Skip to main content
Log in

A general equilibrium evolutionary model with two groups of agents, generating fashion cycle dynamics

  • Published:
Decisions in Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We propose a discrete-time exchange economy evolutionary model with two groups of agents. In our setting the definition of equilibrium depends also on agents’ population shares, which affect the market clearing conditions. We prove that, despite such difference with the classical Walrasian framework, for all economies and population shares there exists at least one equilibrium, and we show that for all population shares, generically in the set of the economies, equilibria are finite and regular. We then introduce the dynamic law governing the evolution of the population shares, and we investigate the existence and the stability of the resulting stationary equilibria. We assume that the reproduction level of a group is related to its attractiveness degree, which depends on the social visibility level, determined by the consumption choices of the agents in that group. The attractiveness of a group is described via a generic bell-shaped map, increasing for low visibility levels, but decreasing when the visibility of the group exceeds a given threshold value, due to a congestion effect. The model is able to reproduce the recurrent dynamic behavior typical of the fashion cycle, presenting booms and busts in the agents’ consumption choices, and in the groups’ attractiveness and population shares.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Oscillatory dynamics in the consumption activities are found, in different contexts, also in Antoci et al. (2004), Bischi and Radi (2012), Matsumoto (2003) and Naimzada et al. (2013).

  2. Cf. also Gori et al. (2014), where an homotopy method is employed to prove existence of equilibria in a model with real assets and restricted participation.

  3. We refer the reader to Naimzada and Pireddu (2019b) for a more detailed bifurcation analysis, conducted for several parameter configurations and for the formulations of the attractiveness maps introduced in Naimzada and Pireddu (2019a), too.

  4. We keep the notation used in Chang and Stauber (2009) and in Naimzada and Pireddu (2016, 2018, 2019a), where \(i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\) was the weight assigned to good x in the Cobb–Douglas utility functions by agents in group i, with \(0<\alpha<\beta <1\).

  5. We notice that, if \(u_{\alpha }=u_{\beta }\), then agents are homogeneous since endowments of both goods coincide between groups. In order not to overburden notation and not to excessively complicate the analysis, we will here focus on the case with \(w_{x,\alpha }=w_{x,\beta }=w_x\) and \(w_{y,\alpha }=w_{y,\beta }=w_y\), implicitly assuming that \(u_{\alpha }\ne u_{\beta }\), like it happens in the example considered in Sect. 3.

  6. We remark that the argument above suggests that market equilibria exist for any economy even when \(a=0\) and \(a=1\), although such extreme cases are not encompassed in Proposition 1 due to the need to deal with open sets because of the differential topology kind of proof. We also notice that considering an open interval of the form \((-\varepsilon , 1+\varepsilon )\), with \(\varepsilon >0\) arbitrarily small, would not solve the issue, as some steps in the proof of Proposition 1 would not work anymore.

  7. Actually, along the proof we show the validity of a stronger result, i.e., that in any time period and for every population share, for each choice of the utility functions in \({\mathcal {U}}\), there exists an open and full measure subset of the space of endowments where the generic regularity property holds. In particular, the fact that the smooth dependence of equilibria holds for all share values—for all utility functions in \({\mathcal {U}}\) and for almost all endowment combinations—is crucial, as we will characterize market stationary equilibria in terms of population shares. Indeed, for our purposes a result more in line with the approach in Chapter 8 in Villanacci et al. (2002), where economies are identified with endowments and the utility function vector is taken as given (see in particular Paragraph 8.7 therein), would suffice. Nonetheless, the smooth dependence of equilibria on utility functions comes as a byproduct of the proof of Proposition 2, which is in line with some recent generic regularity results in the general equilibrium literature (see, e.g., Carosi et al. 2009 and Hoelle et al. 2016). We chose to present such version of the proposition, since we believe that a more general result about generic regularity can be of independent interest.

  8. A more detailed bifurcation analysis, performed for several parameter configurations and for the formulations of the attractiveness maps introduced in Naimzada and Pireddu (2019a), too, can be found in the Appendix of Naimzada and Pireddu (2019b).

  9. We remark that \(V_{i}\), and consequently \({\mathscr {A}}_{i}\), also depend on the economy \(\widetilde{{\mathcal {E}}}\), which together with a determines the market equilibrium. However, in order not to overburden notation, we will not make such dependence explicit.

  10. This happens, for instance, with the parameter configuration considered in Sect. 3, when fixing \(c_i=d_i=0\), for \(i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\), \(\mu =2\) and letting \(\sigma >0\) free to vary. See Scenario A in Naimzada and Pireddu (2019b) for the corresponding details.

  11. The Stone–Geary utility functions were derived by Geary (1950) in a comment on an earlier work, while Stone (1954) estimated the Linear Expenditure System, arising from the utility functions in (13).

  12. Although such feature is mentioned in Fisher (1972) for Stone–Geary utility functions when the coefficients \(c_i,\,d_i\) are non-negative, for \(i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\), a direct proof using the expression for the individual demand functions in (14) shows that the gross substitute property holds also in the case of negative coefficients, as long as their value is not excessively large in absolute value. See the discussion after (14) for more details.

  13. We here consider polarized values for \(v_x\) and \(v_y\), as both of them are positive but one is much larger than the other. As observed in Sect. 2, such case approximates those frameworks in which visibility and attractiveness are produced by the consumption of a single good. However, our results hold true also for more balanced values of \(v_x\) and \(v_y\).

  14. We remark that the symmetry between the bounds of \(c_i\) and \(d_i\) is caused by the fact that, for the parameter configuration we deal with, it holds that \(w_x=(1-\alpha )w_y\). Of course, such peculiarity does not affect the outcomes. Indeed, in the scenario that we will consider below the parameters \(c_i\) and \(d_i\) will not bear any symmetry.

  15. In regard to the second scenario, in Naimzada and Pireddu (2019b) we deal with \(c_{\alpha }=0.3,\,c_{\beta }=0.12,\,d_{\alpha }=0.1,\,d_{\beta }=0.15\).

  16. See Naimzada and Pireddu (2019c) for the corresponding definition and for the proof, in our framework, of the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics, according to which every (stationary) equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimal. Since the employed concept of Pareto optimality concerns one single period at a time, we will use the expression “instantaneous Pareto optimal allocation” in the present work.

  17. We stress that differently from what done in Villanacci et al. (2002), we normalize the price of the first commodity, rather than of the last one. Of course, this change does not affect the validity of the results.

References

  • Antoci, A., Brugnano, L., Galeotti, M.: Sustainability, indeterminacy and oscillations in a growth model with environmental assets. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 5, 571–587 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Day, R.H.: Rational choice and erratic behaviour. Rev. Econ. Stud. 48, 459–471 (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bischi, G.-I., Radi, D.: An extension of the Antoci–Dei–Galeotti evolutionary model for environment protection through financial instruments. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 13, 432–440 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Block, L.S., Coppel, W.A.: Dynamics in One Dimension. Springer Lecture Notes, vol. 1513. Springer, Berlin (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch, W.A., McGough, B.: Replicator dynamics in a Cobweb model with rationally heterogeneous expectations. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 65, 224–244 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabrales, A., Sobel, J.: On the limit points of discrete selection dynamics. J. Econ. Theory 57, 407–419 (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Carosi, L., Gori, M., Villanacci, A.: Endogenous restricted participation in general financial equilibrium. J. Math. Econ. 45, 787–806 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Caulkins, J.P., Hartl, R.F., Kort, P.M., Feichtinger, G.: Explaining fashion cycles: imitators chasing innovators in product space. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 31, 1535–1556 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli, F., Naimzada, A.: A multiscale time model with piecewise constant argument for a boundedly rational monopolist. J. Differ. Equ. Appl. 22, 1480–1489 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli, F., Naimzada, A., Sodini, M.: Oligopoly models with different learning and production time scales. Decis. Econ. Finance 41, 297–312 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, J., Stauber, R.: Evolution of preferences in an exchange economy. Econ. Lett. 103, 131–134 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Coelho, P.R.P., McClure, J.E.: Toward an economic theory of fashion. Econ. Inq. 31, 595–608 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., Jeanne, O.: Segmented communication and fashionable behavior. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 39, 371–385 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Day, R.H.: Rational choice and economic behavior. Theory Decis. 1, 229–251 (1970)

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Giovinazzo, V., Naimzada, A.: A model of fashion: endogenous preferences in social interaction. Econ. Model. 47, 12–17 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P.A.: National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am. Econ. Rev. 55, 1126–1150 (1965)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekaterinchuk, E., Jungeilges, J., Ryazanova, T., Sushko, I.: Dynamics of a minimal consumer network with uni-directional influence. J. Evol. Econ. 27, 831–857 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekaterinchuk, E., Jungeilges, J., Ryazanova, T., Sushko, I.: Dynamics of a minimal consumer network with bi-directional influence. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul. 58, 107–118 (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F.M.: Gross substitutes and the utility function. J. Econ. Theory 4, 82–87 (1972)

    Google Scholar 

  • Frijters, P.: A model of fashions and status. Econ. Model. 15, 501–517 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W.: A dynamic model of interdependent consumer behavior. Zeitschr. f. Nationalökonomie 34, 327–344 (1974)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W.: Periodic and aperiodic consumer behavior. Appl. Math. Comput. 22, 233–254 (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W., Jungeilges, J.: A non-linear model of interdependent consumer behaviour. Econ. Lett. 27, 145–150 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W., Jungeilges, J.: “Spindles” and coexisting attractors in a dynamic model of interdependent consumer behavior: a note. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 21, 223–231 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W., Jungeilges, J.: A model of interdependent consumer behavior: nonlinear dynamics in \({\mathbb{R}}^2\). In: Eichhorn, W. (ed.) Models and Measurement of Welfare and Inequality, pp. 941–962. Springer, Berlin (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardini, L., Sushko, I., Matsuyama, K.: 2D discontinuous piecewise linear map: emergence of fashion cycles. Chaos 28, 055917 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1063/1.5018588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geary, R.C.: A note on “A constant-utility index of the cost of living”. Rev. Econ. Stud. 18, 65–66 (1950)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gloeckner, H.: Implicit functions from topological vector spaces to Banach spaces. Isr. J. Math. 155, 205–252 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gori, M., Pireddu, M., Villanacci, A.: Regularity and Pareto improving on financial equilibria with price-dependent borrowing restrictions. Res. Econ. 67, 100–110 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gori, M., Pireddu, M., Villanacci, A.: Existence of financial equilibria with endogenous short selling restrictions and real assets. Decis. Econ. Finance 37, 349–371 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heffetz, O.: A test of conspicuous consumption: visibility and income elasticities. Rev. Econ. Stat. 93, 1101–1117 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heffetz, O.: Who sees what? Demographics and the visibility of consumer expenditures. J. Econ. Psychol. 33, 801–818 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heifetz, A., Shannon, C., Spiegel, Y.: The dynamic evolution of preferences. Econ. Theory 32, 251–286 (2007a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heifetz, A., Shannon, C., Spiegel, Y.: What to maximize if you must. J. Econ. Theory 133, 31–57 (2007b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, M.: Differential Topology. Springer, New York (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoelle, M., Pireddu, M., Villanacci, A.: Incomplete financial markets with real assets and endogenous credit limits. J. Econ. 117, 1–36 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofbauer, J., Weibull, J.: Evolutionary selection against dominated strategies. J. Econ. Theory 71, 558–573 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  • Karni, E., Schmeidler, D.: Fixed preferences and changing tastes. Am. Econ. Rev. 80, 262–267 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H.: Bandwagon, snob and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers. Q. J. Econ. 65, 183–207 (1950)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd, N.G.: Degree Theory, Cambridge Tracts in Mathematics, vol. 73. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1978)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M.D., Green, J.R.: Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press, New York (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsumoto, A.: Let it be: chaotic price instability can be beneficial. Chaos Solitons Fractals 18, 745–758 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K.: Custom versus fashion: path-dependence and limit cycles in a random matching game. In: Working Paper in Economics, E-92-11, Hoover Institution; Northwestern University CMS-EMS DP # 1030 (1991)

  • Nachbar, J.H.: “Evolutionary” selection dynamics in games: convergence and limit properties. Int. J. Game Theory 19, 59–89 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M.: Endogenous evolution of heterogeneous consumers preferences: multistability and coexistence between groups. Econ. Lett. 142, 22–26 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M.: Fashion cycle dynamics in a model with endogenous discrete evolution of heterogeneous preferences. Chaos 28, 055907 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1063/1.5024931

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M.: Fashion cycle dynamics induced by agents’ heterogeneity for generic bell-shaped attractiveness functions. J. Differ. Equ. Appl. (2019a). https://doi.org/10.1080/10236198.2019.1627344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M.: A general equilibrium evolutionary model with generic utility functions and generic bell-shaped attractiveness maps, generating fashion cycle dynamics. Extended version available as: University of Milan Bicocca Department of Economics, Management and Statistics Working Paper No. 401 (2019b)

  • Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M.: The first fundamental theorem of welfare in a general equilibrium evolutionary setting. University of Milan Bicocca Department of Economics, Management and Statistics Working Paper No. 415 (2019c)

  • Naimzada, A., Sacco, P., Sodini, M.: Wealth-sensitive positional competition as a source of dynamic complexity in OLG models. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 14, 1–13 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesendorfer, W.: Design innovation and fashion cycles. Am. Econ. Rev. 85, 771–792 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandholm, W.H.: Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics. MIT Press, Cambridge (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharkovsky, A.N., Kolyada, S.F., Sivak, A.G., Fedorenko, V.V.: Dynamics of One-Dimensional Maps. Kluwer Academic, Boston (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G.: Fashion. Int. Q. 10, 130–155 (1904)

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R.: Linear expenditure systems and demand analysis: an application to the pattern of British demand. Econ. J. 64, 511–527 (1954)

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, P.D., Jonker, L.B.: Evolutionarily stable strategies and game dynamics. Math. Biosci. 40, 145–156 (1978)

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T.: The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions. Macmillan, New York (1899)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vigneron, F., Johnson, L.: A review and a conceptual framework of prestige-seeking consumer behavior. Acad. Mark. Sci. Rev. 3, 1–15 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Villanacci, A., Carosi, L., Benevieri, P., Battinelli, A.: Differential Topology and General Equilibrium with Complete and Incomplete Markets. Springer, US (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiggins, S.: Introduction to Applied Nonlinear Dynamical Systems and Chaos, Texts in Applied Mathematics, 2nd edn. Springer, New York (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, W.-B.: Fashion with snobs and bandwagoners in a three-type households and three-sector neoclassical growth model. Rev. Mex. Econ. Finanz. 11, 1–19 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, W.-B.: Fashion and business cycles with snobs and bandwagoners in a multi-sector growth model. J. Bus. 2, 1–13 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the anonymous Referees for the helpful and valuable comments.

Funding

This research did not receive any specific grant.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marina Pireddu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Proof of the analytical results

Proof of the analytical results

Proof of Proposition 1

Since the arguments we shall employ are independent of the considered time period, in order not to overburden notation, we will omit the subscript t, as well as the stars, which will refer to the Pareto optimal allocationFootnote 16 only.

We define \(\theta =\left( p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i}\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\right) \in \varTheta =(0,+\infty )^{6}\) and, according to Definition 2, we say that \(\theta \in \varTheta \) is a market equilibrium given \( E\in {\mathcal {E}}\) and \(a\in (0,1)\) if, for every \(i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\), \(\left( x_{i},y_{i}\right) \) solves problem (4) at \(\left( p_x,p_y,E\right) \) and \(\left( x_{i},y_{i}\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\) satisfies market clearing conditions (3) at \(\left( E,a\right) \).

We denote by \(\varTheta (E,a)\) the set of market equilibria for E and a, and we introduce

$$\begin{aligned} \varTheta _\mathrm {n}(E,a)=\left\{ \theta \in \varTheta (E,a):p_x=1\right\} , \end{aligned}$$

that is, the set of normalizedFootnote 17 market equilibria for E and a. We will show that \(\varTheta _{\mathrm {n}}(E,a)\ne \emptyset \), for every \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\).

As one Walras’ law holds true in our model, just one market clearing condition in Definition 2 is significant. To fix ideas, we will focus on the equation for commodity y, i.e., on

$$\begin{aligned} a\, y_{\alpha }+(1-a)\, y_{\beta }=w_{y}. \end{aligned}$$

The extended system for our economy with two groups of agents, whose numerosity may not coincide, reads as

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} \frac{\partial u_{\alpha }}{\partial x_{\alpha }}(x_{\alpha },y_{\alpha })-\lambda _{\alpha } p_x=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\alpha }}{\partial y_{\alpha }}(x_{\alpha },y_{\alpha })-\lambda _{\alpha } p_y=0\\ -p_{x}\, x_{\alpha }-p_{y}\, y_{\alpha }+ p_{x}\, w_x+p_{y}\, w_y=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\beta }}{\partial x_{\beta }}(x_{\beta },y_{\beta })-\lambda _{\beta } p_x=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\beta }}{\partial y_{\beta }}(x_{\beta },y_{\beta })-\lambda _{\beta } p_y=0\\ -p_{x}\, x_{\beta }-p_{y}\, y_{\beta }+ p_{x}\, w_x+p_{y}\, w_y=0\\ a\, y_{\alpha }+(1-a)\, y_{\beta }-w_{y}=0\\ p_x-1=0 \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Since we are going to study market equilibria in terms of first-order conditions associated with households’ maximization problems and (significant) market clearing conditions, we define

$$\begin{aligned} \xi =\left( p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i},\lambda _i\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\right) \in (0,+\infty )^{8}, \end{aligned}$$

and the function

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {F}}:(0,+\infty )^{8}\times {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^{8},\quad {\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a)=\text{ lhs } \text{ of } (19). \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Given \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\), it is immediate to prove that if \(\theta =\bigl (p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i}\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\bigr )\) belongs to \(\varTheta _{\mathrm {n}}(E,a)\), then there exists the vector \((\lambda _{\alpha },\lambda _{\beta })\in (0,+\infty )^{2}\) such that \(\xi =\left( p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i},\lambda _i\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\right) \in (0,+\infty )^{8}\) solves the system \({\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a)=0\). Vice versa, if \(\xi =\left( p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i},\lambda _i\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\right) \in (0,+\infty )^{8}\) solves \({\mathcal {F}}\left( \xi ,E,a\right) =0\), then \(\left( p_{x},p_{y},\left( x_{i},y_{i}\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\right) \in \varTheta _{\mathrm {n}}(E)\).

Let us then show that for all \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\) there exists \(\xi \in (0,+\infty )^{8}\) which solves system \({\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a)=0\). Fixing \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\), we define

$$\begin{aligned} F:(0,+\infty )^{8}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^{8},\quad F(\xi )={\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a). \end{aligned}$$

Let us also introduce the homotopy

$$\begin{aligned} H:(0,+\infty )^{8}\times [0,1]\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^{8},\quad H(\xi ,\tau )=\text{ lhs } \text{ of } (21), \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} \frac{\partial u_{\alpha }}{\partial x_{\alpha }}(x_{\alpha },y_{\alpha })-\lambda _{\alpha } p_x=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\alpha }}{\partial y_{\alpha }}(x_{\alpha },y_{\alpha })-\lambda _{\alpha } p_y=0\\ -p_{x}\, x_{\alpha }-p_{y}\, y_{\alpha }+ p_{x}\,((1-\tau )w_x+\tau x_{\alpha }^{*})+p_{y}\,((1-\tau )\, w_y+\tau y_{\alpha }^{*})=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\beta }}{\partial x_{\beta }}(x_{\beta },y_{\beta })-\lambda _{\beta } p_x=0\\ \frac{\partial u_{\beta }}{\partial y_{\beta }}(x_{\beta },y_{\beta })-\lambda _{\beta } p_y=0\\ -p_{x}\, x_{\beta }-p_{y}\, y_{\beta }+ p_{x}\,((1-\tau )w_x+\tau x_{\beta }^{*})+p_{y}\,((1-\tau )\, w_y+\tau y_{\beta }^{*})=0\\ a\, y_{\alpha }+(1-a)\, y_{\beta }-\left( (1-\tau )w_y+\tau (a y_{\alpha }^{*}+(1-a) y_{\beta }^{*})\right) =0\\ p_x-1=0, \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where \(\left( x_{i}^{*},y_{i}^{*}\right) _{i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}}\in (0,+\infty )^{4}\) is an instantaneous Pareto optimal allocation, whose existence can be proven as in Section 8.5 in Villanacci et al. (2002). In particular, denoting by r the vector of the total resources associated with E, we have \(r=(w_x,w_y)\in (0,+\infty )^{2}\) and, denoting by \(\underline{U}^r\) the set of utility level vectors attainable with resources r in correspondence to \(E\in {\mathcal {E}}\) and \(a\in (0,1)\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{U}^r=\left\{ (\underline{u}_{\alpha },\underline{u}_{\beta })\in {\mathbb {R}}^2: \exists (x_{\alpha },x_{\beta },y_{\alpha },y_{\beta })\in (0,+\infty )^{4} \text{ s.t. } \begin{array}{ll} a\, j_{\alpha }+(1-a)\, j_{\beta }=w_{j}, \text{ for } j\in \{x,y\}, \\ \!\! \text{ and } u_i(x_i,y_i)-\underline{u}_i=0, \text{ for } i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \} \end{array} \right\} . \end{aligned}$$

We notice that \(H(\xi ,0)=F(\xi ),\,\forall \xi \in (0,+\infty )^{8}\). Setting

$$\begin{aligned} G:(0,+\infty )^{8}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^{8},\quad G(\xi )=H(\xi ,1), \end{aligned}$$

it holds that \(F,\,H\) and G are continuous functions. If we prove that, for some \({\widehat{\xi }}\in (0,+\infty )^{8}\),

$$\begin{aligned}&G^{-1}(0)=\{{\widehat{\xi }}\} \text{ and } G \text{ is } {\mathcal {C}}^1 \text{ in } \text{ an } \text{ open } \text{ neighborhood } \text{ of } {\widehat{\xi }}, \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned}&D_\xi G({\widehat{\xi }}) \text{ is } \text{ not } \text{ singular }, \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned}&H^{-1}(0) \text{ is } \text{ compact }, \end{aligned}$$
(24)

then Theorem 1 can be applied with the identifications \(M=(0,+\infty )^{8},\,N={\mathbb {R}}^{8},\,y=0\in {\mathbb R^8},\,\varPhi =F,\,\varGamma =G,\,\varPsi =H\), to get \(F^{-1}(0)\ne \emptyset \), so that a market equilibrium exists in correspondence to the fixed \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\).

The proof of conditions (22), (23) and (24) follows by standard arguments and it is omitted. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

Since the arguments we shall employ are independent of the considered time period, like in the proof of Proposition 1, in order not to overburden notation, we will omit the subscript t.

Recalling the definition of the map \({\mathcal {F}}\) in (20), it is evident that \({\mathcal {F}}\) is continuous. In order to apply Theorem 2 with the identifications \(f={\mathcal {F}},\,\mathbb R^n={\mathbb {R}}^8,\,O=(0,+\infty )^8,\,B={\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1),\,{\mathscr {B}}={\mathscr {E}}\times {\mathbb {R}}\), with \({\mathscr {E}}\) as in (1), we have to check that \({\mathcal {F}}\in \mathcal {C}^1((0,+\infty )^8\times {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1),{\mathbb {R}}^8)\) according to the definition in (5), i.e., that

$$\begin{aligned} d{\mathcal {F}}:\left( (0,+\infty )^8\times \mathcal E\times (0,1)\right) \times \left( {\mathbb {R}}^8\times \mathscr {E}\times {\mathbb {R}}\right) \rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^8 \end{aligned}$$

is well defined and continuous. Considering any \((\xi ,E,a)\in (0,+\infty )^8\times {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\) and \((\nu ,\eta ,\kappa )\in {\mathbb {R}}^8\times {\mathscr {E}}\times {\mathbb {R}}\), it holds indeed that the limit

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {d}{\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a)=\lim _{\varepsilon \rightarrow 0}\frac{{\mathcal {F}}(\xi +\varepsilon \nu ,E+\varepsilon \eta ,a+\varepsilon \kappa )-{\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,E,a)}{\varepsilon } \end{aligned}$$

exists, and it is easy to check that the map \(\hbox {d}{\mathcal {F}}\) is continuous.

Next, we want to show that for every \(a\in (0,1)\) the set

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {D}}(a)=\left\{ E\in {\mathcal {E}}: {\mathcal {F}}\left( \xi ,E,a\right) =0\Rightarrow \det D_{\xi }{\mathcal {F}}\left( \xi ,E,a\right) \ne 0 \right\} \end{aligned}$$

is an open and full measure subset of \({\mathcal {E}}\). Namely, applying Theorem 2, we obtain the smooth dependence of the market equilibria associated with all population shares \(a\in (0,1)\) and to any economy \(E\in {\mathcal {D}}(a)\) on the elements \((E,a)\in {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\).

Let us then sketch the proof that, for every \(a\in (0,1)\), \({\mathcal {D}}(a)\) is an open and full measure subset of \({\mathcal {E}}\).

The openness of \({\mathcal {D}}(a)\) follows by the closedness of the complement set \({\mathcal {E}}\setminus {\mathcal {D}}(a)\), due to the continuity of the involved functions. In order to show that \({\mathcal {D}}(a)\) is a full measure subset of \({\mathcal {E}}\), it suffices to show that, for every \((u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\in \mathcal U^2\times (0,1)\) the set

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {D}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)=\left\{ (w_x,w_y)\in (0,+\infty )^2: {\mathcal {F}}\left( \xi ,u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },w_x,w_y,a\right) =0\Rightarrow \det D_{\xi }{\mathcal {F}}\left( \xi ,E,a\right) \ne 0 \right\} \end{aligned}$$

is a full measure subset of \((0,+\infty )^2\). Since it can be proven that 0 is a regular value for the map

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{{\mathcal {F}}}:(0,+\infty )^8\times (0,+\infty )^2\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}^8,\quad \widetilde{{\mathcal {F}}}(\xi ,w_x,w_y)={\mathcal {F}}(\xi ,u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },w_x,w_y,a), \end{aligned}$$

then, by a transversality result (cf. Theorem 6.3.294 in Villanacci et al. 2002), there exists a full measure subset \(\widetilde{{\mathcal {D}}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\) of \((0,+\infty )^2\) such that, for all \((w_x,w_y)\in \widetilde{{\mathcal {D}}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\), 0 is a regular value for the map \(\widetilde{{\mathcal {F}}}(\cdot ,w_x,w_y)\). As \(\widetilde{{\mathcal {D}}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\subseteq {\mathcal {D}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\), it follows that \({\mathcal {D}}(u_{\alpha },u_{\beta },a)\) is a full measure subset of \((0,+\infty )^2\). Consequently, for every \(a\in (0,1)\), \({\mathcal {D}}(a)\) is a full measure subset of \({\mathcal {E}}\).

