Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Climate Policy with Technology Transfers and Permit Trading

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we analyze technology transfers (TT) and tradable emission rights, which are core issues of the ongoing climate negotiations. Subsidizing TT leads to the adoption of better abatement technologies in the South, thereby reducing the international permit price. This is beneficial for the North as long as it is a permit buyer; hence it chooses to subsidize TT. By contrast, the permit selling South suffers from the lower permit price and its welfare usually deteriorates, despite receiving subsidies. We also consider how TT affects countries’ non-cooperative choices of permit endowments and find that it tends to reduce overall emissions. Finally, a simple numerical simulation model illustrates the results and explores some further comparative statics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g., http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/linking/index_en.htm.

  2. Another difference is that Greaker and Hagem (2013) assume specific functional forms which enables them to calculate closed form solutions.

  3. The assumption could easily be dropped, but some of the following results would then require a case distinction—a complication that we want to avoid.

  4. For example, this assumption is satisfied for a multiplicative specification \(f\left( k_{i}\right) c_{i} \left( x_{i}\right) \), where \(f^{\prime }\left( k_{i}\right) <0\) (see Montero 2002). Baker et al. (2008) contains a more general discussion of marginal abatement cost and technical change, which also includes other assumptions.

  5. For example, \(\gamma _{S}\) maybe a rent that has to be paid to the bureaucracy. Alternatively, the difference between the private and social costs of technology investments may result from technology spillovers to other local firms.

  6. For all figures, we subtract a constant from the solution of some variables in order to facilitate their presentation. For this diagram, \(\hat{x}_{N}=x_{N}-1, \hat{\omega }_{S}=\omega _{S}-1, \hat{\omega }=\omega -1\) and \(\hat{W}=W^{en}+25.5\).

  7. Formally, the first effect is driven by the term \(\sigma _{S}k_{S}^{\prime }(\omega )\) in Eq. (20), and the second by the terms \(p^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) (\omega _{S}-x_{S})\) and \(p^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) (\omega _{N}-x_{N})\) in Eqs. (19) and (20).

  8. Analytically, \(\omega _{S}^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) \) follows from applying the implicit function theorem to the equilibrium conditions (19) and (20) for endowment choices (after substituting for \(p'(\omega )\) and \(k_S'(\omega )\) from Eq. 18). Hence the outcome depends in a complex way on third-order derivatives.

  9. For this diagram, \(\hat{\sigma }_{S}=\sigma _{S}-0.4\), \(\Delta _1\hat{W}_S=\Delta _1W_S-1.4\) and \(\Delta _1\hat{W}_N=\Delta _1W_N-1.4\).

References

  • Aldy JE, Krupnick AJ, Newell RG, Parry IWH, Pizer WA (2010) Designing climate mitigation policy. J Econ Lit 48(4):903–934

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker E, Clarke L, Shittu E (2008) Technical change and the marginal cost of abatement. Energy Econ 30(6):2799–2816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (2001) Cooperation for sale. Eur Econ Rev 45:1835–1850

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati JN (1982) Directly unproductive, profit-seeking (DUP) activities. J Polit Econ 90(5):988–1002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer C, Conrad K, Löschel A (2003) Carbon taxes and joint implementation: An applied general equilibrium analysis for Germany and India. Environ Resour Econ 24(1):49–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchholz W, Konrad K (1994) Global environmental problems and the strategic choice of technology. J Econ 60(3):299–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comin D, Hobija B (2010) An exploration of technology diffusion. Am Econ Rev 100(5):2031–2059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechezleprêtre A, Glachant M, Haščič I, Johnstone N, Ménière Y (2011) Invention and transfer of climate change-mitigation technologies: a global analysis. Rev Environ Econ Policy 5(1):109–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douglas S, Nishioka S (2012) International differences in emissions intensity and emissions content of global trade. J Dev Econ 99(2):415–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass AJ, Saggi K (1998) International technology transfer and the technology gap. J Dev Econ 55(2):369–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golombek R, Hoel M (2004) Unilateral emission reductions and cross-country technology spillovers. B E J Econ Anal Policy 4 (2), Article 3

  • Greaker M, Hagem C (2013) Strategic investment in climate friendly technologies: the impact of global emissions trading. Environ Resour Econ 1–21

  • Helm C (2003) International emissions trading with endogenous allowance choices. J Public Econ 87(12):2737–2747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoekman B, Maskus K, Saggi K (2005) Transfer of technology to developing countries: unilateral and multilateral policy options. World Dev 33(10):1587–1602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King D (2004) Climate change science: adapt, mitigate, or ignore? Science 303(5655):176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson A (2009) Technology, international trade, and pollution from US manufacturing. Am Econ Rev 99(5):2177–2192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metz B, Davidson O, Bosch P, Dave R, Meyer L (2007) Climate change 2007: mitigation. Contribution of working group III to the fourth assessment report of the IPCC

  • Montero J-P (2002) Permits, standards, and technology innovation. J Environ Econ Manag 44(1):23–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundial B (2011) World development indicators. The Wold Bank, IEC information Center, Development data group

  • Requate T, Unold W (2003) Environmental policy incentives to adopt advanced abatement technology: Will the true ranking please stand up? Eur Econ Rev 47(1):125–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider L (2009) Assessing the additionality of CDM projects: practical experiences and lessons learned. Clim Policy 9(3):242–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seres S, Haites E, Murphy K (2009) Analysis of technology transfer in cdm projects: an update. Energy Policy 37(11):4919–4926

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund J (1996) On the strategic potential of technological aid in international environmental relations. J Econ 64(1):1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang Z (1999) Should the North make unilateral technology transfers to the South?: North–South cooperation and conflicts in responses to global climate change. Resour Energy Econ 21(1):67–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang Z, Nordhaus WD (2006) Magnitude and direction of technological transfers for mitigating GHG emissions. Energy Econ 28(5–6):730–741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Youngman R, Schmidt J, Lee J, De Coninck H (2007) Evaluating technology transfer in the clean development mechanism and joint implementation. Clim Policy 7(6):488–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J, Wang C (2011) Co-benefits and additionality of the clean development mechanism: an empirical analysis. J Environ Econ Manag 62(2):140–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carsten Helm.

Additional information

We would like to thank Ralph Winkler, Gunter Stephan, Mads Greaker, three anonymous referees and conference participants in Bern, Wageningen and Prague for useful comments.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A1: Proof of Proposition 1

From the comparative statics at the end of Sect. 3.2, \(p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) >0\) and \(k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) <0\). Accordingly, if the North is a permit seller or does not trade, then the left-hand side of (13) is non-positive and we have a boundary solution with \(\sigma _{S}=0\).

By contrast, if the North is a permit buyer, then \(-p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) (\omega _{N}-x_{N})>0\) so that a subsidy reduces its costs on the permit market. The subsidy payments depend on the degree of additionality. First, consider the case where subsidies can be fully restricted to additional investments, i.e., \(\tilde{k}_{S}=k_{S}^{0}\). By contradiction to statement (ii), suppose that \(\sigma _{S}=0\); hence \(k_{S}=k_{S}^{0}\) by definition of \(k_{S}^{0}\). In this case \(k_{S}-\tilde{k}_{S} +\sigma _{S}k_{S}^{\prime } (\pi _{S})=0\) so that the left-hand side of (13) is strictly positive. Therefore, \(\sigma _{S}=0\) can not be an optimal solution. Second, suppose that the North is not able to restrict subsidies to additional investments, i.e., \(\tilde{k}_{S}<k_{S}^{0}\). In this case \(k_{S}-\tilde{k}_{S}>0\) even at \(\sigma _{S}=0\). If this term is sufficiently large compared to the other terms in (13), then we may have a boundary solution with \(\sigma _{S}=0\) (statement iii). \(\square \)

1.2 A2: Proof of Proposition 3

For interior solutions with \(\sigma _{S}^{c}>0\), it follows immediately from the first-order condition (13) for subsidies—or, equivalently, from Proposition 1(i)— that \(\omega _{N}^{c}<x_{N}^{c}\). Turning to boundary solutions with \(\sigma _{S}^{c}=0\), remember that \(v_{N}^{\prime }(\omega ^{c}) >v_{S}^{\prime }(\omega ^{c})\) by assumption. Substituting from the first-order conditions for endowment choices, (20) and (19), thereby noting that \(\omega _{S}^{c}-x_{S}^{c}= -\left( \omega _{N}^{c} -x_{N}^{c}\right) \), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} 2p^{\prime }\left( \omega ^{c}\right) (\omega _{N}^{c}-x_{N}^{c})> \gamma _{S}{k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega ^{c}\right) .} \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Given that \(p^{\prime }\left( \omega ^{c}\right) <0\), this implies \(\omega _{N}^{c}<x_{N}^{c}\) for \(\gamma _{S}\) sufficiently small (while the outcome is ambiguous for large \(\gamma _{S}\) due to \(k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega ^{c}\right) \le 0\)). \(\square \)

