1\) for \(t \ge t^S(c^L)\) and \(\mu ^S(t)=0\) for \(t<t^S(c^L)\). Then, it is easy to verify that government i\((\ne j)\) would also be willing to play the strategy \(t^S(\cdot )\), and the beliefs \(\mu ^S(\cdot )\) are consistent with the governments’ strategy. Thus, we can conclude that the strategy and beliefs do provide a separating equilibrium.

1.4 Proof of the Statement of Proposition 1

Suppose that the equilibrium expected tax rate, \(E(t^S)\), satisfies \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + E(t^S) > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) and, thus, the best response for each type of government is given by \(R^S(c^L;E(t^S))=\tau ^{H1}(E(t^S))+X^H(E(t^S))\) and \(R^S(c^H;E(t^S))=\tau ^{H0}(E(t^S))\) from (25) and (26). Then, \(E(t^S)\) must be a solution of \(T=H^S(T)\) in (28), which yields

$$\begin{aligned} T^S=\frac{X+Y+3\lambda \sqrt{(c^H-c^L)\left[ 2X+Y+(2k+5)^2(4a-c^L-7c^H+4\bar{c})\right] }}{2(2k+5)^2}, \end{aligned}$$
(30)

where \(X=(2k-1)(2k+5)(2a-3c^H+\bar{c})\) and \(Y=9\lambda ^2(c^H-c^L)\). Note that this is a valid and unique solution of (28) if \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T^S > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\), which can be rewritten after some cumbersome algebra as (12). As a result, under condition (12), the unique pair of equilibrium emission taxes is given by \(t^S(c^L)=\tau ^{H1}(T^S)+X^H(T^S)\) and \(t^S(c^H)=\tau ^{H0}(T^S)\).

Then, (13) follows because

$$\begin{aligned} R^{S}(c^L;E(t^S))&=\tau ^{H1}(E(t^S))+X^H(E(t^S)) \\&=\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))+[\tau ^{H1}(E(t^S))+X^H(E(t^S))-\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))] \\&=R^{N}(c^L;E(t^S))+[\tau ^{H1}(E(t^S))+X^H(E(t^S))-\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))], \end{aligned}$$

where the bracketed term can be rearranged to yield the second term of the right-hand side of (13). Similarly, (14) follows from \(R^S(c^H;E(t^S))=\tau ^{H0}(E(t^S))=R^{N}(c^H;E(t^S))\). Moreover, as in the proof of Lemma 1, it is easy to verify that the strategy and beliefs, \(t^S(\cdot )\) and \(\mu ^S(\cdot )\), do provide a separating equilibrium.

Since condition (12) is equivalent to \(a - 2c^H + \bar{c} + T^S > (c^H-c^L)(k^2-k)\) as mentioned earlier, (23) implies that \(\tau ^{H1}(E(t^S))+X^H(E(t^S))-\tau ^{L1}(E(t^S))>0\) with \(E(t^S)=T^S\). Therefore, the second term of the right-hand side of (13) is also strictly positive; that is, \(R^S(c^L;E(t^S))>R^N(c^L;E(t^S))\) holds. Then, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} t^S(c^L)&=R^S(c^L;E(t^S))>R^N(c^L;E(t^S))>R^N(c^L;E(t^N))=t^N(c^L), \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} t^S(c^H)&=R^S(c^H;E(t^S))=R^N(c^H;E(t^S))>R^N(c^H;E(t^N))=t^N(c^H), \end{aligned}$$
(32)

where, in the third inequality in (31) and (32), we also used the fact that \(R^N(c^m;E(t_j))\) is strictly increasing in \(E(t_j)\) for \(m=L,H\).

Finally, note that the exact expression for the expected welfare in this signaling equilibrium, \(EW^S(c^m)\), \(m=L,H\), is given by (18) with \(t^e(\cdot )\) replaced by \(t^S(\cdot )\), as derived above.

1.5 Elimination of Pooling Equilibria

In a pooling equilibrium, both types of governments set the same tax rate in each country, that is, \(t_A(c^L)=t_A(c^H)=t_A^{pool}\) and \(t_B(c^L)=t_B(c^H)=t_B^{pool}\), and each firm infers that its rival’s marginal cost is \(c^L\) (\(c^H\)) with probability \(\lambda \) (\(1-\lambda \)). Note that such a pooling equilibrium fails the Intuitive Criterion if, given government j’s pooling strategy \(t_j(c^L)=t_j(c^H)=t_j^{pool}\), there exists a tax rate \(t^*\) for government i such that

$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(t^*,c^H,1 ; t_j^{pool})&< EW_i(t_i^{pool},c^H,\lambda ; t_j^{pool}), \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} EW_i(t^*,c^L,1 ; t_j^{pool})&> EW_i(t_i^{pool},c^L,\lambda ; t_j^{pool}). \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Equation (33) states that the high-type government could not be better off by deviating to \(t^*\) even if firm j had the most favorable inference, \(\mu _j=1\), on observing such a deviation.Footnote 42 By contrast, (34) states that the low-type government prefers to deviate to \(t^*\) if firm j reasonably infers that \(\mu _j=1\) since the high-type government never prefers such a deviation when (33) is satisfied. In the following proof, we show that, for any \(t_i^{pool}\) and \(t_j^{pool}\), there exists \(t^*\) such that (33) and (34) are both satisfied.

(33) can be rewritten as \(t^* < \tau ^{H1}-Z^H\) or \(t^* > \tau ^{H1}+Z^H\), where

$$\begin{aligned} Z^H=\sqrt{(\tau ^{H1}-t_i^{pool})^2+\frac{(\bar{c}-c^L)[(2-k)(4a-c^L-6c^H+3\bar{c}+4t_j^{pool})+4(2k-1)t_i^{pool}]}{16(k+1)}}>0, \end{aligned}$$

and (34) can be rewritten as \(\tau ^{L1}-Z^L< t^* < \tau ^{L1}+Z^L\), where

$$\begin{aligned} Z^L=\sqrt{(\tau ^{L1}-t_i^{pool})^2+\frac{(\bar{c}-c^L)[(2-k)(4a-7c^L+3\bar{c}+4t_j^{pool})+4(2k-1)t_i^{pool}]}{16(k+1)}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Below, we prove that \(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) holds for any \(t_i^{pool}\) and \(t_j^{pool}\).

Note that \(\tau ^{L1}>\tau ^{H1}\), and we can show that \(Z^L \gtreqless Z^H\) if and only if \(t_i^{pool} \lesseqgtr \bar{\tau }\), where

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\tau }=\frac{(2k-1)^2(4a-3c^L-3c^H+2\bar{c}+4t_j^{pool})+18(\bar{c}-c^L)}{16(k+1)(2k-1)}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, when \(t_i^{pool} \le \bar{\tau }\) and \(Z^L \ge Z^H\), we can easily infer that \(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) holds.

When \(t_i^{pool} > \bar{\tau }\) and \(Z^L < Z^H\), on the other hand, \(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) holds if and only if \((\tau ^{L1}-\tau ^{H1})^2-(Z^H-Z^L)^2\) is positive. The latter expression can be rearranged as

$$\begin{aligned} 2Z^HZ^L-[(Z^H)^2+(Z^L)^2-(\tau ^{L1}-\tau ^{H1})^2], \end{aligned}$$
(35)

where the sign of the bracketed term is ambiguous. If the bracketed term is non-positive, then (35) is positive and \(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) holds. If the term is positive, the sign of (35) is equivalent to that of \((2Z^HZ^L)^2-[(Z^H)^2+(Z^L)^2-(\tau ^{L1}-\tau ^{H1})^2]^2\), which can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{81(c^H-c^L)^2(\bar{c}-c^L)[4(2k-1)t_i^{pool}-(2-k)(\bar{c}-c^L)]}{256(k+1)^3}. \end{aligned}$$

This is positive if and only if \(t_i^{pool}>(2-k)(\bar{c}-c^L)/[4(2k-1)]\). Note that since

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\tau }-\frac{(2-k)(\bar{c}-c^L)}{4(2k-1)}=\frac{(2k-1)^2(4a-4c^L-3c^H+3\bar{c}+4t_j^{pool})+9(\bar{c}-c^L)}{16(k+1)(2k-1)}>0 \end{aligned}$$

and \(t_i^{pool}>\bar{\tau }\) in the present case, we obtain \(t_i^{pool}>\bar{\tau }>(2-k)(\bar{c}-c^L)/[4(2k-1)]\). Therefore, (35) is positive and \(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) holds.

\(\tau ^{L1}+Z^L>\tau ^{H1}+Z^H\) for any \(t_i^{pool}\) and \(t_j^{pool}\) implies that there always exists \(t^* \in (\tau ^{H1}+Z^H,\tau ^{L1}+Z^L)\), for which (33) and (34) are both satisfied. We can thus conclude that no pooling equilibrium exists under the refinement of the Intuitive Criterion.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Miyaoka, A. The Signaling Effect of Emission Taxes Under International Duopoly. Environ Resource Econ 72, 691–720 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0220-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0220-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation