Skip to main content
Log in

Trade credit contract with limited liability in the supply chain with budget constraints

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper investigates the impacts of trade credit (i.e., open account payment) and limited liability on the performance of a two-level supply chain with budget constraints. It shows that limited liability accounts for the reason why the retailer with a lower initial budget initiates a higher ordering level under trade credit contract. Furthermore, this paper finds that trade credit contract could create value in a supply chain with budget constraints, and partly coordinate the supply chain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, Bayer Material Science APAC, Tailed Service Guidelines and Payment Terms, in 2008, http://bhks10.ap.bayer.cnb/GC/HK/common/Comguide.nsf.

  2. See, e.g., Gerchak and Wang (2004). We also performed another analysis on the case where p is not normalized to one. The analysis shows that our qualitative results hold regardless of the normalization.

References

  • Atanasova, C. V., & Wilson, N. (2003). Bank borrowing constraints and the demand for trade credit: evidence from panel data. Managerial and Decision Economics, 24, 503–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., & Gollier, C. (1997). Trade credit and credit rationing. The Review of Financial Studies, 10, 903–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, M., Miksimovic, V., & Zechner, J. (1988). Vendor financing. The Journal of Finance, 43, 1127–1141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burkart, M., & Ellingsen, T. (2004). In-kind finance: a theory of trade credit. American Economic Review, 94, 569–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In S. Graves & T. de Kok (Eds.), Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P., & Lariviere, M. A. (2005). Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limits. Management Science, 51, 30–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X., & Wan, G. (2011). The effect of financing service on a budget-constrained supply chain. Asia-Pacific Journal of Operational Research, 28, 457–485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, P. S., & Srinivasan, K. (1995). Demand signalling under unobservable effect in franchising: linear and nonlinear price contracts. Management Science, 41, 1303–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emery, G. W. (1987). An optimal financial response to variable demand. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22, 209–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferris, J. S. (1981). A transactions theory of trade credit use. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96, 243–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R. (2001). Trade credit and productive efficiency in developing countries. World Development, 29, 311–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerchak, Y., & Wang, Y. (2004). Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contract in assembly systems with random demand. Production and Operations Management, 13, 23–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerstner, E., & Hess, J. D. (1995). Pull promotions and channel coordination. Marketing Science, 14, 43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graves, S., & de Kok, T. (2003). Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. Amsterdam: North-Holland, Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadley, G., & Whitin, T. (1963). Analysis of inventory system. New York: Prentice-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingene, C. A., & Parry, M. E. (1995). Channel coordination when retailer compete. Marketing Science, 14, 360–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeuland, A. P., & Shugan, S. M. (1983). Management channel profits. Marketing Science, 2, 239–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lal, R. (1990). Improving channel coordination through franchising. Marketing Science, 1, 299–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lariviere, M. A., & Porteus, E. L. (2001). Selling to the newsvendor: an analysis of price-only contracts. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 3, 293–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Y. W., & Stowe, J. D. (1993). Product risk, asymmetric information, and trade credit. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28, 285–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian, S. L., & Smith, C. W. Jr. (1992). Accounts receivable management policy: theory and evidence. The Journal of Finance, 47, 169–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moorthy, K. S. (1987). Managing channel profits: comment. Marketing Science, 6, 375–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padmandabhan, V., & Png, I. P. (1997). Manufacturer’s returns policies and retail competition. Marketing Science, 16, 81–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasternack, B. A. (1985). Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Science, 4, 166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1994). The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. The Journal of Finance, 49, 2–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1997). Trade credit: theories and evidence. The Review of Financial Studies, 10, 661–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simchi-Levi, D., Wu, S. D., & Shen, Z. (2004). Handbook of quantitative supply chain analysis: modeling in the ebusiness era. New York: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. K. (1987). Trade credit and information asymmetry. The Journal of Finance, 23, 863–872.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, J. (1950). Vertical integration and antitrust policy. Journal of Political Economy, 58, 347–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weng, Z.K. (1995). Channel coordination and quantity discounts. Management Science, 41, 1509–1522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilner, B.S. (2000). The exploitation of relationships in financial distress: the case of trade credit. The Journal of Finance, 55, 153–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Editor Boros and the anonymous referees for their very valuable comments and suggestions. The first author acknowledges support from NSF of China (70972046, 71172039), and NCET program (NCET-10-0340). The second author acknowledges support from 985 funds of Fudan University (2012SHKXYB004) and NSFC (71171059).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anyu Wang.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Part 1. Let \(\pi^{R}(Q)\equiv \mathbb{E} [(\min[D,Q]-(wQ-B))^{+}-B ]\). Then

$$\pi^R(Q)=\int_{(wQ-B)}^Q\bigl[D-(wQ-B)\bigr]dF(D)+\int_Q^\infty \bigl[Q-(wQ-B)\bigr]dF(D)-B$$