1.3 A3: Proof of Proposition 4

We want to show that \(\omega \left( \sigma _{S}^{c}\right) -\omega \left( 0\right) <0\), where \(\omega \left( \sigma _{S}^{c}\right) \) and \(\omega \left( 0\right) \) are endowment choices that arise in the regimes with subsidies (\(\sigma _{S}=\sigma _{S}^{c}>0)\) and with no TT (\(\sigma _{S} =0\)). Given the lack of closed form solutions we can not directly compare these endowment levels. However,

$$\begin{aligned} \omega \left( \sigma _{S}^{c}\right) -\omega \left( 0\right) =\int \limits _{0}^{\sigma _{S}^{c}}\omega ^{\prime }\left( \sigma _{S}\right) d\sigma _{S}, \end{aligned}$$
(23)

where \(\omega ^{\prime }\left( \sigma _{S}\right) \) can be determined using the implicit function theorem. In particular, we treat \(\sigma _{S}\) as an exogenous variable and then track how \(\omega \) evolves as subsidies rise from \(\sigma _{S}=0\) to the equilibrium value \(\sigma _{S}^{c}\).

To determine \(\omega ^{\prime }\left( \sigma _{S}\right) \), summation of the first-order conditions for endowment choices, Eqs. (19) and (20), yields

$$\begin{aligned} 2p-\sigma _{S}k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) +\gamma _{S} {k_{S}^{\prime } \left( \omega \right) }-v_{N}^{\prime } (\omega )-v_{S}^{\prime }(\omega )=0, \end{aligned}$$
(24)

which implicitly defines \(\omega \) as a function of \(\sigma _{S}\). For high values of \(\omega \), we may have a boundary solution with \(k_{S}=\underline{k}_{S}\) and \({k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) =0}\). In this case, a marginal change in the subsidy level has no real effects and \(\frac{d\omega }{d\sigma _{S}}=0\).

By contrast, if \(\omega \) is sufficiently low, an interior solution with \(k_{S}>\underline{k}_{S}\) obtains. For this case, implicit differentiation of (24) yields (remember that \(d\pi _{S} /d\sigma _{S}={d\bar{\pi }_{S}/d\sigma _{S}=}-1\))

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\omega }{d\sigma _{S}}=\frac{2p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) +k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) -\left( \sigma _{S}-\gamma _{S}\right) \frac{\partial k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) }{\partial \pi _{S}}}{2p^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) -\left( \sigma _{S}-\gamma _{S}\right) k_{S}^{\prime \prime } \left( \omega \right) -v_{N}^{\prime \prime } (\omega )-v_{S}^{\prime \prime }(\omega )}, \end{aligned}$$
(25)

where the derivatives account for the effects of endowment choices and subsidies at the subsequent stages of the game. From the comparative statics (10) and (18) we have \(k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) =-p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) \) so that \(2p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) +k_{S}^{\prime } \left( \omega \right) =p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) \) and \(-\frac{\partial k_{S}^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) }{\partial \pi _{S}}=p^{\prime \prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) \). Upon substitution into (25)

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\omega }{d\sigma _{S}}=\frac{p^{\prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) +\left( \sigma _{S}-\gamma _{S}\right) p^{\prime \prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) }{2p^{\prime }\left( \omega \right) -\left( \sigma _{S}-\gamma _{S}\right) k_{S}^{\prime \prime }\left( \omega \right) -v_{N}^{\prime \prime }(\omega ) -v_{S}^{\prime \prime }(\omega )}. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Accordingly, the numerator of (25) is positive for all \(\sigma _{S}\) if \(p^{\prime \prime }\left( \pi _{S}\right) \) is not too small and \(\gamma _{S}\) is not too large. Moreover, the denominator is negative by the second-order conditions with respect to the regions’ endowment choices. To see this, note that these conditions require (using \(d\omega /d\omega _{i}=1\))

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{d\omega }\left( \frac{dW_{i}}{d\omega }\right) <0,\quad i=N,S. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Hence, summation yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{d\omega }\left( \frac{dW_{N}}{d\omega }\right) +\frac{d}{d\omega } \left( \frac{dW_{S}}{d\omega }\right) =\frac{d}{d\omega } \left( \frac{dW_{N}}{d\omega }+\frac{dW_{S}}{d\omega } \right) <0. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

In the above calculations, \(\frac{dW_{N}}{d\omega }+\frac{dW_{S}}{d\omega }\) is given by the l.h.s. of (24). The denominator of (26) is the derivative of this term with respect to \(\omega \), i.e. \(\frac{d}{d\omega }\left( \frac{dW_{N}}{d\omega }+\frac{dW_{S}}{d\omega } \right) <0\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Helm, C., Pichler, S. Climate Policy with Technology Transfers and Permit Trading. Environ Resource Econ 60, 37–54 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9756-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9756-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation