Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The influence of negative emission technologies and technology policies on the optimal climate mitigation portfolio

  • Published:
Climatic Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Combining policies to remove carbon dioxide (CO2) from the atmosphere with policies to reduce emissions could decrease CO2 concentrations faster than possible via natural processes. We model the optimal selection of a dynamic portfolio of abatement, research and development (R&D), and negative emission policies under an exogenous CO2 constraint and with stochastic technological change. We find that near-term abatement is not sensitive to the availability of R&D policies, but the anticipated availability of negative emission strategies can reduce the near-term abatement optimally undertaken to meet 2°C temperature limits. Further, planning to deploy negative emission technologies shifts optimal R&D funding from “carbon-free” technologies into “emission intensity” technologies. Making negative emission strategies available enables an 80% reduction in the cost of keeping year 2100 CO2 concentrations near their current level. However, negative emission strategies are less important if the possibility of tipping points rules out using late-century net negative emissions to temporarily overshoot the CO2 constraint earlier in the century.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The captured CO2 would be moved to geological sequestration absent another use or form of storage (e.g., Stephens and Keith 2008). Importantly, geological sequestration of CO2 can pose its own risks, and leakage can reduce the effectiveness of negative emission technologies (Benson et al. 2005; Damen et al. 2006; van der Zwaan and Gerlagh 2009). Other negative emission strategies include methods that use biological activity to sequester atmospheric CO2 (Read 2009; Woodward et al. 2009), such as applying biochar to soils (Lehmann 2007), sending crop residues to the deep ocean (Strand and Benford 2009), and fertilizing swathes of ocean to promote plankton blooms (Smetacek and Naqvi 2008; Strong et al. 2009).

  2. While Goulder and Mathai (2000) used induced technological change (ITC) to refer to the effect on future abatement technology of both abatement and direct public R&D support, we reserve ITC to refer only to the effect of abatement. We do not, however, restrict abatement to only affect technology via learning-by-doing.

  3. Our two channels are similar to the two-factor experience curves summarized by Clarke et al. (2008). We do not consider how knowledge spillovers might affect the balance between R&D and abatement policies in the presence of induced technological change (see Hart 2008; Greaker and Pade 2009).

  4. In a model with R&D, having multiple actors introduces the possibility of international spillovers, which tend to reduce equilibrium R&D investment (Bosetti et al. 2008). NETs might have complex effects with multiple actors. On the one hand, NETs introduce a means for one country to unilaterally take care of another's emissions, but on the other hand, they also increase the scope for free-riding on others' emission reductions.

  5. Available at: http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Research/GGI/DB/.

  6. Experiments using the lower BAU emissions from scenario B2 showed that our results are robust to assumptions about the BAU path. The difference between BAU emission paths can represent different assumptions about population growth, the distribution of worldwide economic growth, future consumption habits, and BAU low-carbon technology adoption.

  7. Keller et al. (2004) and Lemoine and Traeger (2010) modeled tipping points as affecting the climate system or climate damages in a future world. They considered the decision about whether to risk crossing a possibly uncertain threshold, whereas we here take it as given that a policymaker has decided not to cross a known threshold.

  8. The quantities of NETs deployed are within the range of estimates of underground global CO2 storage capacity (Benson et al. 2005). While NETs might not involve underground storage, captured CO2 from fossil fuel plants could also compete with captured CO2 from negative emission facilities for end uses or storage capacity.

  9. The main exceptions with public R&D commonly at 75% of the maximal level are: period 2 carbon-free R&D in scenarios with the 435 ppm CO2 constraint and unavailable NETs, period 2 emission intensity R&D in scenarios with NET options and cheap R&D or cheap abatement, and period 2 NET R&D in scenarios with the 435 or 390 ppm CO2 constraints.

  10. In the case that \(\hat{\alpha}_{t-1} + ITC_{\alpha}(\mu_{t-1}) > \bar{\alpha}\), we have \(Pr[\alpha_t=\bar{\alpha}] = (1-p_{\alpha})+p_{\alpha}\bar{\alpha}\), implying that either \(\alpha_t=\bar{\alpha}\) or α t  = α t − 1. An analogous caveat holds for the probability distribution for γ.

  11. More specifically, we develop the two marginal cost representations by assuming that: the carbon prices reported in Hoogwijk et al. (2008) represent the marginal cost of abatement; abatement of 25% has a marginal cost of $20/tCO2; abatement of 50% makes marginal costs either quintuple (base case) to $100/tCO2 or triple (low-cost case) to $60/tCO2; higher levels of abatement follow the same geometric progression; and the marginal cost of abating a given fraction of contemporary emissions is unaffected by previous periods' abatement except through modeled technological change.

References

  • Allen MR, Frame DJ, Huntingford C, Jones CD, Lowe JA, Meinshausen M, Meinshausen N (2009) Warming caused by cumulative carbon emissions towards the trillionth tonne. Nature 458(7242):1163–1166. doi:10.1038/nature08019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar C, Lindgren K, Larson E, Möllersten K (2006) Carbon capture and storage from fossil fuels and biomass—costs and potential role in stabilizing the atmosphere. Clim Change 74(1):47–79. doi:10.1007/s10584-005-3484-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar C, Lindgren K, Obersteiner M, Riahi K, van Vuuren D, den Elzen K, Möllersten K, Larson E (2010) The feasibility of low CO2 concentration targets and the role of bio-energy with carbon capture and storage (BECCS). Clim Change 100(1):195–202. doi:10.1007/s10584-010-9832-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker E, Adu-Bonnah K (2008) Investment in risky R&D programs in the face of climate uncertainty. Energy Econ 30(2):465–486. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2006.10.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker E, Shittu E (2008) Uncertainty and endogenous technical change in climate policy models. Energy Econ 30(6):2817–2828. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2007.10.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker E, Chon H, Keisler J (2009) Advanced solar R&D: combining economic analysis with expert elicitations to inform climate policy. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 1):S37–S49. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2007.10.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson S, Cook P, Anderson J, Bachu S, Nimir HB, Basu B, Bradshaw J, Deguchi G, Gale J, von Goerne G, Heidug W, Holloway S, Kamal R, Keith D, Lloyd P, Rocha P, Senior B, Thomson J, Torp T, Wildenborg T, Wilson M, Zarlenga F, Zhou D (2005) Underground geological storage. In: Metz B, Davidson O, de Coninck H, Loos M, Meyer L (eds) IPCC Special Report on Carbon Dioxide Capture and Storage. Prepared by Working Group III of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA, pp 195–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackstock JJ, Long JCS (2010) The politics of geoengineering. Science 327(5965):527. doi:10.1126/science.1183877

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blyth W, Bunn D, Kettunen J, Wilson T (2009) Policy interactions, risk and price formation in carbon markets. Energy Policy 37(12):5192–5207. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.07.042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Tavoni M (2009) Uncertain R&D, backstop technology and GHGs stabilization. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 1):S18–S26. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2008.03.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti V, Carraro C, Massetti E, Tavoni M (2008) International energy R&D spillovers and the economics of greenhouse gas atmospheric stabilization. Energy Econ 30(6):2912–2929. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2008.04.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke L, Weyant J, Birky A (2006) On the sources of technological change: Assessing the evidence. Energy Econ 28(5-6):579–595. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2006.05.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke L, Weyant J, Edmonds J (2008) On the sources of technological change: what do the models assume? Energy Econ 30(2):409–424. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2006.05.023

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke L, Edmonds J, Krey V, Richels R, Rose S, Tavoni M (2009) International climate policy architectures: Overview of the EMF 22 international scenarios. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S64–S81. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2009.10.013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damen K, Faaij A, Turkenburg W (2006) Health, safety and environmental risks of underground CO2 storage—overview of mechanisms and current knowledge. Clim Change 74(1):289–318. doi:10.1007/s10584-005-0425-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denman K, Brasseur G, Chidthaisong A, Ciais P, Cox PM, Dickinson RE, Hauglustaine D, Heinze C, Holland E, Jacob D, Lohmann U, Ramachandran S, da Silva Dias P, Wofsy S, Zhang X (2007) Couplings between changes in the climate system and biogeochemistry. In: Solomon S, Qin D, Manning M, Chen Z, Marquis M, Averyt K, Tignor M, Miller H (eds) Climate change 2007: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA, pp 500–587

    Google Scholar 

  • Edenhofer O, Knopf B, Barker T, Baumstark L, Bellevrat E, Chateau B, Criqui P, Isaac M, Kitous A, Kypreos S, Leimbach M, Lessmann K, Magné B, Scrieciu Ş, Turton H, van Vuuren DP (2010) The economics of low stabilization: model comparison of mitigation strategies and costs. Energy J 31:11–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer C, Newell RG (2008) Environmental and technology policies for climate mitigation. J Environ Econ Manage 55(2):142–162. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2007.11.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher AC, Narain U (2003) Global warming, endogenous risk, and irreversibility. Environ Resour Econ 25(4):395–416. doi:10.1023/A:1025056530035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher BS, Nakićenović N, Alfsen K, Morlot JC, de la Chesnaye F, Hourcade J, Jiang K, Kainuma M, Rovere EL, Matysek A, Rana A, Riahi K, Richels R, Rose S, van Vuuren D, Warren R (2007) Issues related to mitigation in the long term context. In: Metz B, Davidson OR, Bosch PR, Dave R, Meyer LA (eds) Climate Change 2007: mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlagh R, Kverndokk S, Rosendahl K (2009) Optimal timing of climate change policy: Interaction between carbon taxes and innovation externalities. Environ Resour Econ 43(3):369–390. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9271-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH, Mathai K (2000) Optimal CO2 abatement in the presence of induced technological change. J Environ Econ Manage 39(1):1–38. doi:10.1006/jeem.1999.1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greaker M, Pade L (2009) Optimal carbon dioxide abatement and technological change: should emission taxes start high in order to spur R&D? Clim Change 96(3):335–355. doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9643-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart R (2008) The timing of taxes on CO2 emissions when technological change is endogenous. J Environ Econ Manage 55(2):194–212. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2007.06.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastie T, Tibshirani R, Friedman JH (2009) The Elements of Statistical Learning: Data Mining, Inference, and Prediction, 2nd edn. Springer series in statistics, Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoogwijk M, Vuuren D, Boeters S, Blok K, Blomen E, Barker T, Chateau J, Grübler A, Masui T, Nabuurs G, Novikova A, Riahi K, du Can SR, Sathaye J, Scrieciu S, Urge-Vorsatz D, Vliet J (2008) Sectoral emission mitigation potentials: comparing bottom-up and top-down approaches. PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency

  • Keith DW (2009) Why capture CO2 from the atmosphere? Science 325(5948):1654–1655. doi:10.1126/science.1175680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keith DW, Ha-Duong M, Stolaroff JK (2006) Climate strategy with CO2 capture from the air. Clim Change 74(1-3):17–45. doi:10.1007/s10584-005-9026-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller K, Bolker BM, Bradford DF (2004) Uncertain climate thresholds and optimal economic growth. J Environ Econ Manage 48(1):723–741. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2003.10.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kintisch E (2010) ‘Asilomar 2’ takes small steps toward rules for geoengineering. Science 328(5974):22–23. doi:10.1126/science.328.5974.22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krey V, Riahi K (2009) Implications of delayed participation and technology failure for the feasibility, costs, and likelihood of staying below temperature targets—Greenhouse gas mitigation scenarios for the 21st century. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S94–S106. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2009.07.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann J (2007) Bio-energy in the black. Front Ecol Environ 5(7):381–387. doi:10.1890/1540-9295(2007)5[381:BITB]2.0.CO;2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemoine DM (2010) Climate sensitivity distributions depend on the possibility that models share biases. J Climate 23(16):4395–4415. doi:10.1175/2010JCLI3503.1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemoine DM, Traeger C (2010) Tipping points and ambiguity in the integrated assessment of climate change. CUDARE Working Paper 1111, University of California, Berkeley

  • Lenton TM, Vaughan NE (2009) The radiative forcing potential of different climate geoengineering options. Atmos Chem Phys Discuss 9(1):2559–2608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenton TM, Held H, Kriegler E, Hall JW, Lucht W, Rahmstorf S, Schellnhuber HJ (2008) Tipping elements in the earth’s climate system. Proc Natl Acad Sci 105(6):1786–1793. doi:10.1073/pnas.0705414105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luckow P, Wise M, Dooley J, Kim S (2010) Large-scale utilization of biomass energy and carbon dioxide capture and storage in the transport and electricity sectors under stringent CO2 concentration limit scenarios. International Journal of Greenhouse Gas Control 4(5):865–877. doi:10.1016/j.ijggc.2010.06.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews HD, Gillett NP, Stott PA, Zickfeld K (2009) The proportionality of global warming to cumulative carbon emissions. Nature 459(7248):829–832. doi:10.1038/nature08047

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MEF (2009) Declaration of the leaders: The Major Economies Forum on Energy and Climate. L’Aquila, Italy

  • Meinshausen M, Meinshausen N, Hare W, Raper SCB, Frieler K, Knutti R, Frame DJ, Allen MR (2009) Greenhouse-gas emission targets for limiting global warming to 2°C. Nature 458(7242):1158–1162. doi:10.1038/nature08017

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery WD, Smith AE (2007) Price, quantity, and technology strategies for climate change policy. In: Schlesinger ME, Kheshgi HS, Smith J, de la Chesnaye FC, Reilly JM, Wilson T, Kolstad C (eds) Human-Induced Climate Change: An Interdisciplinary Assessment. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 328–342

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council (2011) Climate Stabilization Targets: Emissions, Concentrations, and Impacts over Decades to Millennia. The National Academies Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Nemet GF (2006) Beyond the learning curve: factors influencing cost reductions in photovoltaics. Energy Policy 34(17):3218–3232. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2005.06.020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obersteiner M, Azar C, Kauppi P, Mollersten K, Moreira J, Nilsson S, Read P, Riahi K, Schlamadinger B, Yamagata Y, Yan J, van Ypersele J (2001) Managing climate risk. Science 294(5543):786b–787. doi:10.1126/science.294.5543.786b

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Neill BC, Oppenheimer M (2004) Climate change impacts are sensitive to the concentration stabilization path. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 101(47):16411–16416. doi:10.1073/pnas.0405522101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pielke Jr RA (2009) An idealized assessment of the economics of air capture of carbon dioxide in mitigation policy. Environ Sci Policy 12(3):216–225. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2009.01.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS (2002) Optimal timing problems in environmental economics. J Econ Dyn Control 26(9–10):1677–1697. doi:10.1016/S0165-1889(01)00090-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pizer WA, Popp D (2008) Endogenizing technological change: matching empirical evidence to modeling needs. Energy Econ 30(6):2754–2770. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2008.02.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Read P (2009) Reducing CO2 levels—so many ways, so few being taken. Clim Change 97(3-4):449–458. doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9723-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes JS, Keith DW (2005) Engineering economic analysis of biomass IGCC with carbon capture and storage. Biomass and Bioenergy 29(6):440–450. doi:10.1016/j.biombioe.2005.06.007

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riahi K, Grübler A, Nakićenović N (2007) Scenarios of long-term socio-economic and environmental development under climate stabilization. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 74(7):887–935. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2006.05.026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandén BA, Azar C (2005) Near-term technology policies for long-term climate targets—economy wide versus technology specific approaches. Energy Policy 33(12):1557–1576. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.01.012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smetacek V, Naqvi S (2008) The next generation of iron fertilization experiments in the Southern Ocean. Philos Trans - Royal Soc A Math Phys Eng Sci 366(1882):3947–3967. doi:10.1098/rsta.2008.0144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephens J, Keith D (2008) Assessing geochemical carbon management. Clim Change 90(3):217–242. doi:10.1007/s10584-008-9440-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stolaroff JK, Keith DW, Lowry GV (2008) Carbon dioxide capture from atmospheric air using sodium hydroxide spray. Environ Sci Technol 42(8):2728–2735. doi:10.1021/es702607w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strand SE, Benford G (2009) Ocean sequestration of crop residue carbon: recycling fossil fuel carbon back to deep sediments. Environ Sci Technol 43(4):1000–1007. doi:10.1021/es8015556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strong AL, Cullen JJ, Chisholm SW (2009) Ocean fertilization: science, policy, and commerce. Oceanography 22(3):236–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uddin SN, Barreto L (2007) Biomass-fired cogeneration systems with CO2 capture and storage. Renew Energy 32(6):1006–1019. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2006.04.009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNFCCC (2009) Copenhagen Accord

  • UNFCCC (2011) Compilation of economy-wide emission reduction targets to be implemented by Parties included in Annex I to the Convention: Note by the secretariat

  • van der Zwaan B, Gerlagh R (2009) Economics of geological CO2 storage and leakage. Clim Change 93(3):285–309. doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9558-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Vuuren D, den Elzen M, Lucas P, Eickhout B, Strengers B, van Ruijven B, Wonink S, van Houdt R (2007) Stabilizing greenhouse gas concentrations at low levels: an assessment of reduction strategies and costs. Clim Change 81(2):119–159. doi:10.1007/s10584-006-9172-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Vuuren DP, Riahi K (2011) The relationship between short-term emissions and long-term concentration targets. Clim Change 104(3–4):793–801. doi:10.1007/s10584-010-0004-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Vuuren DP, van Vliet J, Stehfest E (2009) Future bio-energy potential under various natural constraints. Energy Policy 37(11):4220–4230. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.05.029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Vuuren DP, Bellevrat E, Kitous A, Isaac M (2010a) Bio-energy use and low stabilization scenarios. Energy J 31:193–221

    Google Scholar 

  • van Vuuren DP, Stehfest E, den Elzen MG, van Vliet J, Isaac M (2010b) Exploring IMAGE model scenarios that keep greenhouse gas radiative forcing below 3 W/m2 in 2100. Energy Econ 32(5):1105–1120. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.03.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodward FI, Bardgett RD, Raven JA, Hetherington AM (2009) Biological approaches to global environment change mitigation and remediation. Curr Biol 19(14):R615–R623. doi:10.1016/j.cub.2009.06.012

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Comments from three anonymous reviewers greatly improved this paper. We also thank Michael O’Hare for comments and for connecting the authors. The research was carried out at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) as part of the 2009 Young Scientists Summer Program. Participation by Lemoine in the IIASA Young Scientists Summer Program was made possible by a grant from the National Academy of Sciences Board on International Scientific Organizations, funded by the National Science Foundation under grant number OISE-0738129. Support to Lemoine also came from the Robert and Patricia Switzer Foundation Environmental Fellowship Program. Support to Fuss, Szolgayova, and Obersteiner came from the EU-supported project Climate Change: Terrestrial Adaptation and Mitigation in Europe (CC-TAME) (grant number 212535, http://www.cctame.eu/), from the Greenhouse Gas Initiative [“Climate Risk Management Modeling” (http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Research/GGI)] at IIASA, and from Paradigm Shifts Modelling and Innovative Approaches (PASHMINA) (grant number 244766, http://www.pashmina-project.eu).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Derek M. Lemoine.

Appendix: Model parameterization

Appendix: Model parameterization

This appendix presents the parameterizations of the portfolio selection model. It describes the probability distributions for technological outcomes, the functional representation of induced technological change (ITC), and the cost functions used in the objective function.

The state variables α t , γ t , and ϕ t record the technology outcomes that apply to period t (Table 1). These outcomes are each drawn from a three-point probability distribution similar to the one in Baker and Adu-Bonnah (2008). The main differences are that here the distribution is anchored by the previous period's realized outcome and that here the targeted level of technology depends not just on the previous period's R&D funding but also on its abatement policy. Abatement can induce technological change via functions \(ITC_{\alpha}:\mu_t \rightarrow [0,\bar{\alpha}]\) for carbon-free R&D and \(ITC_{\gamma}:\mu_t \rightarrow [0,\bar{\gamma}]\) for emission intensity R&D. ITC may occur through private R&D or through learning-by-doing. The technology target for a given period comes from summing the targets produced by abatement via ITC and by public R&D, provided the total target does not exceed the exogenously fixed maximal level. The three possibilities are that technology does not change, that the technology target is attained, and that the technology target is surpassed to yield the best possible outcome:Footnote 10

$$Pr[\alpha_t=\alpha_{t-1}] = p_{\alpha}(1- \min[\hat{\alpha}_{t-1} + ITC_{\alpha}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\alpha} ] ) \label{equ_prob_alpha_target}\\[3pt] $$
(3)
$$Pr[\alpha_t=\min(\hat{\alpha}_{t-1}e+ ITC_{\alpha}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\alpha} )] = 1-p_{\alpha} \label{equ_prob_alpha_exact}\\[3pt] $$
(4)
$$Pr[\alpha_t=\bar{\alpha}]e= p_{\alpha}(\min[\hat{\alpha}_{t-1} + ITC_{\alpha}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\alpha} ])\label{equ_prob_alpha_high}\\[3pt] $$
(5)
$$Pr[\gamma_t=\gamma_{t-1}]e= p_{\gamma}(1-\min[\hat{\gamma}_{t-1} + ITC_{\gamma}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\gamma} ]) \label{equ_prob_gamma_target}\\[3pt] $$
(6)
$$Pr[\gamma_t=\min(\hat{\gamma}_{t-1}e+ ITC_{\gamma}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\gamma} )] = 1-p_{\gamma} \label{equ_prob_gamma_exact}\\[3pt] $$
(7)
$$Pr[\gamma_t=\bar{\gamma}]e= p_{\gamma}(\min[\hat{\gamma}_{t-1} + ITC_{\gamma}(\mu_{t-1}),\bar{\gamma} ]) \label{equ_prob_gamma_high}\\[3pt] $$
(8)
$$Pr[\phi_t=\phi_{t-1}]e= p_{\phi}(1-\hat{\phi}_{t-1}) \label{equ_prob_phi_target}\\[3pt] $$
(9)
$$Pr[\phi_t=\hat{\phi}_{t-1}]e= 1-p_{\phi} \label{equ_prob_phi_exact}\\ $$
(10)
$$Pr[\phi_t=\bar{\phi}]e= p_{\phi} \hat{\phi}_{t-1} \label{equ_prob_phi_high} $$
(11)