Differentiating π R with respect to Q and collecting terms, we have

$$\frac{d\pi^R(Q)}{dQ}=\bar{F}(Q)-w\bar{F}(wQ-B)$$

The retailer’s optimal ordering level, Q , must satisfy the first-order condition:

$$\bar{F}\bigl(Q^*\bigr)=w\bar{F}\bigl(wQ^*-B\bigr).$$

We further have

Since h is an increasing function by Assumption A1, we have h(Q )>h(wQ B). Therefore, \(\frac{d^{2}\pi^{R}(Q)}{d(Q)^{2}}|_{Q=Q^{*}}<0\) and Q is thus unique.

Part 2. Inspection of \(\bar{F}(Q^{*})=w\bar{F}(wQ^{*}-B)\) readily reveals that

$$\frac{dQ^*}{dB}=-\frac{h(wQ^*-B)}{h(Q^*)-wh(wQ^*-B)}<0.$$

Then, we can show that Q is decreasing in B. We further show that \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}<0\). Let

$$G\bigl(Q^*,w,B\bigr)=\bar{F}\bigl(Q^*\bigr)-w\bar{F}\bigl(wQ^*-B\bigr).$$

Because of \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}=-\frac{dG(Q^{*},w,B)}{dw}/\frac{dG(Q^{*},w,B)}{dQ^{*}}\) and \(\frac{dwQ^{*}}{dw}=Q^{*}+w\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}\), we obtain

Suppose \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}\geq 0\). Then wQ and Q h(Q ) are increasing in w. Let w 0 satisfy 1−Q (w 0)h(Q (w 0))=0. We have \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}<0\) when w<w 0 and \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}>0\) when w>w 0. That means that wQ achieves its minimum at w 0. Recall that under trade credit contract the feasible region of wholesale price is (c,1). The remaining proof splits into three cases.

  • Case A: w 0≥1. In this case,

    $$Q^*(w)h\bigl(Q^*(w)\bigr)\leq Q^*(1)h\bigl(Q^*(1)\bigr)\leq Q^*(w_0)h\bigl(Q^*(w_0)\bigr)=1$$

    which implies that \(\frac{dwQ^{*}}{dw}\leq 0\). A contradiction.

  • Case B: c<w 0<1. We have wQ being decreasing in w over (c,w 0). Again, a contradiction.

  • Case C: w 0=c. In this case, we have

    $$wQ^*(c)h\bigl(wQ^*(c)-B\bigr)<Q^*(c)h\bigl(Q^*(c)\bigr)=1$$

    because w<1 and B≥0 by assumption. Since we suppose \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}\geq 0\), we also obtain wQ h(wQ B)≥1, a contradiction to the inequality above.

We have reached a contradiction in each of the three cases. Therefore, we must have \(\frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}<0\). □

Proof of Proposition 2

First, we need to proof Πs(w) is a unimodal function of w∈[c,p], where p=1.

In (9), we can show that \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}=\frac{[1-wQ^{*}h(wQ^{*}-B)]}{-w[h(Q^{*})-wh(wQ^{*}-B)]}<0\).

Let \(\varepsilon(w)=\frac{\bar{F}(Q^{*})[1-H(Q^{*})]}{1-wQ^{*}h(wQ^{*}-B)}\), then the sign of \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}\) depends on that of [ε(w)−c]. Let w 0 satisfies 1−H(Q )=0. When w<w 0, we have ε(w)<0 and thus \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}>0\). When w>w 0, we have ε>0.

Next, we aim to show that ε(w) is an increasing function when w>w 0. We have

where QQ , \(H'(D)\equiv\frac{dH(D)}{dD}>0\), \(Q'\equiv \frac{dQ^{*}}{dw}\), to simplify notation.

Therefore, ε(w) is an increasing function when w>w 0. Let \(\hat{w}\) solves ε(w)=c. This further implies that \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}>0\) when \(w<\hat{w}\), \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}=0\) when \(w=\hat{w}\) and \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}<0\) when \(w>\hat{w}\). And, w=c, we can get ε<c, and \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}>0\); Alternatively, w=c, we can get ε>c, and \(\frac{d\Pi^{S}}{dw}<0\). Therefore, we can conclude that ΠS(w) is a unimodal function of w∈[c,1]. Given the feasible region for \(w\in[\underline{w},\bar{w}]\), as a consequence, we can show that the optimal solution for the supplier, w , is equivalent to \(\min[\max[\underline{w},\hat{w}],\bar{w}]\). Then, the proof is well done. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chen, X., Wang, A. Trade credit contract with limited liability in the supply chain with budget constraints. Ann Oper Res 196, 153–165 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-012-1119-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-012-1119-0

Keywords

Navigation