The finiteness of the number of market equilibria associated with an element (aE), with \(a\in (0,1)\) and \(E\in {\mathcal {D}}(a)\), comes now from the fact that, as it is easy to check, the projection

$$\begin{aligned} \pi :{\mathcal {F}}^{-1}(0)\rightarrow {\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1),\quad \pi \left( \xi ,E,a\right) =(E,a), \end{aligned}$$

is proper, i.e., the inverse image through \(\pi \) of a compact subset of \({\mathcal {E}}\times (0,1)\) is compact, too.

The proof is complete. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

By Theorem 1 we know that, for any \(E\in {\mathcal {E}},\,t\in {\mathbb {N}}\) and \(a_t\in (0,1)\), there exists at least a market equilibrium at time t. Let us then check that the equilibrium is unique, omitting as usual the dependence on t, in order not to overburden notation.

Recalling Definition 2 and the formulation of the market clearing conditions with shares in (3), we have to prove that if the gross substitute property holds for all the individual demand functions there exists one solution \(({\widehat{p}}_x,\widehat{p}_y)\in (0,+\infty )^2\) to the system

$$\begin{aligned} a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(p_x,p_y){+}(1{-}a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(p_x,p_y)-w_{x}{=}0{=}a\, y^{*}_{\alpha }(p_x{,}p_y){+}(1{-}a)\, y^{*}_{\beta }(p_x{,}p_y){-}w_{y}.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Since we can normalize one price, to show the uniqueness of the solution, we may focus on the price vectors \((1,p)\in (0,+\infty )^2\), with \(p=p_y/p_x\). Assuming that \(a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(1,\widehat{p})+(1-a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(1,{\widehat{p}})-w_{x}=0=a\, y^{*}_{\alpha }(1,{\widehat{p}})+(1-a)\, y^{*}_{\beta }(1,\widehat{p})-w_{y}\), let us prove that no \((1,{\widetilde{p}})\), with \(\widetilde{p}\ne {\widehat{p}}\), may solve (25). Namely, if \({\widetilde{p}}< {\widehat{p}}\), by the gross substitute property it would hold that \(x^{*}_i(1,{\widetilde{p}})<x^{*}_i(1,\widehat{p}),\,i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\), and thus, since \(a\in (0,1)\), we would have

$$\begin{aligned} a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(1,{\widetilde{p}})+(1-a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(1,{\widetilde{p}})-w_{x}<a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(1,{\widehat{p}})+(1-a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(1,{\widehat{p}})-w_{x}=0, \end{aligned}$$

so that \((1,{\widetilde{p}})\) would not be a solution to (25). Similarly, if \({\widetilde{p}}>{\widehat{p}}\), by the gross substitute property it would hold that \(x^{*}_i(1,\widetilde{p})>x^{*}_i(1,{\widehat{p}}),\,i\in \{\alpha ,\beta \}\), and thus, since \(a\in (0,1)\), it would follow that

$$\begin{aligned} a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(1,{\widetilde{p}})+(1-a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(1,{\widetilde{p}})-w_{x}>a\, x^{*}_{\alpha }(1,{\widehat{p}})+(1-a)\, x^{*}_{\beta }(1,{\widehat{p}})-w_{x}=0, \end{aligned}$$

so that \((1,{\widetilde{p}})\) would not solve (25).

This completes the proof. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

The conclusion immediately follows by observing that the solutions to the fixed-point equation \(g(a)=a\), with g as in (10), are given by \(a=0,\,a=1\), as well as by all solutions to the equation \(V_{\alpha }(a)=V_{\beta }(a)\), if any, and by all the solutions to the equation \((V_{\alpha }(a)+V_{\beta }(a))/2={\overline{V}}\), if any. Namely, the nontrivial equilibria for Equation (9) are found as solutions to the equation \({\mathscr {A}}_{\alpha }=f(\sigma \,d^2(\overline{V},V_{\alpha }))=f(\sigma \,d^2(\overline{V},V_{\beta }))={\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }\). Since f is strictly decreasing, all solutions have to satisfy \(d(\overline{V},V_{\alpha })=d({\overline{V}},V_{\beta })\), i.e., \(V_{\alpha }=V_{\beta }\) or \((V_{\alpha }+V_{\beta })/2={\overline{V}}\), as desired. This concludes the proof. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

Since \(g'(0)=1/(\exp \left( \mu \left( {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(0)-{\mathscr {A}}_{\alpha }(0)\right) \right) )\), the condition \(g'(0)>-1\) is always fulfilled, while \(g'(0)<1\) is fulfilled for \({\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(0)>{\mathscr {A}}_{\alpha }(0)\). Independently of f, exploiting the strictly decreasing behavior of \({\mathscr {A}}_{i}\) with respect to \(d^2({\overline{V}},V_i)\), we then find \((V_{\alpha }(0)-{\overline{V}})^2>(V_{\beta }(0)-{\overline{V}})^2\), as desired.