TheeITC functions allow us to see how beliefs about the effectiveness of abatement at producing each type of technological change affect optimal policy. Unfortunately, the relationship between ITC and public R&D cannot be specified using empirical results (Pizer and Popp 2008). Instead, we translate the fraction of emissions abated into the equivalent of some fraction of maximal R&D funding. First, 0% abatement does not affect the R&D targets. Second, we require ``perfect'' ITC to translate a given percentage abatement into R&D targets that are the same percentage of their maximal levels. This implies that \(\mu=ITC_{\alpha}(\mu)/\bar{\alpha}=ITC_{\gamma}(\mu)/\bar{\gamma}\) under perfect ITC. A parameter ν controls the effectiveness of ITC and proxies for the severity of innovation market failures. If ν = 0, then ITC for that technology is ``perfect'' in the sense that a percentage of full abatement produces an equivalent percentage of the maximal technology target. If ν > 0, then ITC for that technology is ``imperfect'' in the sense that a percentage of full abatement translates into a smaller percentage of the maximal technology target:

$$ITC_{\alpha}(\mu_t) = \max (0,(\mu_t-\nu_{\alpha})\bar{\alpha}) \label{equ_itc_alpha}\\ $$
(12)
$$ITC_{\gamma}(\mu_t)e= \max (0,(\mu_t-\nu_{\gamma})\bar{\gamma}) \label{equ_itc_gamma} $$
(13)

Wheneν α and ν γ are positive, abatement may not produce any ITC unless it reaches a sufficiently high level. This representation enables us to vary the effectiveness of ITC across scenarios and also to make ITC differentially effective for emission intensity technologies and carbon-free. Under the assumption that emission intensity technologies represent incremental changes that are more responsive to carbon price signals, the base case parameterization assumes that ITC is stronger for emission intensity technologies than for carbon-free technologies.

It remains to define cost functions for abatement, NET deployment, and public R&D targets. First, the cost of abatement depends on the level of abatement and on available technologies. c(μ t ,α t ,γ t ) is the average cost in the base case of abating fraction μ t of BAU emissions e t given R&D outcomes α t and γ t :

$$ c(\mu_t,\alpha_{t},\gamma_{t}) = \ \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \min \big[ \frac{z_t}{\mu_t}d\left( z_t \right),(1-\alpha_{t})d(\mu_t) \big] & \text{for base case abatement cost} \\ \min \big[ \frac{z_t}{\mu_t}\tilde{d}\left( z_t \right),(1-\alpha_{t})\tilde{d}(\mu_t) \big] & \text{for low-cost abatement} \\ \end{array} \right. $$
(14)

where \(z_t \equiv \max \left[ (\mu_t - \gamma_{t})/(1-\gamma_{t}),0 \right]\) as in Baker and Adu-Bonnah (2008). The top expression holds for the base case parameterization and for most others, but the two parameterizations with low-cost abatement use the bottom expression. Both expressions give abatement cost with time t technology as a function of abatement cost with initial technology, but they differ in the function (d(·) or \(\tilde{d}(\cdot)\)) used to assign the cost with initial technology. In either case, zero abatement costs nothing (\(d(0)=\tilde{d}(0)=0\)), and the normalization is d(1) = 100. The range of c(·) is [0,100]. The two terms inside the minimization operators give the effect of emission intensity technologies and carbon-free technologies, and the use of the minimization operator assumes that the cheapest type of technology is used at each level of abatement (compare Blyth et al. 2009). Hoogwijk et al. (2008) reported the carbon price yielding aggregate global abatement of 25% to be between $10/tCO2 and $40/tCO2 and the carbon price yielding aggregate global abatement of 50% to be between $60/tCO2 and some level well above $100/tCO2. We develop the base case and the low-cost average cost representations by assuming that marginal costs follow a geometric progression at the discretized points and increase linearly between those points.Footnote 11 This yields the normalized values:

$$\text{Base case: } \;d(0.25)=2.4, \, d(0.50)=8.4, \, d(0.75)=28, \, d(1)=100 $$
$$\text{Low-cost: } \;\tilde{d}(0.25)=2.4, \, \tilde{d}(0.50)=6.0, \, \tilde{d}(0.75)=12, \, \tilde{d}(1)=27 $$

When z t falls between the above discretization for μ, we define the cost function by assuming average cost is linear between these discretized points. We only model endogenous technological change, so abatement cost does not change unless carbon-free or emission intensity technology changes as described in Eqs. 3 through 11.

A second type of cost function applies to deployment κ t of NETs. We represent NETs as having constant marginal cost, which is determined by adjusting the base case average cost of an exogenous level x of period 1 abatement for the outcome ϕ t of NET R&D:

$$ f(\kappa_t,\phi_t)=\kappa_t (1-\phi_t) \, d(x) $$
(15)

Converted to non-normalized costs, x = 0.75 in a low-cost parameterization corresponds to NETs costing $115/tCO2, which is near the low end of recent estimates, and x = 1 in the base case parameterization corresponds to NETs costing $415/tCO2, which is above many recent estimates (e.g., Rhodes and Keith 2005; Keith et al. 2006; Uddin and Barreto 2007; Stolaroff et al. 2008; Keith 2009; Pielke 2009).

Finally, a third type of cost function determines how much R&D funding it takes to select a technology target. We assume that the funding that it takes to aim for the chosen public target depends not on the level of the target but on the percentage of the maximal target that it represents. We treat the cost of reaching a percentage of the maximal level of R&D as being an exogenous fraction (specifically: y g , y h y g , or y j ) of the base case cost for abating the same percentage of period 1 emissions:

$$g\left(\frac{\hat{\alpha}_t}{\bar{\alpha}}\right) = y_g*d\left(\frac{\hat{\alpha}_t}{\bar{\alpha}}\right)*\frac{\hat{\alpha}_t}{\bar{\alpha}}*e_1 \\ $$
(16)
$$h\left(\frac{\hat{\gamma}_t}{\bar{\gamma}}\right)e= y_h*g\left(\frac{\hat{\gamma}_t}{\bar{\gamma}}\right) \\ $$
(17)
$$j\left(\frac{\hat{\phi}_t}{\bar{\phi}}\right)e= \frac{y_j}{y_g}*g\left(\frac{\hat{\phi}_t}{\bar{\phi}}\right) $$
(18)

We represent carbon-free R&D costs in terms of average abatement cost because this provides a natural reference point while satisfying the desired property of decreasing returns, and we define the cost of emission intensity R&D as some fraction y h of the cost of carbon-free R&D. We make abatement cost and R&D cost of similar magnitude because, first, we are looking at the cost of shifting the whole abatement cost curve and, second, we aim to gain more insight than would be obtained by making R&D very cheap or very expensive.

The base case parameters in these functions and probability distributions are chosen to represent values that accord with intuition about, for instance, emission intensity technology being more responsive to abatement than is carbon-free technology. This model's parameterizations are used as demonstrations to aid intuition and to provide a framework for assessing the implications of different beliefs; the results should not be read as either predictive or prescriptive. Fourteen alternative parameterizations reflect different beliefs about technological change, cost functions, or discounting (Table 3). If all parameterizations produce similar results, then we have more confidence that the results are robust to specific values. A more thorough assessment of robustness should also include structural variation in, for instance, the form of the cost functions, the form of the ITC functions converting abatement into R&D targets, and the form of the probability distribution for technological change.

Table 3 The 15 parameter scenarios explored with the numerical model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lemoine, D.M., Fuss, S., Szolgayova, J. et al. The influence of negative emission technologies and technology policies on the optimal climate mitigation portfolio. Climatic Change 113, 141–162 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-011-0269-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-011-0269-4

Keywords

Navigation