As concerns the local stability of \(a=1\) for map g, we find that \(g'(1)= \exp \left( \mu \left( {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(1)-{\mathscr {A}}_{\alpha }(1)\right) \right) \). Hence, the condition \(g'(1)>-1\) is always fulfilled, while \(g'(1)<1\) is fulfilled for \({\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(1)<{\mathscr {A}}_{\alpha }(1)\). Independently of f, exploiting again the strictly decreasing behavior of \({\mathscr {A}}_{i}\) with respect to \(d^2({\overline{V}},V_i)\), we find \((V_{\alpha }(1)-{\overline{V}})^2<(V_{\beta }(1)-{\overline{V}})^2\).

In regard to \(a={\hat{a}}\), recalling that \(V_{\alpha }({\hat{a}})=V_{\beta }({\hat{a}})\), we find that \(g'({\hat{a}})=1-2\mu \sigma {\hat{a}}(1-{\hat{a}})\frac{\partial {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(a)}{\partial (\sigma d_{\beta }^2)}\vert _{a={\hat{a}}}(V_{\beta }({\hat{a}})-\overline{V})(V_{\beta }'({\hat{a}})-V_{\alpha }'({\hat{a}}))\). Since \(\frac{\partial {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(a)}{\partial (\sigma d_{\beta }^2)}\vert _{a={\hat{a}}}\) is negative, then \(a={\hat{a}}\in (0,1)\) is unstable for map g for all positive values of \(\mu \) if \((V_{\beta }({\hat{a}})-{\overline{V}})(V_{\beta }'({\hat{a}})-V_{\alpha }'({\hat{a}}))>0\). If instead \((V_{\beta }({\hat{a}})-{\overline{V}})(V_{\beta }'({\hat{a}})-V_{\alpha }'({\hat{a}}))<0\), then \(g'({\hat{a}})<1\) is always fulfilled, while, if \({\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }\) does not depend on \(\mu \), \(g'({\hat{a}})>-1\) is fulfilled for \(\mu <{\hat{\mu }}\), with \({\hat{\mu }}\) as in (11), obtaining the desired conclusion about the local stability of \(a={\hat{a}}\in (0,1)\) for map g, too. The condition for the flip bifurcation follows by setting \(g'({\hat{a}})=-1\).

Finally, in regard to \(a={\tilde{a}}\), recalling that \(V_{\beta }(\tilde{a})-{\overline{V}}={\overline{V}}-V_{\alpha }({\tilde{a}})\), we find that \(g'({\tilde{a}})=1-2\mu \sigma {\tilde{a}}(1-\tilde{a})\frac{\partial {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(a)}{\partial (\sigma d_{\beta }^2)}\vert _{a={\tilde{a}}}({\overline{V}}-V_{\alpha }(\tilde{a}))(V_{\alpha }' ({\tilde{a}})+V_{\beta }'({\tilde{a}}))\). Since \(\frac{\partial {\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }(a)}{\partial (\sigma d_{\beta }^2)}\vert _{a={\tilde{a}}}\) is negative, then \(a=\tilde{a}\in (0,1)\) is unstable for map g for all positive values of \(\mu \) if \(({\overline{V}}-V_{\alpha }({\tilde{a}}))(V_{\alpha }'(\tilde{a})+V_{\beta }'({\tilde{a}}))>0\). If instead \((\overline{V}-V_{\alpha }({\tilde{a}}))(V_{\alpha }'({\tilde{a}})+V_{\beta }'(\tilde{a}))<0\), then \(g'({\tilde{a}})<1\) is always fulfilled, while, if \({\mathscr {A}}_{\beta }\) does not depend on \(\mu \), \(g'({\tilde{a}})>-1\) is fulfilled for \(\mu <{\tilde{\mu }}\), with \({\tilde{\mu }}\) as in (12). The condition for the flip bifurcation follows by setting \(g'(\tilde{a})=-1\). This concludes the proof. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Naimzada, A., Pireddu, M. A general equilibrium evolutionary model with two groups of agents, generating fashion cycle dynamics. Decisions Econ Finan 43, 155–185 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10203-020-00280-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10203-020-00280-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation